SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 101
Download to read offline
Project report
Using financial incentives to increase
testing uptake and reduce risk
behaviour in men
Masters in Public Health – Health System Management
Candidate number: T6423
Jennie van de Weerd
Submitted: 30 September 2010
Word count: 6963
LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423
i
Abstract
Introduction
Treatment will not stop the HIV epidemic in South Africa, but needs to be combined
with cost-effective approaches to prevention for those hardest to reach. This
research explores whether paying incentives could increase uptake of HIV-testing
and behaviour change for daily labourers living in informal settlements in Cape
Town.
Method
A literature review brought together 128 articles about behaviour change theories
and economics, HIV-testing uptake, examples incentive paying schemes and ethics
involved in paying incentives to patients. A calculation model looked at CE for
incentive provision per HIA and potential cost saving per HIA.
Results
The IBM-model and behavioural economics provide concepts to explain why paying
an incentive is effective. Motivation seems the most important factor to explain
testing enrolment. Stigma and risk perception need addressing by provision of
information and skills. Although incentive provision for simple tasks has shown
results, limited evidence exists to support incentive payment for complex behaviour
change. Careful balancing of the 7 elements of contingency management and the
combination of incentive provision with behavioural interventions is called for while
autonomy of the client should be considered. The extra cost of incentive provision
can be justified by the potential cost savings in treatment.
Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
ii
Discussion
The case for incentive provision for uptake of HIV-testing is clear, but not for
behaviour change. The contingent link between sexual behaviour and HIV at
individual level is weak. Incentive provision should therefore be combined with
behavioural interventions and alternative reinforcements. The potential cost-
effectiveness of incentive provision warrants further research.
LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423
iii
Foreword
Today, I can only be happy to zip this document and upload it to the London School
Website over the remains of my crashed laptop, using a laptop gracefully provided
by the ICT department of my employer. My husband and children will be equally
happy, since it will mean that I can participate again in our family life. And, it is high
time to rediscover my friends and colleagues. All in all, writing this report was a
heavy but interesting journey which made me grow.
Charles Maisel of Indlu Yegazi and Nienke van Schaik en Linda Gail-Bekker of
Desmond Tutu HIV Foundation (Tutu tester) triggered me to start this journey. I want
to thank them for their support and wish them success in their on-going work. I would
like to thank Piya Hanvoravongchai, my supervisor, and the PH project support team
of LSHTM for pointing me in the right direction when I almost lost the way.
Last but not least, I would like to thank the authors that sent their articles when
requested and Nadine Pakker who made it possible to gather most of my data.
Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
iv
Table of contents
Abstract ...................................................................................... i
Foreword....................................................................................iii
List of tables and figures ..............................................................vi
Tables in Annex...........................................................................vi
List of Abbreviations ...................................................................vii
List of Abbreviations ...................................................................vii
1. Introduction ....................................................... 1
1.1. Background .......................................................................1
1.2. Incentivized testing: DTHF Tutu tester and Indlu Yegazi ..........3
1.3. Report lay out ....................................................................5
2. Methodology ....................................................... 6
2.1. Aim and objectives .............................................................6
2.2. Literature review ................................................................6
2.3. Potential Cost effectiveness................................................ 10
2.4. Ethical considerations........................................................ 13
3. Results................................................................. 14
3.1. Behaviour change Theories ................................................ 14
3.1.1. The IMB-model ........................................................... 14
3.1.2. Behavioural economics ................................................ 15
3.1.3. Motivation as entry point ............................................. 16
3.2. HIV-testing uptake determinants ........................................ 18
3.2.1. Costs and access to HIV-testing .................................... 18
3.2.2. Stigma....................................................................... 18
3.2.3. Risk perception ........................................................... 19
3.2.4. Motivation to test........................................................ 19
3.3. Lessons from incentivized schemes..................................... 20
3.3.1. Overview included studies and reviews .......................... 20
3.3.2. Target behaviour......................................................... 20
3.3.3. Target population........................................................ 22
3.3.4. Incentive ................................................................... 23
3.3.5. Incentive size ............................................................. 24
3.3.6. Incentive-provision: frequency and timing...................... 25
3.3.7. Incentive duration....................................................... 26
3.4. Ethical considerations........................................................ 27
4. Costing model results ....................................... 28
4.1. Number of men tested and HIV-infections averted ................ 28
4.2. Cost of incentive provision ................................................. 29
4.3. Potential cost saving ......................................................... 30
4.4. One-way sensitivity analysis .............................................. 30
LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423
v
5. Discussion ........................................................ 32
5.1. Limitations....................................................................... 32
5.2. Theories .......................................................................... 33
5.3. Screening uptake.............................................................. 34
5.4. Incentivized schemes: Lessons learned ............................... 34
5.5. Ethics.............................................................................. 36
5.6. Cost effectiveness............................................................. 37
5.7. Conclusions...................................................................... 38
Literature....................................................................I
Annex 1: The TUTU TESTER......................................................... IX
Annex 2: Client risk assessment form ............................................ X
Annex 3: Calculation of odds ratio ...............................................XII
Annex 4: List of excluded articles ................................................ XV
Annex 5: Explanation of parameters used.................................... XIX
Annex 6: CRE form .................................................................. XXV
Annex 7: Confidentiality agreement ........................................ XXXVI
Annex 8: Health behaviour theories ....................................... XXXVII
Annex 9: Overview of studies............................................... XXXVIII
Annex 10: Ethical issues around payment of incentive..................XLIX
Annex 11: Calculation results number of testers and HIA................. LI
Annex 12: Calculation results additional cost of incentive ................LV
Annex 13: Calculation results potential cost savings ..................... LIX
Annex 14: Calculation results one-way sensitivity analysis........... LXIII
Annex 15: Calculation results HIV-testing cost per DALY ............ LXVII
Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
vi
List of tables and figures
Table 1: M&E data DTHF for Tutu tester 2009..............................................4
Table 2: Combination of search terms........................................................8
Table 3: Type of documents included ........................................................9
Table 4: Parameter values used in model ................................................. 12
Figure 1: No of AIDS deaths under 4 scenario's South Africa, ...........................2
Figure 2: Markov model MSR................................................................ 11
Figure 3: Fisher's IMB model (Fisher, 2005) .............................................. 15
Figure 4: Number of testers, HIA and HIV+ ............................................... 28
Figure 5: Cost incentive provision / HIA.................................................... 29
Figure 6: One-way sensitivity averaged over 2 years.................................... 31
Tables in Annex
A-Table 1: Odds ratio using 2009 M&E data DTHF ..................................... XII
A-Table 2: Odds of men compared to women .......................................... XIII
A-Table 3: Odds MSR compared to other men ......................................... XIII
A-Table 4: Odds MSR compared to women............................................. XIII
A-Table 5: Odds MSR compared to all others ...........................................XIV
A-Table 6: First time testers compared to others ........................................XIV
LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423
vii
List of Abbreviations
AIDS - Acquired Immuno Deficiency Syndrome
ART - Anti Retroviral Therapy
ARV - Anti Retro Viral
BMI - Body Mass Index
BMJ - British Medical Journal
CCT - Conditional Cash Transfer
CE - Cost Effectiveness
CE - Cost Effectiveness
CI - Confidence Interval
CINAHL - Cumulative Index to nursing and allied health literature
CM - Contingency Management
CPI - Consumer Price Index
CRE - Combined Risk Assessment and Ethics form
DALY - Disability Adjusted Life Years
DTHF - Desmond Tutu HIV Foundation
GDP - Gross Domestic Product
HARP - Highly Active Retroviral Prevention
HIA - HIV-infection Averted
HIV - Human Immunodeficiency Virus
IDU - Intravenous Drug Users
IMB - Information, motivation, behaviour model
IY - Indlu Yegazi
KIU - Keep It Up
LDL-C - Low-density lipoprotein-cholesterol
LSHTM - London School of Hygiene and Tropical Medicine
M&E - Monitoring and Evaluation
MARP - Most At Risk Population
MCH - Mother and Child Health
MSR - Men on the Side of the Road
na - Not applicable
NDOH - National Department of Health (South Africa)
NICE - National Institute of Clinical Excellence (UK)
OR - Odds Ratio
PIT - Provider Initiated Testing
PMTCT - Prevention of Mother to Child Transmission
PPD - Purified Protein Derivate
RCT - Randomized Controlled Trial
RSA - Republic of South Africa
SASA - South African Statistical Agency
STD / STI - Sexual Transmitted Disease / Infection
TB - Tuberculosis
UNAIDS - Joint United Nations Program on HIV/AIDS
UNICEF - United Nations Childrens’ Fund
US - United States
VBRT - Voucher Based Reinforcement Therapy
VCT - Voluntary Counselling and Testing
WHO - World Health Organization
ZAR - South African Rand
LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423
1
1. Introduction
1.1. Background
A South African survey found that 73.3% of women and 66.1% of men had tested for
HIV in Western Cape (Shisana et al., 2009)1
compared to the universal access target
of 75% by 20102
. Tests during the survey showed an HIV-prevalence of 12.8% in
first-time testers and 16.3% for others (Peltzer et al., 2009). STIs accounted for more
than 26% of all deaths and over 5 million DALYs in 2000 in South Africa and over
98% of this burden was due to HIV/AIDS (Johnson et al., 2007). African males (25-
49) have been identified as a country-specific most at risk group (MARP) with
prevalence levels of 23.7%. Comprehensive knowledge of HIV/AIDS declined from
40.6% to 28%3
in this group (Shisana et al., 2009) while access to and utilization of
HIV-services is significantly lower (NDOH, 2008).
The need to seriously expand testing coverage is well acknowledged in the
“Universal Access-campaign” (UNAIDS and WHO, 2004). But reaching the next
client will be increasingly expensive as more effort is needed to convince him (Glick,
2005; Marseille et al., 2007). Over the last years, with treatment becoming more and
more available, different delivery models of HIV-testing are introduced to increase
uptake (Western Cape Province, 2009).
1
South Africa overall data of 2008 indicate that only 43% of men and 56.7% of women ever received
an HIV test and test results (UNAIDS et al., 2009). Cape Town is in Western Cape Province.
2
Accessed from www.unaidsrstesa.org on 18 June 2010.
3
Comparing 2008 with 2005 data.
Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
2
Cost-effective prevention efforts are needed, because for every two persons put on
treatment another five get infected (Global HIV prevention working group, 2010).
Figure 1 shows four scenarios for South Africa indicating that only a combination of
treatment and prevention can reduce HIV deaths in the country (Johnson et al.,
2007).
Figure 1: No of AIDS deaths under 4 scenario's South Africa,
Source Johnson et al., 2007
The importance of HIV-testing as a gateway to treatment and as a secondary
prevention method by inducing behaviour change in those testing HIV positive is
acknowledged (Valdiserri et al., 2003; Glick, 2005; Global HIV Prevention working
group, 2010) and has been shown to be a cost-effective intervention (Galárraga et
al., 2009; Denison et al., 2009).
Evidence of testing as an effective prevention intervention for those testing negative
is inconclusive (Elwy et al, 2002; Hageman et al., 2009). Could this be caused by the
fact that even the newly proposed service-delivery methods are still focussed on
increasing access to testing from a supply side perspective? In “Three letter Plague”
(Steinberg, 2008) the struggle of a young South African black man to decide whether
LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423
3
or not to take an HIV-test is narrated. In the end, although being aware of the threat
HIV poses, knowing where to go for a test and the fact that treatment is available,
the main character decides not to take an HIV-test. He is not alone.
1.2. Incentivized testing: DTHF Tutu tester and Indlu Yegazi
In the Cape Town metropolitan area, the Desmond Tutu HIV Foundation reaches out
to hard to reach populations with their Tutu Tester mobile tester (see Annex 1). The
Tutu tester frequents informal settlements. Clients are given a comprehensive health
check, including tests for hypertension, diabetes and obesity. As part of HIV
counselling, clients are helped to complete a risk assessment form and make a plan
to reduce their risk of attracting AIDS (Annex 2). Condom demonstrations are given
and condoms are provided free of charge. DTHF works together with Indlu Yegazi
(IY), a NGO offering HIV-testing to daily labourers4
. They are paid an incentive of
around ZAR 75/- to motivate them to test5
. When testing negative, these men on the
side of the road (MSR) can come back after 6 months to test again6
. It is assumed
that this can provide the men the necessary motivation to stay negative and come
back to test.
Table 1 shows data from Desmond Tutu HIV Foundation Tutu mobile tester (DTHF)
for 2009. While 29% of women tested reported that this is their first test, this is 47%
for men7
.
4
These men stand at the side of the road each day waiting for a prospective employer and are
therefore called Men on the side of the road (MSR).
5
Level of incentive varies depending on the average wage per day paid.
6
Limited demographic information is available on the MSR targeted by IY and limited data is
collected. Most of the men are African and have lower educational levels (unskilled jobs). Men testing
positive are referred to the care and treatment services of DTHF. Indlu Yegazi is contemplating
offering a different incentive for men adhering to care services.
7
While 27% is comparable to the mean of Western Cape, 47% for men is much higher.
Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
4
Table 1: M&E data DTHF for Tutu tester 2009
Female Male No-incentive With incentiveTutu tester
2009 data8
n % n % n % n %
Total 3191 41 4648 59 3001 65 1647 35
First test 925 29 2169 47 1281 43 888 54
HIV positive 207 6 405 9 155 5 250 15
1st
test, HIV+ 75 36 260 12 85 7 175 20
Zooming in on the results of the MSR over 2009, one might conclude that specific
attention for this group is necessary since 54% have not tested before (20% above
the provincial level) and 20% of this group’s first testers is positive. MSR have
significant higher odds of testing for the first time (1.57), testing HIV+ (3.29) and
testing HIV+ for the first time (especially when compared to other men: 3.45). Some
real differences seem to exist between the populations in terms of uptake of HIV-
testing and HIV prevalence. Annex 3 gives an overview of odds ratio calculated for
this group of testers.
Seen these results, it is not surprising that the Western Cape province indicates that
uptake of testing by men has their focus (Western Cape Province, 2009). Since
transmission from male to female is much easier and due to power inequalities it is
men’s behaviour placing women at risk, men are key to controlling the spread of HIV
and STI (Elwy et al., 2002).
8
Derived from monitoring and evaluation data from the DTHF – Tutu tester. This is a mobile testing
unit deployed in Cape Town, South Africa (Nyanga and Masiphumele district). Data reflect 201 days
testing without incentive and 45 times with incentive.
LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423
5
1.3. Report lay out
With a big burden of disease caused by unhealthy behaviour9
, incentives directed
towards patients may have a great impact on public health and cost of care (Volpp et
al, 2009; Volpp et al, 2009a). The question is whether providing incentives would
indeed increase testing uptake and behaviour change.
The incentivized testing intervention can be termed a contingency management
approach defined as “the systematic reinforcement of desired behaviour and the
withholding of reinforcement or punishment of undesired behaviour” (Higgins and
Petry, 1999). Conditional Cash Transfers (CCT) are considered to fall in this
definition. Different incentive type interventions exist, though application of these
principles in Africa or on HIV risk-reduction is so far limited (Volmink and Garner,
1997; Haug and Sorensen, 2006). Interventions using material incentives provided to
patients mainly focus on interventions to reduce substance abuse in Europe and
America while Conditional Cash Transfer (CCT) programs have been successful in
Latin America. One proof of concept CCT pilot study is currently underway in
Tanzania assessing effectiveness of the use of incentives for young adults to test
negative for STIs (DeWalque et al., 2010).
This report presents available evidence from interventions aimed at changing
behaviour or increasing service uptake using incentives. Chapter 2 provides the
methodology of the research. In chapter 3, the results from the literature research
are presented followed by the cost modelling in chapter 4. The concluding chapter
discusses the results.
9
Preventable disease estimated at 40% for the US by Volpp et al (2009a). To compare STIs in South
Africa consists of 26% of DALY of which 98% is due to AIDS.
Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
6
2. Methodology
2.1. Aim and objectives
The aim of the research is to explore whether providing incentive based HIV-testing
for men could be an effective10
way of HIV prevention.
Specific objectives of the research are:
1) Conduct a literature review on the use of incentive-based systems to
increase uptake of preventive services and change behaviour with a
focus on HIV-testing.
2) Based on available cost data, assess the potential cost-effectiveness of
incentive provision for HIV-testing and behaviour change in South
Africa.
2.2. Literature review
To address objective 1 “the use of incentive-based systems to increase uptake of
preventive services and change behaviour”, six databases were searched
(Cochrane, Pubmed, Embase, BMJ, Google scholar and CINAHL) to address the
following search questions.
1) Which theories exist to explain the motivation and determinants for men
to take up HIV-testing and change behaviours?
2) What are determinants for HIV-testing uptake in South Africa?
10
Effective is defined as increasing uptake of testing and reducing risky behaviour measured by a
lower incidence of HIV.
LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423
7
3) Which examples exist of increases in uptake of services, strengthened
adherence to treatment or changed behaviour due to the use of
material11
incentives?
4) What are the ethics of providing a financial incentive (to a specific
group)?
A number of key terms were identified based on these research questions. Different
spelling options for words were used12
.
Table 2 presents searches using a combination of key terms. Boolean operators
“AND” and “OR” were used to respond to the research questions13
. A total of 2720
articles were found. Articles that focussed on provider-incentives, incentives to
recruit patients in trials or non-material incentives were excluded after reviewing the
summary.
11
Cash or no-cash
12
See example in table 2: behaviour change / behavior change but also men / male
13
Only articles published from 1995 were included. Language was no restriction.
Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
8
Table 2: Combination of search terms
Combination of search terms Cochrane14
Pubmed
15
Embase BMJ GoogleScholar CINAHL Total
Total (T) and Relevant (R) articles T R T R T R T R T R T R T R
[“HIV testing” or “HIV test”] AND incentive 5 1 15 4 6 0 50 7 200
16
1 4 2 280 13
17
Incentive AND [patient OR client] AND [financial OR
material OR economic]
83 20 137 7 29 6 32 5 200
18
7 125 9 606 38
19
Intervention AND promotion AND incentive 29 8 11 4 20 2 162 10 200
20
13 15 3 437 35
21
[HIV or AIDS or STI or STD] AND [intervention or
promotion or prevention or testing] AND [incentive or
cash or reward or payment or gift or remuneration or
compensation or bonus or prize or lottery]
51 8 164 12 194 12 83 3 181
22
4 86 10 759 25
23
[HIV or STD or STI or AIDS ] AND [“Conditional Cash
Transfer” or “Contingency Management”]
13 3 22 10 22 8 1 1 26 5 11 5 95 20
24
Sexual AND “Behaviour change” AND [incentive or
cash or reward or payment or gift or remuneration or
compensation or bonus or prize or lottery]
6 1 32 1 0 0 - 0
-
200 16 7 0 245 18
“risk reduction” AND [male OR men] AND incentive
AND HIV
10 0 84 3 3 1 - 0 200 1 1 1 298 4
25
Total 197 41 465 41 274 29 328 26 1207 47 249 30 2720 118
26
14
Search in fields: title, abstract and key words
15
Search in fields: title and abstract
16
The first 200 of 5670 articles were reviewed by title and abstract
17
2 articles were overlapping across databases
18
The first 200 of a total of 6460 documents were reviewed by title and abstract
19
16 articles were overlapping across databases
20
The first 200 of a total 19,400 documents were reviewed by title and abstract
21
5 articles overlapping across databases
22
Search in field: intitle
23
24 articles were overlapping across databases
24
12 articles overlapping across databases
25
2 articles overlapping across databases
26
35 articles overlapping across searches
LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423
9
Of these 118 articles, 7 could not be retrieved, 7 were already included in a review
which was part of the research and 31 were excluded after full text review. Reasons
are listed in Annex 4. This resulted in a final number of 73 documents.
A further search of article references and websites was conducted to find additional
information on theories underlying the provision of incentives, information on
determinants for HIV-testing uptake in South Africa and the ethics of incentive
provision. This resulted in a final number of 128 articles and books as presented in
table 3.
Table 3: Type of documents included
StudyQuestion
RCT
28
Cohort Cross-
sectional
Review Other
27
Total
1 2 1 1 5 10 19
2 1 14 2 4 21
3 3029
10 2 9 24 75
4 2 4 7 13
Total 32 12 19 20 45 128
27
Other includes books, background articles, reports, editorial notes and letters in journals.
28
Randomized controlled trial
29
2 pilot studies were not randomized, but worked with control group
Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
10
2.3. Potential Cost effectiveness
To respond to objective 2 “assess the potential cost-effectiveness of incentive
provision for HIV-testing and behaviour change in the context of South Africa” a
model was developed to compare the DTHF normal mobile testing intervention
without incentive (control group) with the DTHF/IY incentivized intervention modelled
on the MSR population (intervention group). Calculations were made based on the
full capacity of one mobile testing unit in one year using accounting costs from a
provider perspective thus excluding cost to the tester or society due to the limited
costing data available (UNAIDS, 2000). The two outcomes of interest are the
additional cost of providing an incentive per additional HIV-infection averted (HIA)
and the potential cost saving per HIA30
.
A Markov model was developed to answer the following questions, compared with
the current mobile testing intervention of DTHF:
1. What is the additional cost of providing an incentive per HIA over a five-year
period to a cohort of men?
2. What is the potential cost saving per HIA over a five-year period to a cohort of
men?
3. What is the necessary reduction in the chance of getting infected with HIV
and the necessary time-span to justify the current provision of an incentive31
?
4. How are the outcomes of the calculation model influenced by different values
of the key variables (sensitivity analysis)?
30
Potential cost saving per HIV-infection prevented is the cost of providing an incentive minus the
cost that otherwise would have been paid to treatment.
31
ZAR75 per test, 2 tests a year, n=4416 men
LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423
11
The model (see figure 2) describes the chance of a man to become infected in a
given time period (year) based on his initial state. Whether or not the man has tested
before – his ‘history’ – is not considered (Sanderson and Gruen, 2006). Thus it
assumes that chance of getting infected and loss to follow up will stay the same over
time. Except for the incentive and parameter values, the flow of the model will be the
same for the control group.
Figure 2: Markov model MSR
Four positive effects of providing an incentive are assumed by DTHF/IY. First, more
men will be interested to take up testing. This is reflected in the utilization rates (77%
vs. 92%) of the DTHF vs. DTHF/IY intervention32
. Secondly, more men will test
regularly at the recommended intervals. Thus, the percentage of men lost to follow
up (nl) will be lower in the incentivized group and the number of tests (and thus
incentive) performed will be higher in the incentivized group (nt). Third, because of
32
The 2009 M&E data show that on DTHF/IY days, a number close to the full capacity of 40 testers a
day is tested.
Motivated to test
= n
HIV+
HIV-
On ART treatment
Not on ART treatment
Lost to follow up
Men on the side of
the Road (MSR)
Men on the side of
the Road (MSR)
1-nl
p
1-p
nl
t
1-t
nl: % of men lost to follow up
p: chance of becoming infected
?: chance that when HIV+
treatment is initiated immediately
Incentive
I
Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
12
the incentive, men will be motivated to change behaviour thus reducing the chance
(p) to become infected compared to the control group. Furthermore, men will be
diagnosed with HIV earlier on, so the percentage of men needing to go on ART
immediately will be lower (t). Due to the limitations in available data, the model
however assumes that all diagnosed HIV+ will be put on treatment.
The Markov model formed the basis for the development a costing model prepared
in Microsoft Excel 200333
. Cost data were retrieved for the provision of HIV/AIDS
testing, ART treatment and other services in South Africa (Cape Town) in the last 5
years. Parameter values are presented in table 4.
Table 4: Parameter values used in model
Model parameters
34
Current situation (control)
35
Incentive effect
Chance to become infected (p) 0.20 0.15, 0.10, 0.05, 0.00
Incentive value (I) 0 10.22 US$
Number of testers (n) 3696 441636
Number of tests (nt) 2 2
Loss to follow up (nl)
37
0.15 0.00, 0.05, 0.10
Two outcomes of interest were calculated: the incentive cost per HIV+ case directly
prevented and the potential cost saving per HIV-infection directly prevented38
.
Budget data from IY were utilized to calculate the cost of providing an incentive.
33
Attached as separate file to this report.
34
All parameters in the model can be changed.
35
Based on the M&E 2009 data for MSR
36
In 2009, utilisation rate was 77% of full capacity per day (40 testers) without incentive and 92% with
incentive
37
No data could be retrieved from DTHF/IY. Rutledge et al, 2002 found average attrition over 12
sexually transmitted HIV prevention interventions based upon social learning to be 15%. The normal
intervention of DTHF could be considered an intervention like this. The incentive is an added extra.
38
Potential cost saving per HIV-infection prevented is the cost of providing an incentive minus the
total cost that would have been paid to treatment if the infection was not averted.
LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423
13
A one-way sensitivity analysis was performed testing the influence of varying the
value of variables n, nl, nt, I and p in the intervention (i) group on the overall outcome
of the intervention. Annex 5 presents underlying assumptions, data sources and
limitations of the parameters used. All costs are standardized to 2009 using the
consumer price indexes of South African Statistical Agency39
. A discounting rate of
3% is used (Mathers et al, 2006). Discounting enables to take into account the fact
that people would like to have benefits now and pay later so cost in the future are
decreased with this percentage (Belli et al., 1998).
2.4. Ethical considerations
Ethics clearance was obtained from LSHTM (reference 009/06). Annex 6 presents
the Approved CRE form. After obtaining the ethical clearance, the scope of the study
was limited. Only M&E data from DTHF Tutu tester were used. Annex 7 presents the
confidentiality agreement signed with the DTHF.
39
http://www,statssa,gov,za/timeseriesdata/excel_format,asp accessed on 7July 2010
Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
14
3. Results
3.1. Behaviour change Theories
3.1.1. The IMB-model
Fisher states that prevention interventions fail because they are not rooted in
theory40
, provide information only – which is not sufficient to change behaviour - and
focus on general patterns of behaviour rather than information, skills and
motivational support specially targeting the group addressed (Fishbein and Guinan,
1996; Rutledge, 2002; Fisher, 2005; Albarracín et al., 2005; Medlin et al., 2008).
According to the Information – Motivation – Behaviour model (IMB), any intervention
aimed at behaviour change should 1) give information which is relevant to the
intended behaviour change and the specific population, 2) also work on social
support systems and motivation of the individual and lastly 3) train skills of the
individual so that he is able to behave in the intended manner41
. The model is simple
and has been validated in various settings (DiClementi et al, 2009; Mimiaga et al.,
2009). A US-RCT found the model to be most effective for men (Kalichman et al.,
2005). Figure 3 presents the model.
40
Annex 8 provides background on three main categories of health behaviour theories.
41
Five skills are identified as necessary for HIV prevention: Self-acceptance of sexuality, acquisition
of behaviourally relevant information, negotiation of preventive behaviour with partner, performance of
public prevention acts and consistent performance of prevention behaviour (Mimiaga et al., 2009).
LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423
15
Figure 3: Fisher's IMB model (source Fisher, 2005)42
The model was generalized to the South African context although with special
attention on AIDS related stigma as an important environmental factor which
adversely influences all three elements of the model (Kalichman and Simbayi, 2003;
Kalichman et al., 2006). Effective prevention should also include interventions to
increase service availability, promotion of testing at population level and biomedical
strategies (Coates et al., 2008). Evidence suggests that for the short term, a full IMB
counselling model is most effective for men (Kalichman et al., 2005).
3.1.2. Behavioural economics
Behavioural economics helps to explain why paying an incentive will increase the
motivation for individuals to change behaviour. People prefer to have a reward now
than the ‘may-be’ risk of acquiring HIV in the future (time-preference) (Loewenstein
et al., 2007; Volpp et al., 2009a). By putting a price on staying HIV-, the opportunity
cost of risky sex increases. Neoclassical theory assumes individuals to be rational,
making the choices that maximize utility subject to constraints in time and budget
(Eichler, 2006; Jochelson, 2007; Finkelstein et al., 2008). Preferences – which may
42
Kalichman et al. (2006) uses the terms AIDS knowledge (HIV prevention information), behavioural
intentions (motivation) and self-efficacy (behavioural skills).
HIV Prevention
Information
HIV Prevention
Motivation
HIV Prevention
Behavioral Skills
HIV Preventive
Behavior
Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
16
vary from day to day (Kiene et al., 2008) - also influence the perceived opportunity
costs of engaging in risky sex. When the next opportunity to receive an incentive is
too far off or the incentive is too small, time-preference can actually explain
engagement in risk-sex if the individual wants to maximize his utility (Medlin and
DeWalque, 2008).
3.1.3. Motivation as entry point
The IMB model suggests that for different populations, the trigger for behaviour
change will be different. Paying an incentive assumes that motivation is the entry
point to behaviour change. The incentive can overcome stigma and thus have men
enrol for a test and participate in a risk assessment. The question however, is also
how to change behaviour43
. Paying an incentive increases external motivation. How
long an incentive needs to be paid to internalize motivation? Also, should the
incentive be stable over time, increase or decrease to maintain the level of
motivation.
A reduction in opportunity cost attracts people that are less interested to change
behaviour (Glick, 2005; Cahill and Perera, 2008). Economic theory would suggest
that when an incentive is no longer paid, there is no reason to sustain the behaviour.
The intrinsic motivation for individuals to change behaviour is their aim to maximize
utility which they do when they get the incentive. When the incentive is stopped
behaviour which is maximizing utility – which could be risky sexual behaviour rather
than using condoms – is again adopted (Kane et al., 2004a).
43
The transtheoretical model identifies 5 stages of change: 1) precontemplative (no intention to
change), 2) contemplative stage (considering change), 3) ready for action stage (exploratory attempts
to adopt behaviour), 4) action stage and finally 5) maintenance stage (behaviour has become routine)
(Fishbein and Guinan, 1996).
LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423
17
Behavioural learning theory suggests that after several rounds of rewards, the
behaviour is automated so even though payment is stopped, behaviour will be
sustained (Kellog et al., n.d.). Cognitive dissonance theory suggests that even
though initial engagement with the program depends on the payment of the
incentive, communication with the service providers, enhancement of skills and
provision of information can influence motivation so that individuals as social
creatures want to comply with behaviour which is advocated as being good (Corrigan
et al., 2005). Communication theory implies that therapeutic alliance will be built by
regular interaction and this regular reinforcement will in time be sufficient to sustain
the desired behaviour (Kiene et al., 2008).
Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
18
3.2. HIV-testing uptake determinants
3.2.1. Costs and access to HIV-testing
In Western Cape44
, men test significantly less than women (Western Cape Province,
2009). An Eastern Cape study found that every one kilometre a man lives away from
a testing facility, reduces the likelihood that a man will test (Hutchinson and
Mahlalela, 2006). PIT45
might therefore not be the only answer to increase testing
uptake by men. Mobile testing, a strategy suggested to reach Most At Risk
Populations (MARP) brings testing facilities closer to people. Black African Males
between 25 and 49 years are identified as a country specific MARP for South Africa
(Shisana et al., 2009).
Physical access to a testing facility is important, but also the willingness and ability to
absorb the monetary and time-related costs to go for a test. (Weinreb and Stecklov,
2009; Nyanzi-Wakholi et al., 2009; Peltzer et al., 2009; Jepson et al., 2000). A meta-
analysis of HIV risk-reduction interventions in the US found that tangible incentives
had a positive effect on the participation and retention of men in screening programs
(Durantini and Albarracín, 2009).
3.2.2. Stigma
Stigma is another important influence on the decision to go for testing. Men indicated
that they preferred to live in doubt and would only go for VCT when they were sick.
Men do not fear family based stigma so much, but are more scared to loose their
position in the community (Day et al., 2003; Holzemer and Uys, 2004; Nyanzi-
44
Cape Town is located in the Western Cape province of South Africa.
45
Provider initiated testing has been introduced in all public health facilities in the Western Cape.
LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423
19
Wakholi et al., 2009). The possibility of testing HIV+ and the stigma attached to this,
thus reduces the acceptability and uptake. Embedding HIV-testing in a more
comprehensive health check could address the issue of stigma and acceptability,
and result in higher uptake (O’Donnell, 2009).
3.2.3. Risk perception
For many people, the motivation to use VCT is low because they do not see
themselves as at risk for HIV/AIDS, even in high-prevalence areas or following high-
risk behaviour (Hutchinson and Mahlalela, 2006; Kalichman et al., 2008; Hageman et
al., 2009; Johnston et al., 2010). But even if they consider themselves at risk, HIV is
only one of the threats they face most of which are considered more pressing and
immediate than HIV/AIDS (Kalichman et al., 2006). In Western Cape, self reported
condom use is very low pointing to high-risk sexual intercourse (Johnson and
Budlender, 2002; Shisana et al., 2009). The DTHF/IY M&E data indicate that MSR
are 2.88 times more likely to test HIV+ while they are much less likely to have tested
before (see Annex 3). Social networks strongly influence the individual’s perceptions
of risk surrounding HIV/AIDS and their preventive behaviours (Hutchinson et al.,
2007).
3.2.4. Motivation to test
With high opportunity costs to go for testing, high levels of stigma and low risk
perception possibly due to incorrect knowledge, motivation to test will be low. Correct
knowledge of HIV transmission – positively associated with being tested for HIV - is
only 43.8% in Black African Male overall and 34.1% in Western Cape (Shisana et al.,
2009). The fact that DTHF provides mobiles HIV-testing embedded in a more
comprehensive health check apparently does not overcome the barriers to test for
Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
20
MSR. The next paragraph explores evidence to assess if, as stated by the men
(Indlu Yegazi, 2009) a financial incentive could increase uptake and change
behaviour.
3.3. Lessons from incentivized schemes
3.3.1. Overview included studies and reviews
Fifty-one articles were included referring to 49 studies: 30 RCTs, 10 cohorts, 2 cross
sectional designs and 9 reviews. Of these 37 were conducted in the US and only 2 in
Africa46
(Malawi and Tanzania). Fifteen studies referred to HIV-related incentive
interventions. Others were related to compliance (5), uptake of preventive health
services (4), smoking cessation (4), substance abuse (4), tuberculosis (6) and weight
loss (4). The 9 reviews referred to 7 studies covering a total of 235. None of the
reviews specifically targeted HIV-related behaviour change. Annex 9 provides
information on the studies. Lessons from the included articles are presented along
the 7 core issues to be considered when looking at or designing a contingency
management program are 1) Targeted behaviour, 2) Choice of target population, 3)
Choice of incentive, 4) Incentive magnitude, 5) Frequency of incentive distribution,
6) Timing of incentive and 7) Duration of the incentive provision (Razavi et al., 2009;
Kellog et al., n.d.).
3.3.2. Target behaviour
Target behaviour is complex or simple (Kane et al., 2004 and 2004a). Simple
behaviours are one-off activities, treatment adherence, return visits to collect results,
attendance at educational activities, completion of a procedure, enrolment. Twenty-
two of the included studies refer to such simple behaviours and show that incentive
46
Malawi and Tanzania.
LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423
21
provision results in higher success rates, higher enrolment and attraction of MARP
(Chaisson et al., 1996; Fitzgerald et al., 1999; White et al, 1998; Kelen, 1996; Bloch
et al., 2006; Corrigan et al., 2005; Corrigan and Bogner, 2007; Haukoos et al., 2005).
The more complex and sustained the targeted behavioural outcomes47
, the weaker
the evidence of effectiveness of incentives. After the incentives stop, relapses occur
and differences with the control group diminish or disappear completely (Kane et al.,
2004; Cahill and Perera, 2008; Haug et al, 2006; Brandon et al., 2007; Forde and
Zeuner, 2009; Oliver, 2009; Volpp, 2009; Marteau et al., 2009). Results from CCTs
suggest that the programs increase the use of preventive services and improve
intermediate outcome measures, but long-term effectiveness has not been assessed
(Anderson, 2010; Lagarde et al, 2007; Lagarde et al, 2009; Razavi et al., 2009).
Ten of the 15 HIV-related studies referred to simple behaviour. In the five referring to
complex behaviour, one used self-report of behaviour change to measure behaviour
change (Petry et al., 2010) while it is important that target behaviour can be
measured objectively to avoid bias. Two studies saw risk behaviour change not
related to risky sex but substance abuse48
(Ghitza at al., 2008; Hanson et al., 2008).
The Tanzania-study used STI infection as proxy for HIV-infection since chances to
get infected with HIV are small and distant even when engaging in risky sex (Medlin
and DeWalque, 2008)49
. The Malawi study used pregnancy rates and early marriage
as proxy for risky sexual behaviour (Baird et al, 2009)50
.
47
Smoking cessation, weight loss, substance abuse.
48
Harm reduction measures like bleaching of needles, syringes exchange etc.
49
Risk of HIV transmission in men during penile-vaginal intercourse is 0.01-0.1%. Risk of
transmission will be higher if an STI is present (Baggaley et al., 2008).
50
The main target behaviour of the incentive provision was to increase school attendance and reduce
drop-out for girls. Effect on sexual behaviour and early marriage were a by-product of the increase in
school attendance (both in number of girls and length of attendance).
Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
22
While stimulating demand is important, the capacity of the supply side system to
offer quality services in sufficient quantity also needs to be addressed (Morris et al.,
2004; Lagarde et al., 2007; Medlin and DeWalque, 2008; Adato and Bassett, 2009;
Bassett, 2008; Baird et al., 2009; Lagarde et al., 2009; Schafer, 2010; Banerjee et
al., 2010; Lim et al., 2010)
3.3.3. Target population
Paying an incentive increases the cost of normal treatment, therefore it is suggested
to target for specific populations and behaviour with high public health impact
(Higgins et al., 2002; DeWalque et al., 2010; Lim et al., 2010)51
. The studies show
that paying an incentive is effective in reaching MARP which were targeted in 24 of
the included studies. But the more targeted the intervention and the more
conditioned, the more expensive it becomes administratively. Furthermore, targeting
can induce stigma (Forde and Zeuner, 2009). And the incentive will be paid to
people that already behave as intended (Lagarde et al, 2007; Volpp et al, 2009a). In
12 studies attrition was still high, attributed to the height of the incentive, the physical
distance to the service and/or the quality of service provision (White et al., 1998;
Carey et al., 2005; Gift et al., 2005; Ghitza et al., 2008; Petry et al., 2010). Two
studies found that success rates were higher in men than women (Tulsky et al.,
2000; Chaisson et al., 1996).
51
Populations to be addressed are treatment recalcitrant, hard-to-reach or most at risk populations
(MARP).
LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423
23
3.3.4. Incentive
The first question is whether incentive provision is necessary. Since incentive
provision is expensive compared to other interventions, cost-effectiveness might
easier be achieved with another intervention (Chaisson et al., 1996; Villano et al.,
2002; Morris et al., 2004; Petry et al., 2004; Adato and Bassett, 2009; Heil et al.,
2008; Ghitza et al., 2008; Banerjee et al., 2010). This is especially true when looking
from a provider-perspective as potential cost-savings might benefit another budget.
Incentives can be conditional or unconditional. While unconditional cash transfers
have shown to improve health seeking behaviour, it is not likely that people with low
risk perception and high stigma will change HIV-related risk behaviour when no
condition applies to the cash transfer (Stitzer, 2006). Incentives can be positive or
negative. Positive approaches seem to be more effective possibly because it
reinforces individuals’ sense of personal achievement (Jochelson, 2007; Heil et al.,
2008). Positive reinforcement is also more enjoyable for clients and providers (Kellog
et al., n.d.). Incentives can be in-kind, vouchers or cash. In-kind incentives are less
appreciated by clients than the more flexible vouchers or cash and require more time
and effort from the service provider52
. With cash, clients could purchase unintended
items53
and the necessity to keep stocks of cash at the service-delivery point carries
a security risk (DTHF/IY, personal comment; Alfers and Butterfoss, 2000; Kane et
al., 2004 and 2004a; Hanson et al., 2008; Cahill and Perera, 2009).
Flat payments for task completion or regular flat payments were provided in 22
studies. Escalating incentives with a reset value were used in 12. These incentives
grow, the longer you do (not) exhibit the behaviour, the higher your payment
52
Staff need to go buy the items in sufficient quantities. Articles have to be stored somewhere etc.
53
Alcohol, drugs etc.
Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
24
becomes. Once you relapse, payments are reset to the original value (Pilling et al.,
2007; Mayor, 2007; Volpp et al., 2009; Heil et al., 2008; Cahill and Perera, 2008).
Nine researches used a lottery system. Participants can win draws for big prices.
Lottery systems were introduced to enable continuous or escalating reinforcement at
a lesser cost. The incentive provided is the right to take a draw in the lottery with a
chance to win a price varying from 0 to 1. Lottery and escalating incentives are more
effective in longer-term reinforcement (Petry et al., 2004; Cahill and Perera, 2009).
The HIV-interventions saw a mix of flat payments, lottery and escalating incentives.
Interventions that combined incentives with strengthened provider interaction,
support groups, information provision, skills building or other supportive interventions
were more successful to sustain behaviour after incentive provision ceased
(Chaisson et al., 1996; Corrigan and Bogner, 2007; Jochelson, 2007; Finkelstein et
al., 2008; Higgins et al., 2002, Kane et al., 2004a).
3.3.5. Incentive size
The success of the incentives depends on the size of the incentive. Determining the
exact threshold to inducing change is difficult (Lagarde et al, 2007; Volpp et al,
2009a). If the incentive is too high, the target group might not be motivated to
change behaviour but to earn the money (Higgins et al., 2002; Forde and Zeuner,
2009; Volpp et al.,2009; Kane et al, 2004; Volpp et al, 2008; Seaverson et al, 2009).
If the latter, after stopping the incentive, people will fall back in their old behaviour
(Kane et al, 2004; Volpp et al., 2008; Higgins et al, 2002). Lottery-type incentives
included in this study could grow very large. Flat and/or recurrent payments were
more modest ranging from 2 to 30 US$ per event. The HIV study in Tanzania linked
LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423
25
the payment of either US$30 or US$60 per year which is 7.5-15% of GDP and 12-
24% of the average annual income of participants54
. As a result, the STI infection
reduced (from 12 to 9%) and only for the higher incentive (Anonymous, 2010).
3.3.6. Incentive-provision: frequency and timing
Incentives should be distributed frequent enough to keep it ever-present in the minds
of the target group but not too frequent in order to contain costs (Medlin and
DeWalque, 2008). The studies included pay incentives for each successful
measurement. Frequency of payment can be daily in case of substance abuse
treatment, weekly, monthly, one-off payment, monthly or every four months. In case
of lotteries, big price draws are sometimes organised for the attainment of a ‘super-
goal’ on top of escalating incentives or regular lotteries. Reinforcement should be
applied as soon as possible following the target behaviour to establish a strong
contingent link (Haug and Sorensen, 2006; Stitzer et al., 2006; Medlin and
DeWalque, 2008). It is therefore necessary to define a target behaviour which is
close to the consequence and objectively quickly and cheaply measurable.
Frequency and timing are strongly linked to the magnitude of the incentive and the
expected behaviour. If the frequency is high and the target behaviour is wanted by
the target group, a lower incentive will suffice (Rigsby et al., 2000; Schroeder et al.,
2006; Volpp et al, 2008; Seaverson et al., 2009). If the target behaviour is wanted for
the public and frequency of reinforcement is lower55
, the incentive should be higher
(Bloch et al., 2006; Volpp et al., 2006; Volpp et al., 2009; Anonymous, 2010).
54
GDP in Tanzania was US$400 and the average annual income earned by participants in this study
was US$250. DTHF/IY pays half a day’s wage (ZAR 75 or US$10.22) to go for HIV-testing.
55
A reduction in sexual behaviour might not be a felt need by the targeted group (as is the case in
MSR). Therefore, more effort is necessary to convince them to change behaviour. If cost of
Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
26
3.3.7. Incentive duration
The studies show that incentives - as extrinsic motivators - are useful to initiate
behaviour change, though sustaining this behaviour after the incentive has stopped
will depend on whether the person is or has become intrinsically motivated and the
norms in his social network (Corrigan et al., 2005; Jochelson, 2007; Sorensen et al.,
2007; Volpp et al., 2008; Hanson et al., 2008; Rigsby et al., 2000; Petry et al., 2010).
Therefore it is necessary to focus on increasing the individual’s perception of skill,
competence and desire to change behaviour (Gaither et al., 2009). Self belief and
confidence to change are critical to sustain behaviour (Forde and Zeuner, 2009).
Of 20 included studies aiming at complex behaviour change, seven provided
incentives for 3 or less months of which six reported no or limited long-term
behaviour change56
. Incentive-provision for three months seems insufficient to
change complex behaviour. What the optimal time of reinforcement will depend on
the combination of all 7 principles of CM (Kellog et al., n.d.).
measurement is high, there is a need to have limited reinforcement moments or to otherwise pay
without measurement in some instances. Another option is to have intermediate steps (proxy
indicators) which are less distant and/or cheaper to measure.
56
No follow up was reported in the last study.
LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423
27
3.4. Ethical considerations
All studies retrieved justified paying an incentive from a public health or an economic
efficiency point of view. The economic rational to pay an incentive to go for HIV-
testing can be found in the fact that it creates positive externalities57
that warrant its
subsidy to maximize uptake by the population (Jepson et al, 2000; Childress et al.,
2002; Lagarde et al., 2009). At individual level, the picture is more complicated.
Annex 10 provides an overview of arguments found in the literature.
Looking at the four dimensions of humanity in health58
, the key issue to consider
here is how to ensure autonomy and informed uptake. If the incentive is too high,
MSR will not bother informing themselves about possible consequences. In that
case, to maximize utility, they should test. However, if the incentive is too low or non-
existent, MSR will not test. This can also not be termed as informed or autonomous
decision making seen the low level of correct knowledge and the high levels of
stigma. Thus the height of the incentive and the way the testing is provided will
determine whether autonomy and informed decision making is ensured.
57
Individual can access treatment earlier which leads to better treatment results. Testing positive has
shown to lead to behaviour change and possible reduction in rates of HIV-transmission.
58
Smith et al. (2005) distinguishes autonomy, dignity, beneficence and non-maleficence as the four
elements of humanity in health.
Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
28
4. Costing model results
The costing model was used to make calculations varying the chance to become
infected and loss to follow up as an effect of the incentive over time59
.
4.1. Number of men tested and HIV-infections averted
Since the uptake of testing increases due to the incentive and the loss to follow up is
estimated to be lower in this group, the average number of men that tests per year
will be higher compared to the control group. Because of this, even with lower
prevalence, more HIV-infections can be discovered. HIA can therefore even be
negative as shown in figure 4. Complete calculations for different (discounted) values
of p(i) and nl are included in Annex 11.
-500
0
500
1.000
1.500
2.000
2.500
1 2 3 4 5
Testers p(i)=0,15
Testers p(i)=0,00
HIA with p(i)=0.15
HIA with p(i)=0.00
Extra HIV+ with
p(i)=0.15
Figure 4: Number of testers, HIA and HIV+
59
Control group parameters p(c)=0.20, nl(c)=0.15, n(c)= 3696. Intervention group n(i)=4416. For
explanation of parameters and limitations, see Annex 5.
LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423
29
4.2. Cost of incentive provision
Figure 5 shows that costs of incentive per HIA rapidly increases after year 2, more
so for lower loss to follow up and bigger reductions in the chance to get infected
since more testers means more incentive costs.
0
500
1.000
1.500
2.000
2.500
3.000
3.500
4.000
4.500
5.000
1 2 3 4 5
Year
US$
HIA nl(i) = 0.10
p(i)=0.10
HIA nl(i) = 0.10 Disc.
p(i)=0.10
HIA nl(i) = 0.00
p(i)=0.10
HIA nl(i) = 0.00 Disc.
p(i)=0.10
Figure 5: Cost incentive provision / HIA
The average cost of incentive provision per HIA for p(i)=0.15 for different levels of
follow up in the first two years is US$8065. After this cost increases considerably,
since the number of HIA plummet. Average costs of incentive provision vary from
US$346 to US$95660
averaged over 2 years and US$351 to US$ 200961
over 5
years. For all calculations, see annex 12.
60
Nl(i)=0.10 and p(i)=0.00 (lowest) to nl(i)=0.00 and p(i)=0.10 (highest)
61
Nl(i)=0.10 and p(i)=0.00 (lowest) to nl(i)=0.00 and p(i)=0.10 (highest)
Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
30
4.3. Potential cost saving
Potential cost saving was calculated using treatment cost derived from Cape Town
plus the cost of incentive provision. Over time, potential cost saving per HIA slowly
increases. If an incentive is paid for two years, the average potential savings are
negative for p(i)=0.15 regardless which level of loss to follow up is chosen. This is
not the case when calculating average savings over 5 years. Highest average cost
savings per HIA of US$3472 over 2 years are found for p(i)=0.00 and nl(i)=0.00 for
1242 HIA. Over 5 years, the highest cost savings per HIA is US$6515 for p(i)=0.10
and nl(i)=0.00 but with 166 HIA. Annex 13 provides more detail.
4.4. One-way sensitivity analysis
Different levels of loss to follow up and chance to get infected for the intervention
group were presented above. Three other situations are modelled. The first assumes
that for both control and intervention, the number of men tested starts at 4800. The
second foresees an increase of the current incentive to a full-day salary (US$16.32)
to attract all the MSR and encourage follow-up visits even when labour is available
for the day. Lastly, a 6 month interval might be insufficient to reinforce behaviour
change so what happens when 4 tests need to be performed to achieve a chance in
behaviour. Loss to follow up in the intervention group was set at nl(i)=0.10.
Starting with the same number of men in each group leads to a reduction of average
cost of incentive provision per HIA since the total number of testers is higher and
because both groups have the same size now relatively more HIV+ men will be
LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423
31
discovered in the control group62
. Testing 4 times a year is only possible when
n=240063
. This results in a significantly higher number of HIA averted compared to
the original situation and thus to a lower cost of incentive provision per HIA. The
reason is however not the more intensive testing, but the fact that less men are
tested in the incentive situation thus less potential HIV+ cases are detected. The cost
of incentive provision per HIA is mostly influenced by variations in the cost of the
incentive itself. Cost presented in figure 6 are averaged over 2 years, cost over 5
years show a similar pattern.
0
200
400
600
800
1000
1200
1400
1600
p(i)=0.10 p(i)=0.05 p(i)=0.00
Different chances of infection
Averagecostofincentiveper
HIAUS$
Base situation
n=4800
Incentive US$16.32
4 tests
Figure 6: One-way sensitivity averaged over 2 years
This analysis shows that the model is responsive for changes in important
parameters and reacts as expected. The potential cost saving per HIA averaged
over 2 years strongly reduces from an average of about US$5.000 across different
values of p(i) to around US$3.000 for all scenarios. Calculation tables can be found
in Annex 14.
62
Model so far assumed differential intake based on the data from DTHF which saw an increased
utilization of the DTHF tester when an incentive is provided.
63
Full capacity of one mobile tester is 9600 tests per year.
Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
32
5. Discussion
5.1. Limitations
This research set out to explore whether providing incentive based HIV-testing for
men could be an effective64
way of HIV prevention. Although a variety of databases
were consulted and considerable time was spent searching literature, it is possible
that relevant publications (especially grey literature) were missed. Publication bias
might have resulted in a too positive impression if failed experiments were not
officially published. Several of the studies published had small numbers of
participants which might have affected the power of the research and thus its
conclusions. Assessing publications for inclusion in the research was done by only
one person which might have caused bias as well. The literature search found a very
limited number of studies referring to incentive provision and focussing on men, on
Africa and on HIV-related risk behaviour, let alone a combination of these three
elements.
The calculations made with the developed model were based on limited data. There
are real opportunities to expand the model by including the costs of mobile test
provision65
, mortality figures for both groups, differential initiation on ART66
, changing
infection risk over time67
, using real life data of a cohort of DTHF men68
and including
64
Effective is defined as increasing uptake of testing and reducing risky behavior measured by a
lower incidence of HIV.
65
When more people test, the unit cost per test decreases due to better capacity utilisation.
66
Now assumed that all testing HIV+ started ART. CD4 count information would be necessary to
include different initiation timing. Cleary et al. (2006) found mortality in the first year on ART. Ideally, in
the intervention group HIV would be detected earlier, resulting in later initiation on ART and lower
mortality once on ART compared to the control group.
67
Markov model is memoryless. It assumes that the chances to become infected will remain stable
over time.
68
Were not available in time to be included.
LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423
33
indirect HIA because of behaviour change of MSR69
. Including these details is
expected to result in a stronger case for incentive provision since cost ART provision
will be lower and higher utilisation leads to lower unit cost (Marseille et al., 2007) and
the number of HIA will be higher due to the effects outside the targeted population.
The adopted provider perspective does not include cost and benefits for the MSR or
the society as a whole. DTHF integrates both testing and treatment in its activities,
therefore cost saving could be included here in the provider model. An incentive is
not likely to be a cost-effective intervention for a stand-alone testing unit or a unit
with a separate budget since cost-savings will be made under another budget (Kahn
et al., 2006). Taking a broader perspective could accommodate this, but was not
possible in the available time and budget for this thesis.
5.2. Theories
According to behavioural economics, MSR will want to maximize utility and will not
change behaviour when the opportunity costs to do so are higher than maintaining
their behaviour. The incentive lowers the opportunity costs of HIV-testing. Men will
be able to overcome the barriers caused by stigma since the incentive appeals to the
most important role MSR identify for themselves – the breadwinner role (Indlu
Yegazi, 2009).
Regular return visits will allow the building of therapeutic alliance with the provider
thus internalizing this external motivation and reinforcing the ‘good’ behaviour. The
69
Kahn et al. (2006) mentions that each infected individual is responsible for one other new infection.
Thus one HIA directly prevented should actually count double. Seen the expected high risk behaviour
of MSR, the indirect-HIA might actually be higher than 1.
Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
34
risk-assessment format which is filled can help build the necessary skills. Thus
combining the incentive and regular DTHF HIV-testing provision will work on all
elements of the IMB model and make sustained behaviour change possible.
5.3. Screening uptake
The DTHF approach already brings testing close to the men, embedding it in a
comprehensive health check which will reduce stigma and opportunity costs of
utilisation. One-day testing plus the availability of an on-site CD4-count machine and
possibility to refer to a treatment program also contribute to high uptake. However,
the 2009 DTHF M&E data show that MSR are not effectively reached even with this
program. Paying an incentive can has attracted MARP in several other settings.
However, it is important to realize that it is the incentive that makes the MSR test for
HIV and not the intention to change behaviour70
. After enrolment, engaging the men
will be of key importance.
5.4. Incentivized schemes: Lessons learned
Targeting must be kept simple to avoid extra cost. In the DTHF/IY example, all MSR
are eligible to enrol at specific sites. This simple approach avoids problems at the
site, since it will be difficult to pay one person but not the next and is administratively
easy. But how do you treat a MSR coming for a follow up visit at a non-IY site? It is
probably more cost-effective to attach the incentive to the MSR and have vouchers
available in the Tutu tester at each testing site.
70
Pre-contemplative stage in the trans-theoretical theory of change (Fishbein and Guinan, 1996).
LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423
35
Uptake of HIV-testing is simple behaviour with a clear target which can be
immediately reinforced with a payment. Payment is made once, irrespective of the
testing result. Testing positive has shown to induce a positive behaviour change.
Since because of the incentive, more MSR will test, incentive provision will have a
public health impact. The expected behaviour change for those testing positive might
be less than otherwise observed since men will enrol in the pre-contemplative stage.
Using financial incentives to reduce risk behaviour in MSR is more complicated. First
of all, testing for HIV is not a good proxy for safe sexual behaviour since even with
unsafe sex the chance of contracting HIV is distant. The contingent link is weak. A
MSR might have engaged in unsafe sex, test negative and get an incentive plus the
message to change behaviour. By why would he? To ensure immediate
reinforcement, other proxies need to be chosen. The Tanzania study uses STI which
might be a better proxy, but providing immediate tests on site will be very expensive
(Anonymous, 2010). Payment of an incentive combined with other support activities
working on information, motivation and skills of people have shown promising results
(Villano et al., 2002; Gift et al., 2005; Jochelson, 2007). DTHF/IY could therefore
consider combining monthly visits for health education talks or peer support group
meetings with an incentive (possibly escalating) with a half yearly check up which in
the case of DTHF also includes testing for syphilis. Incentives for monthly visits could
be smaller especially if they are organised at times when the MSR do not work.
The incentive needs to be meaningful for the participant. The Tanzania study saw
behaviour change only in the arm which received 24% of the average annual income
of the participants (Anonymous, 2010). The Malawi example saw a change in
Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
36
behaviour with payments of 2 to 8% of monthly income. However, payments were
not to the main income-earner of the family and behaviour was to be avoided not
changed (Baird et al., 2009). DTHF/IY provides an incentive which is less than the
daily wage of MSR. Paying a full day’s wage will make going for testing a real choice
for MSR, not only those that did not get work. Although it is not likely that a lottery
approach will appeal to the target group, after an initial period of intensive contact
and establishing therapeutic alliance one can start playing around with the incentive
– increasing or decreasing it. This might allow reduction of payments over time.
It is assumed that after some time, behaviour is automated and/or motivation is
internalized. For complex behaviour change, 3 months of reinforcement is insufficient
and incentive provision alone will not suffice to change behaviour. Seen the possible
cost effectiveness of providing the incentives, one might ask why not pay the
incentive over a much longer time.
5.5. Ethics
DTHF/IY ensures informed uptake of testing through the pre- and post-test
counselling. After counselling MSR can decide not to the test. However, payment of
the incentive depends on doing the test (though not on the test result)71
. Men that
come to test, have no work for the day. Seen their economic situation, they need
money to keep themselves going. This will affect their freedom to choose to reject
the test. This however can be justified by the public health benefit of behaviour
change. For the individual, early detection of HIV virus through regular tests will
enhance treatment outcomes.
71
MSR testing positive are referred to the treatment program of DTHF.
LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423
37
5.6. Cost effectiveness
The calculation model suggests that incentive provision seems to be most cost-
effective after two years. After this, potential cost savings per HIA decrease while the
cost of incentive provision per HIA increase for all levels of p(i) and nl(i). With current
utilization levels, a reduction of p(i) to 0.15 will not be cost effective averaging
US$8065 for incentive provision and a negative potential cost saving.
The commission on macroeconomics and health recommends that when the cost of
an intervention per DALY is below the GDP per capita, it is very cost-effective
(Cleary et al., 2006). Combining VCT CE estimates and cost for mobile testing from
literature72
with the cost of incentive provision from the model, the total cost of VCT
per DALY using a high cost estimate for VCT ranges from US$233-USS$311 per
DALY for different values of p(i). A low cost estimate for VCT brings the total cost of
VCT per DALY at US$54 to US$132. Both are well below the GDP rate of South
Africa73
. Annex 15 provides the full calculations.
Seen the above, there is room to increase the value of the incentive and the
frequency of provision to attain low attrition and high reduction of chances to become
infected without affecting the cost-effectiveness of incentive provision.
72
A generalized CE estimate for VCT in sub-Saharan Africa reported US$1956/- per HIA (Galárraga
et al., 2009). Kahn et al. (2006) reported cost for testing per HIA from a South African Primary Health
Care unit at US$ 162. A Kenyan study found that mobile testing results in a US$17.54 extra cost per
test done (Grabbe et al., 2010).
73
The World Bank puts GDP per capita for South Africa at US$10,291 in 2009, accessed on 16 June
2010 from http://data.worldbank.org/country/south-africa.
Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
38
5.7. Conclusions
This research shows that while supply side activities are important, specific attention
to stimulate the demand for services by MARP is important. Incentive provision is
one way to reach them. But, even though CE is expected to be high, incentive
provision needs to be combined with intense follow up and behavioural interventions
to internalize motivation and sustain behaviour change. The approach however is
promising and needs further testing in order to design a less resource intensive but
effective approach which can be scaled up.
LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423
I
Literature
Adato M and Bassett L, 2008, What is the potential of cash transfers to strengthen families affected by
HIV and AIDS? A review of the evidence on impacts and key policy debates, Paper submitted
by IFPRI to learning group 1: Strengthening Families of the Joint Learning initiative on children
and HIV/AIDS (JLICA), co-chaired by Richter L and Sherr L.
Albarracín D, Gilette JC, Earl AN, Glasman LR, Durantini MR and Ho MH, 2005, A test of major
assumptions about behavior change: A comprehensive look at the effect of the passive and
active HIV-prevention interventions since the beginning of the epidemic, Psychol Bull. 2005;
131(6): 856-897
Alfers D and Butterfoss FD, 2000, Evaluation on a shoestring: key to success for Virginia prenatal
incentive program, Health Promotion Practice, 2000 Jul; 1 (3): 259-67
Anderson T, 2010, How can child and maternal mortality be cut?, BMJ 2010;340:c431, doi:
10.1136/bmj.c431
Anonymous, 2010, Result brief:: The RESPECT study – Evaluating Conditional cash transfers for
HIV/STI prevention in Tanzania, Downloaded on 27 September 2010 from
http://siteresources.worldbank.org/DEC/Resources/HIVExeSummary(Tanzania).pdf
Baggaley R, Bakobaki J, Brown M, Carter Francis J, Corbett E, Foster C, Glynn J, Grant A, Grassly N,
Grosskurth H, Hayman A, Martinez-Alier N, McDonald B, Moffatt C, Morison L, Nascimento MC,
Pittrof R, Platt L, Quigley M, De Silva S, Tanton C, Thomas E, Weiss H and Willley S, 2008,
Module ID501: AIDS – Study guide, London School of Hygiene and Tropical Medicine, UK.
Baird S, Chirwa E, McIntosh C and Özler B, 2009, The short-term impacts of a schooling conditional
cash transfer program on the sexual behavior of young women, World Bank Policy Research
Working paper No. 5089, The World Bank, Washington, USA.
Banerjee AV, Duflo E, Glennerster R and Kothari D, Improving immunisation coverage in rural India:
clustered randomised controlled evaluation of immunisation campaigns with and without
incentives, BMJ 340:doi:10.1136/bmj.c2220 (Published 17 May 2010))
Bassett, 2008, Can Conditional Cash Transfer Programs Play a greater role in reducing child
undernutrition, SP Discussion paper No.0835, WorldBank, Washington
Belli P, Anderson J, Barnum H, Dixon J and Tan J-P, 1998, Handbook on economic analysis of
investment operations, Operational Course Services Network Learning and Leadership Center
Bloch MJ, Armstrong DS, Dettling L, Hardy A, Caterino K and Barrie S, 2006, Partners in lowering
cholesterol: comparison of a multidisciplinary educational program, monetary incentives, or
usual care in the treatment of dyslipidemia identified among employees, Journal of occupational
and environmental medicine / American College of Occupational and Environmental Medicine
48: 7: 675-81.
Bock NN, Sales RM, Rogers T and DeVoe B, 2001, A spoonful of sugar...: improving adherence to
tuberculosis treatment using financial incentives, Int J Tuberc Lung Dis. 2001 Jan;5(1):96-8.
Brandon TH, Vidrine JL, Litvin EB, 2007, Relapse and relapse prevention, Annual Review Clinical
Psychology 2007;3:257-84
Burns T and Shaw J, 2007, Is it acceptable for people to be paid to adhere to medication?, BMJ 2007;
335: 232-233
Cahill K and Perera R, 2009, Competitions and incentives for smoking cessation, Cochrane Database of
Systematic Reviews: Reviews 2008 Issue 3 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd Chichester, UK DOI:
10.1002/14651858.CD004307.pub3
Carey MP, Vanable PA, Senn TE, Coury-Doniger P and Urban MA, 2005, Recruiting patients from a
sexually transmitted disease clinic to sexual risk reduction workshops: are monetary incentives
necessary? Journal of Public Health Management & Practice, 2005 Nov-Dec; 11 (6): 516-21
Chaisson RE, Barnes LG, Hackman J, Watkinson L, Kimbrough L, Metha S, Cavalcante S and Moore
Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
II
RD, 2001, A randomized Controlled trial of interventions to improve adherence to isoniazid
therapy to prevent tuberculosis in injection drug users, Am J Med. 2001;110:610-615
Chaisson RE, Keruly JC, McAvinue S, Gallant JE and Moore RD, 1996, Effects of an incentive and
education program on return rates for PPD test reading in patients with HIV infection, J Acquir
Immune Defic Syndr Hum Retrovirol. 1996 Apr 15;11(5):455-9.
Childress JF, Faden RR, Gaare RD, Gostin LO, Kahn J, Bonnie RJ, Kass NE, Mastroianni AC, Moreno
JD and Nieburg P, 2002, Public health ethics: Mapping the terrain, Journal of law, medicine and
ethics, 30 (2002): 170-178
Choe HM, Stevenson JG, Streetman DS, Heisler M, Sandiford CJ and Piette JD, 2007, Impact of patient
financial incentives on participation and outcomes in a statin pill-splitting program, Am J Manag
Care. 2007 Jun;13(6 Part 1):298-304
Claassen D, 2007, Financial incentives for antipsychotic depot medication: ethical issues, Journal of
Medical Ethics, 2007 Apr; 33 (4): 189-93
Cleary SM, Mcintyre D and Boulle AM, 2006, The cost-effectiveness of Antiretroviral Treatment in
Khayelitsha, South Africa – a primary data analysis, Cost effectiveness and Resources
allocation 2006, 4:20, doi:10.1186/1478-7547-4-20
Coates TJ, Richter L and Caceres C, 2008, Behavioural strategies to reduce HIV Transmission: how to
make them work better, Lancet DOI:10.1016/S0140-6736(08)60886-7, 36-51.
Corrigan JD and Bogner J, 2007, Interventions to promote retention in substance abuse treatment, Brain
Inj. 2007 Apr;21(4):343-56
Corrigan JD, Bogner J, Lamb-Hart G, Heinemann AW and Moore D, 2005, Increasing substance abuse
treatment compliance for persons with traumatic brain injury, Psychology of Addictive Behaviors.
19(2)(pp 131-139), 2005.
Day JH, Miyamura K, Grant AD, Leeuw A, Munsamy J, Baggaley R and Churchyard GJ, 2003, Attitudes
to HIV voluntary counselling and testing among mineworkers in South Africa: will availability of
antiretroviral therapy encourage testing?, AIDS Care, 15: 5, 65-672
Denison JA, Higgins DL and Sweat MD, 2009, HIV testing and counseling, In: Mayer KH and Pizer
HF(eds) HIV prevention: A comprehensive approach, Academic press, USA.
DeWalque D, Dow WH and Nathan R, 2010, Evaluating Conditional Cash transfers to prevent HIV and
other STIs in Tanzania, presentation at ASSA Meetings Atlanta.
DiClemente RJ, Crosby RA and Kegler MC, 2009, Emerging theories in health promotion, practice and
research, John Wiley and Sons, USA
Durantini MR and Albarracín D, 2009, Material and social incentives to participation in behavioral
interventions: A meta-analysis of gender disparities in enrollment and retention in experimental
human immunodeficiency Virus prevention interventions, Health Psychology 2009:28:5; 631-
640, American Psychological Association.
Eaton L, 2009, Trial that pays patients to take antipsychotic drugs comes under attack,
BMJ 2009;339:b4202, doi: 10.1136/bmj.b4202.
Eichler R, 2006, Can “Pay for Performance” increase utilization by the poor and improve the quality of
health services?, Discussion paper for the first meeting of the working group on Performance
Based Incentives, Center for Global Development
Elwy AR, Hart GJ, Hawkes S and Petticrew M, 2002, Effectiveness of interventions to prevent sexually
transmitted infections and human immunodeficiency virus in heterosexual men, Arch intern
med.vol 162, sep 9, 1818-1830
Family Health International, 2002, Behavior change – A summary of four major theories, AIDSCAP,
USA.
Finkelstein EA, Brown DS, Brown DR and Buchner DM, 2008, A randomized study of financial
incentives to increase physical activity among sedentary older adults, Preventive medicine 47:
2: 182-7
Fishbein M and Guinan M, 1996, Behavioral science and public health: A necessary partnership for HIV
LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423
III
prevention, Public Health Rep. 1996; 111(Suppl 1): 5–10.
Fisher JD, 2005, HIV Risk Behavior Change Interventions for Seropositives: Initial Ideas on Theory and
Practice, Presentation at 7th
International AIDS impact Conference, Cape Town, South Africa
FitzGerald JM, Patrick DM, Strathdee S, Rekart M, Elwood RK, Schecter MT, Montaner J and
O'Shaughnessy M, 1999, Use of incentives to increase compliance for TB screening in a
population of intravenous drug users. Vancouver Injection Drug Use Study Group, Int J Tuberc
Lung Dis. 1999 Feb;3(2):153-5
Forde I and Zeuner D, 2009, Financial incentives to promote social mobility, BMJ 2009;339:b3219, doi:
10.1136/bmj.b3219
Gaither P, Brown W, Metz D, Nelson C and Bjornaraa J, 2009, Healthy Incentives, Healthyroads Inc.
Galárraga O, Colchero MA, Wamai RG and Bertozzi SM, 2009, HIV prevention cost-effectiveness: a
systematic review, BMC Public Health 2009, 9 (Suppl I):S5, doi:10.1186/1471-2458-9-S1-S5
Ghitza UE, Epstein DH and Preston KL, 2008, Contingency management reduces injection-related HIV
risk behaviors in heroin and cocaine using outpatients, Addictive Behaviors, 2008 Apr; 33 (4):
593-604
Gift TL, Malotte CK, Ledsky R, Hogben M, Middlestadt S, Vandevanter NL, St Lawrence JS and GCAP
Study Group, 2005, A cost-effectiveness analysis of interventions to increase repeat testing in
patients treated for gonorrhea or chlamydia at public sexually transmitted disease clinics, Sex
Transm Dis. 2005 Sep;32(9):542-9.
Giuffrida A and Torgerson DJ, 1997, Should we pay the patient? Review of financial incentives to
enhance patient compliance, BMJ 1997;315:703-707
Glick P, 2005, Scaling up HIV voluntary counseling and testing in Africa; What can evaluation studies tell
us about potential prevention impacts?, Eval Review, 2005; 29(4): 331-57
Global HIV Prevention working group, 2008, Behaviour change and HIV prevention: (Re) considerations
for the 21st
century, accessed from www.globalhivprevention.org on 8 January 2010
Global HIV prevention working group, 2010, Global HIV prevention Progress report card 2010;
Executive summary, accessed from www.globalhivprevention.org on 29 August 2010.
Grabbe KL, Menzies N, Taegtmeyer M, Emukule G, Angala P, Mwega I, Musango G and Marum E,
2010, Increasing Access to HIV Counseling and Testing Through Mobile Services in Kenya:
Strategies, Utilization, and Cost-Effectiveness, J. Acquir Immune Defic Syndr. 2010 1;54(3):317-
23.
Hageman K, Tichacek A and Allen S, 2009, Couples’ voluntary counseling and testing, In: Mayer KH
and Pizer HF(eds) HIV prevention: A comprehensive approach, Academic press, USA.
Hagenzieker MP, Bijleveld FD, Davidse RJ, 1997, Effects of incentive programs to stimulate safety belt
use: a meta-analysis, Accident Analysis & Prevention, Volume 29, Issue 6, November 1997,
Pages 759-777
Halpern SD, 2005, Towards evidence based bioethics, BMJ 2005;331:901-903, doi:
10.1136/bmj.331.7521.901
Hanson T, Alessi SM and Petry NM, 2008, Contingency management reduces drug-related human
immunodeficiency virus risk behaviors in cocaine-abusing methadone patients, Addiction. 2008
Jul;103(7):1187-97. Epub 2008 May 20.
Harling G and Wood R, 2007, The evolving cost of HIV in South Africa: changes in health care cost with
duration on antiretroviral therapy for public sector patients, J Acquir Immune Defic Syndr. 2007
Jul 1;45(3):348-54.
Haug NA and Sorensen JL, 2006, Contingency management interventions for HIV-related behaviors,
Curr HIV/AIDS Rep. 2006 Nov;3(4):154-9..
Haukoos JS, Witt MD, Coil CJ and Lewis RJ, 2005, The effect of financial incentives on adherence with
outpatient human immunodeficiency virus testing referrals from the emergency department,
Acad Emerg Med. 2005 Jul;12(7):617-21
Heil SH, Higgins ST, Bernstein IM, Solomon LJ, Rogers RE, Thomas CS, Badger GJ and Lynch ME,
Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
IV
2008, Effects of voucher-based incentives on abstinence from cigarette smoking and fetal
growth among pregnant women, Addiction 103: 6: 1009-18
Higgins ST and Petry NM, 1999, Contingency management: Incentives for sobriety, Alcohol research
and Health, 1999, vol 23, no. 2:122-127
Higgins ST, Alessi SM and Dantona RL, 2002, Voucher-based incentives; A substance abuse treatment
innovation, Addictive behaviors 27(2002) 887-910
Higgins ST, Heil SH, Solomon LJ, Bernstein IM, Lussier JP, Abel RL, Lynch ME, Badger GJ, 2004, A
pilot study on voucher-based incentives to promote abstinence from cigarette smoking during
pregnancy and postpartum, Nicotine Tob Res. 2004 Dec;6(6):1015-20.
Holzemer WL and Uys LR, 2004, Managing AIDS Stigma, Journal of Social Aspects of HIV/AIDS, 2004,
1; 3; 165-170
Hutchinson PL and Mahlalela X, 2006, Utilization of voluntary counseling and testing services in the
Eastern Cape, South Africa, AIDS Care July 2006; 18(5):446-455
Hutchinson PL, Mahlalela X and Yukich J, 2007, Mass media, Stigma and diwsclosure of HIV test
results: Multilevel analysis in the Eastern Cape, South Africa, Aids education and prevention
2007, 19(6), 489-510
Indlu Yegazi, 2009, Program application (unpublished document)
Jepson R, Clegg A, Forbes C, Lewis R, Sowden A and Kleijnen J, 2000, The determinants of screening
uptake and interventions for increasing uptake: a systematic review, NHS Centre for reviews
and dissemination, University of York, UK
Jochelson K, 2007, Paying the patient: Improving health using financial incentives, King’s Fund, UK.
Johnson L and Budlender D, 2002, HIV Risk Factors: A review of the demographic, socio-economic,
biomedical and behavioural determinants of HIV prevalence in South Africa, Care Monograph
No.8, Centre for Actuarial Research (CARE), Cape Town.
Johnson L, Bradshaw D, Dorrington R and the South African Comparative Risk Assessment
Collaborating Group, 2007, The burdens of disease attributable to sexually transmitted
infections in South Africa in 2000, SAMJ 2007, Vol. 97, No.8; 658-662
Johnston L, O’Bra H, Chopra M, Mathews C, Townsend L, Sabin K, Tomlinson M, Kendall C, 2010, The
associations of voluntary counseling and testing acceptance and the perceived likelihood of
being HIV-infected among men with multiple sex partners in a South African Township, AIDS &
Behavior 2010; 14; 4; 922-931
Kahn JG, Marseille E and Auvert B, 2006, Cost-effectiveness of male circumcision for HIV prevention in
a South African setting, PLoS Medicine, 2006; 3;12; 2349-2358
Kalichman SC and Sambayi LC, 2003, HIV testing attitudes, AIDS stigma, and voluntary HIV
Counselling and testing in a black township in Cape Town, South Africa, Sex Transm Infect
2003;79:442-447
Kalichman SC, Cain D, Weinhardt L, Benotsch E, Presser K, Zweben A, Bjodstrup B and Swain GR,
2005, Experimental Components Analysis of Brief Theory-Based HIV/AIDS Risk-Reduction
Counseling for Sexually Transmitted Infection Patients, Health Psychology, Vol 24(2), Mar 2005,
198-208. doi: 10.1037/0278-6133.24.2.198
Kalichman SC, Simbayi LC, Cain D, Jooste S, Skinner D and Cherry C, 2006, Generalizing a model of
health behaviour change and AIDS stigma for use with sexually transmitted infection clinic
patients in Cape Town, South Africa, AIDS Care, 2006; 18(3):178-182
Kalichman SC, Simbayi LC, Cain D and Jooste S, 2008, Perceived HIV/AIDS Prevalence, burden and
risk, Cape Town, South Africa, American Journal of Health Behavior (AM J HEALTH BEHAV),
2008 Nov-Dec; 32(6): 693-700 (14 ref)
Kane RL, Johnson PE, Town RJ and Butler M, 2004, Economic incentives for preventive care, Evidence
report/Technology Assessment nr. 101, AHRQ Publication No.04-E024-2
Kane RL, Johnson PE, Town RJ, Butler M, 2004a, A structured review of the effect of economic
incentives on consumers' preventive behavior, American Journal of Preventive Medicine,
LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423
V
Volume 27, Issue 4, November 2004, Pages 327-352
Kelen GD, Hexter DA, Hansen KN, Humes R, Vigilance PN, Baskerville M and Quinn TC, 1996,
Feasibility of an emergency department-based, risk-targeted voluntary HIV screening program,
Ann Emerg Med. 1996 Jun;27(6):687-92
Kellog SH, Stitzer ML, Petry NM, Kreek MJ, no date, Contingency management: Foundation and
principles, unpublished document, downloaded from
http://www.nattc.org/pami/PDF/Contingency_Mgt_F_P.pdf on 27 September 2010
Kiene SM, Tennen H and Armeli S, 2008, Today I’ll use a condom, but who knows about tomorrow: A
daily process study of variability in predictors of condom use, Health Psychology 2008;
27(4):463-472
Lagarde M, Haines A and Palmer N, 2007, Conditional cash transfers for improving uptake of health
interventions in low-and middle income countries: A systematic review, JAMA. 2007; 298 (16):
1900-1910 (doi: 10.1001/jama.298.16.1900)
Lagarde M, Haines A and Palmer N, 2009, The impact of conditional cash transfers on health outcomes
and use of health services in low and middle income countries, Cochrane Database of
systematic reviews 2009, Issue 4 Art.no.: CD008137.
Leisegang R, Cleary S, Hislop M, Davidse A, Regensberg L, Little F and Maartens G, 2009, Early and
late direct costs in a Southern African Antiretroviral treatment programme; a retrospective cohort
analysis, Plos medicine 2009; 6; 12; e1000189
Lim SS, Dandona L, Hoisington JA, James SI, Hogan MC and Gakidou E, 2010, India’s Janani
Suraksha Yojana, a conditional cash transfer programme to increase births in health facilities:
an impact evaluation, Lancet 2010; 375: 2009-23
Loewenstein G, Brennan T and Volpp KG, 2007, Asymmetric paternalism to improve health behaviors,
JAMA 2007; 298 (20): 2415-2417.
Marseille E, Dandona L, Marshall N, Gaist P, Bautista-Arredondo S, Rollins B, Brtozzi SM, Coovadia J,
Saba J, Lioznov D, Du Plessis JA, Krupitsky E, Stanley N, Over M, Peryshkina A, Kumar SGP,
Muyingo S, Pitter C, Lundberg M and Kahn JG, 2007, HIV prevention costs and program scale:
data from the PANCEA project in five low and middle-income countries, BMC Health Services
Resarch 2007: 7: 108, accessed from http://www.biomedcentral.com/1472-6963/7/108 on 1
September 2010
Marteau TM, Ashcroft RE and Oliver A, 2009, Using financial incentives to achieve healthy behaviour,
BMJ 2009;338:b1415, doi: 10.1136/bmj.b1415
Mathers CD, Salomon JA, Ezzati M, Begg S, Vander Hoorn S, Lopez AD, 2006, Global burden of
disease and risk factors, chapter 5, http://www.dcp2.org/pubs/GBD/5/Section/864 accessed on 8
September 2010.
Mayor S, 2007, NICE proposes incentives to keep addicts free of drugs, BMJ 2007;334:229, doi:
10.1136/bmj.39112.429190.DB
Medlin C and DeWalque, 2008, Potential application of conditional cash transfers for prevention of
sexual transmitted infections and HIV in Sub-Saharan Africa, Policy research working paper
4673, World Bank, Washington.
Medlin C, Balkus J and Padian N, 2008, Developing minimum quality standards for HIV prevention
interventions, UNAIDS Geneva.
Mimiaga MJ, Reisner SL, Reilly L, Soroudi N and Safren SA, 2009, Individual interventions. In: Mayer
KH and Pizer HF(eds) HIV prevention: A comprehensive approach, Academic press, USA.
Morris SS, Flores R, Olinto P and Medina JM, 2004, Monetary incentives in primary health care and
effects on use and coverage of preventive health care interventions in rural Honduras: cluster
randomised trial, Lancet 2004; 364; 9450: 2030-2037
Munro S, Lewin S, Swart T and Volmink J., 2007, A review of health behaviour theories: how useful are
these for developing interventions to promote long-term medication adherence for TB and
HIV/AIDS, BMC Public health 2007, 7:104
NDOH - National Department of Health South Africa, 2008, The national HIV and Syphilis prevalence
Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
VI
survey South Africa 2007, South Africa
Nyanzi-Wakholi B, Lara AM, Watera C, Munderi P, Gilks C and Grosskurth H, 2009, The role of HIV
testing, counselling and treatment in coping with HIV/AIDS in Uganda: a qualitative analysis,
AIDS Care, 21:7, 903-908
O’Donnell L, Bonaparte B, Joseph H, Agronick G, McLean LD, Myint-U A and Stueve A, 2009, Keep it
up: development of a community-based helath screening and HIV prevention strategy for
reaching young African men, AIDS Education and Prevention, 21(4), 299-313
Oliver A, 2009, Can financial incentives improve health equity? BMJ 2009;339:b3847, doi:
10.1136/bmj.b3847
Peltzer K, Matseke G, Mzolo T and Majaja M, 2009, Determinants of knowledge of HIV status in South
Africa: results from a population-based HIV survey, BMC Public Health 2009, 9:174,
doi:10.1186/1471-2458-9-174
Petry NM, 2010, Contingency management treatment: controversies and challenges, Addiction 2010;
105; 1507
Petry NM, Martin B and Finocche C, 2001, Contingency management in group treatment: a
demonstration project in an HIV drop-in center, Subst Abuse Treat. 2001 Sep;21(2):89-96.
Petry NM, Tedord J, Austin M, Nick C, Caroll KM and Rounsaville BJ, 2004, Prize reinforcement
contingency management for treating cocaine users; how low can we go, and with whom?,
Addiction; 99; 349-360.
Petry NM, Weinstock J, Alessi SM, Lewis MW and Dieckhaus K, 2010, Group-based randomized trial of
contingencies for health and abstinence in HIV patients, J Consult Clin Psychol. 2010
Feb;78(1):89-97.
Pilling S, Strang J and Gerada C, 2007, Psychosocial interventions and opioid detoxification for drug
misuse: summary of NICE guidance, BMJ 2007;335:203-205, doi:
10.1136/bmj.39265.639641.AD
Pisani E, 2008, The wisdom of whores, W.w. Norton and Company, New York (USA)
Powers CL, Mathu-Muju KR and Bush HM, 2009, Effect of a financial incentive on returning for post-
operative care following general anesthesia, J Clin Pediatr Dent 33(4):374-350
Razavi MS, Gaumer G and Wallack S (eds), 2009, What is known about demand and other related
interventions to improve access and strengthen health care systems in low- and middle income
countries?, Schneider Institutes for Health policy, Brandeis University, USA.
Rigsby MO, Rosen MI, Beauvais JE, Cramer JA, Rainey PM, O'Malley SS, Dieckhaus KD and
Rounsaville BJ , 2000, Cue-dose training with monetary reinforcement; pilot study of an
antiretroviral adherence intervention, J. Gen Intern Med 2000;15:841-847
Roll JM, Petry NM, Stitzer ML, Brecht ML, Peirce JM, McCann MJ, Blaine J, MacDonald M, DIMaria J,
Lucero L and Kellog S, 2006, Contingency management for the treatment of methamphetamine
use disorders, Am. J. Psychiatry, 2006; 163; 1993-1999.
Rosen MI, Dieckhaus K, McMahon TJ, Valdes B, Petry NM, Cramer J and Rounsaville B, 2007,
Improved adherence with contingency management, AIDS Patient Care & STDs, 2007 Jan; 21
(1): 30-40
Rutledge SE, Roffman RA, Picciano JF, Kalichman SC and Berghuis JP, 2002, HIV prevention and
attrition: Challenges and Opportunities, AIDS & Behavior, 2002 Mar; 6(1): 69-82 (63 ref)
Sanderson C and Gruen R, 2006, Analytical models for decision making, Open University Press,
LSHTM.
Schafer M, 2010, Using conditional cash transfers to control sexual transmitted infections and HIV,
Discussion papers on Social protection, Issue no. 5, GTZ.
Schmidt H, Gerber A and Stock S, 2009, What can we learn from German health incentive schemes?,
BMJ 2009;339:b3504, doi: 10.1136/bmj.b3504
Schroeder JR, Epstein DH, Umbricht A and Preston KL, 2006, Changes in HIV risk behaviors among
patients receiving combined pharmacological and behavioral interventions for heroin and
LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423
VII
cocaine dependence, Addict Behav. 2006 May;31(5):868-79. Epub 2005 Aug 8.
Seaverson EL, Grossmeier J, Miller TM and Anderson DR, 2009, The role of incentive design, incentive
value, communications strategy, and worksite culture on health risk assessment participation,
Am J Health Promot. 2009 May-Jun;23(5):343-52
Shisana O, Rehle T, Simbayi L, Zuma K, Jooste S and Pillay-van-Wyk V, 2009, South African National
HIV prevalence, incidence, behaviour and communication survey 2008: A turning tide among
teenagers? HSRC, Cape Town.
Sindelar J, Elbel B and Petry NM, 2007, What do we get for our money? Cost-effectiveness of adding
contingency management, Addiction, 2007 Feb; 102 (2): 309-16
Smith S, Sinclair D, Raine R and Reeves B, 2005, Health care evaluation, Open University Press,
LSHTM.
Sorensen JL, Haug NA, Delucchi KL, Gruber V, Kletter E, Batki SL, Tulsky JP, Barnett P and Hall S,
2007, Voucher reinforcement improves medication adherence in HIV-positive methadone
patients: a randomized trial, Drug and Alcohol Dependence 88 (2007) 54–63
Steinberg J, 2008, Three letter plague: A young men’s journey through a great epidemic, Jonathan Ball
Publishers, Johannesburg.
Stitzer ML and Petry NM, 2006, Contingency management for treatment of substance abuse, Annual
Review Clinical Psychology 2; 411-431.
Stone EG, Morton SC, Hulscher ME, Maglione MA, Roth EA, Grimshaw JM, Mittman BS, Rubenstein
LV, Rubenstein LZ and Shekelle PG, 2002, Interventions that increase use of adult
immunization and cancer screening services: A meta-analysis, Annals of Internal Medicine.
136(9)(pp 641-651), 2002.
Szmukler G, 2009, Financial incentives for patients in the treatment of psychosis, J Med Ethics 2009,
35:224-228
Tulsky JP, Pilote L, Hahn JA, Zolopa AJ, Burke M, Chesney M and Moss AR, 2000, Adherence to
isoniazid prophylaxis in the homeless: a randomized controlled trial, Archives of internal
medicine 160: 5: 697-702
UNAIDS and WHO, 2004, Policy statement on HIV Testing, 2004, Geneva
UNAIDS, 1999, Sexual behavior change for HIV: Where have theories taken us?, Geneva.
UNAIDS, 2000, Costing guidelines for HIV prevention strategies, Geneva.
UNAIDS, WHO and UNICEF, 2009, Towards Universal Access – Progress report, Geneva (Switzerland)
Valdiserri RO, Ogden LL and McCray E, 2003, Accomplishments in HIV prevention science: implications
for stemming the epidemic, Nature Medicine (2003), Vol 9: no 7: 881-886
Villano CL, Rosenblum A, Magura S and Fong C, 2002, Improving treatment engagement and outcomes
for cocaine-using methadone patients, The American Journal of Drug and Alcohol Abuse, 28; 2;
213-230
Volmink J and Garner P, 1997, Systematic review of randomised controlled trials of strategies to
promote adherence to tuberculosis treatment, BMJ 1997;315:1403-1406
Volpp KG, 2009, Paying people to loose weight and stop smoking, LDI Issue brief vol 14, no. 3, Leonard
Davis Institute of Health Economics
Volpp KG, John LK, Troxel AB, Norton L, Fassbender J and Loewenstein G, 2008a, Financial incentive-
based approaches for weight loss: a randomized trial, JAMA : the journal of the American
Medical Association; 2008; 300: 22: 2631-7
Volpp KG, Levy AG, Asch DA, Berlin JA, Murphy JJ, Gomez A, Sox H, Zhu J and Lerman C, 2006, A
randomized controlled trial of financial incentives for smoking cessation, Cancer Epidemiol
Biomarkers Prev 2006; 15(1):12-8
Volpp KG, Loewenstein G, Troxel AB, Doshi J, Price M, Laskin M and Kimmel SE, 2008, A test of
financial incentives to improve warfarin adherence, BMC Health Services Research. 8, 2008.
Article Number: 272.
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men
Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men

More Related Content

What's hot

Experiences in Outsourcing Nonclinical Services Among Public Hospitals in Bot...
Experiences in Outsourcing Nonclinical Services Among Public Hospitals in Bot...Experiences in Outsourcing Nonclinical Services Among Public Hospitals in Bot...
Experiences in Outsourcing Nonclinical Services Among Public Hospitals in Bot...HFG Project
 
The Effect of Economic Inequality of Voter Turnout in Canadian Federal Electi...
The Effect of Economic Inequality of Voter Turnout in Canadian Federal Electi...The Effect of Economic Inequality of Voter Turnout in Canadian Federal Electi...
The Effect of Economic Inequality of Voter Turnout in Canadian Federal Electi...Kathryn Wesley
 
Cost-Benefit Analysis of Outsourcing Cleaning Services at Mahalapye Hospital,...
Cost-Benefit Analysis of Outsourcing Cleaning Services at Mahalapye Hospital,...Cost-Benefit Analysis of Outsourcing Cleaning Services at Mahalapye Hospital,...
Cost-Benefit Analysis of Outsourcing Cleaning Services at Mahalapye Hospital,...HFG Project
 
Rebecca Pointer Final MA thesis
Rebecca Pointer Final MA thesisRebecca Pointer Final MA thesis
Rebecca Pointer Final MA thesisRebecca Pointer
 
Tracking Universal Health Coverage
Tracking Universal Health CoverageTracking Universal Health Coverage
Tracking Universal Health CoverageFabio Castaño
 

What's hot (8)

Experiences in Outsourcing Nonclinical Services Among Public Hospitals in Bot...
Experiences in Outsourcing Nonclinical Services Among Public Hospitals in Bot...Experiences in Outsourcing Nonclinical Services Among Public Hospitals in Bot...
Experiences in Outsourcing Nonclinical Services Among Public Hospitals in Bot...
 
Eia and the aims of the book
Eia and the aims of the bookEia and the aims of the book
Eia and the aims of the book
 
The Effect of Economic Inequality of Voter Turnout in Canadian Federal Electi...
The Effect of Economic Inequality of Voter Turnout in Canadian Federal Electi...The Effect of Economic Inequality of Voter Turnout in Canadian Federal Electi...
The Effect of Economic Inequality of Voter Turnout in Canadian Federal Electi...
 
Cost-Benefit Analysis of Outsourcing Cleaning Services at Mahalapye Hospital,...
Cost-Benefit Analysis of Outsourcing Cleaning Services at Mahalapye Hospital,...Cost-Benefit Analysis of Outsourcing Cleaning Services at Mahalapye Hospital,...
Cost-Benefit Analysis of Outsourcing Cleaning Services at Mahalapye Hospital,...
 
PO3DIS PDF
PO3DIS PDFPO3DIS PDF
PO3DIS PDF
 
Thesis458
Thesis458Thesis458
Thesis458
 
Rebecca Pointer Final MA thesis
Rebecca Pointer Final MA thesisRebecca Pointer Final MA thesis
Rebecca Pointer Final MA thesis
 
Tracking Universal Health Coverage
Tracking Universal Health CoverageTracking Universal Health Coverage
Tracking Universal Health Coverage
 

Viewers also liked

La utilización le las herramienta ofimáticas en el ámbito estudiantil univers...
La utilización le las herramienta ofimáticas en el ámbito estudiantil univers...La utilización le las herramienta ofimáticas en el ámbito estudiantil univers...
La utilización le las herramienta ofimáticas en el ámbito estudiantil univers...Sthefy Zavala
 
Blue Brick Says Hi 2017 - Product Development for Startups
Blue Brick Says Hi 2017 - Product Development for StartupsBlue Brick Says Hi 2017 - Product Development for Startups
Blue Brick Says Hi 2017 - Product Development for StartupsTom Kaczmarczyk
 
Martín Miguel de Güemes
Martín Miguel de Güemes Martín Miguel de Güemes
Martín Miguel de Güemes Valeria Sanchez
 
Արտազատության մասին
Արտազատության մասինԱրտազատության մասին
Արտազատության մասինgexarvest
 
Выставка
ВыставкаВыставка
Выставкаrsvsite
 
167460 2016-specimen-paper-4
167460 2016-specimen-paper-4167460 2016-specimen-paper-4
167460 2016-specimen-paper-4Omniya Jay
 
Células sanguíneas y transitorias del tejido conjuntivo
Células sanguíneas y transitorias del tejido conjuntivoCélulas sanguíneas y transitorias del tejido conjuntivo
Células sanguíneas y transitorias del tejido conjuntivoSylvie C.
 
Laparotomia Exploratoria Bovina
Laparotomia Exploratoria Bovina Laparotomia Exploratoria Bovina
Laparotomia Exploratoria Bovina Eduardo Martinez
 
Silicosis
SilicosisSilicosis
SilicosisLuzy147
 

Viewers also liked (15)

La utilización le las herramienta ofimáticas en el ámbito estudiantil univers...
La utilización le las herramienta ofimáticas en el ámbito estudiantil univers...La utilización le las herramienta ofimáticas en el ámbito estudiantil univers...
La utilización le las herramienta ofimáticas en el ámbito estudiantil univers...
 
Blue Brick Says Hi 2017 - Product Development for Startups
Blue Brick Says Hi 2017 - Product Development for StartupsBlue Brick Says Hi 2017 - Product Development for Startups
Blue Brick Says Hi 2017 - Product Development for Startups
 
Martín Miguel de Güemes
Martín Miguel de Güemes Martín Miguel de Güemes
Martín Miguel de Güemes
 
Tuberculosis 57
Tuberculosis 57Tuberculosis 57
Tuberculosis 57
 
Արտազատության մասին
Արտազատության մասինԱրտազատության մասին
Արտազատության մասին
 
Выставка
ВыставкаВыставка
Выставка
 
Sae pronto unic
Sae pronto unicSae pronto unic
Sae pronto unic
 
167460 2016-specimen-paper-4
167460 2016-specimen-paper-4167460 2016-specimen-paper-4
167460 2016-specimen-paper-4
 
AXONIM Devices presentation
AXONIM Devices presentationAXONIM Devices presentation
AXONIM Devices presentation
 
Manejo de datos en investigacion clinica. Aspectos éticos y legales
Manejo de datos en investigacion clinica. Aspectos éticos y legalesManejo de datos en investigacion clinica. Aspectos éticos y legales
Manejo de datos en investigacion clinica. Aspectos éticos y legales
 
Células sanguíneas y transitorias del tejido conjuntivo
Células sanguíneas y transitorias del tejido conjuntivoCélulas sanguíneas y transitorias del tejido conjuntivo
Células sanguíneas y transitorias del tejido conjuntivo
 
Balkan pharma markets
Balkan pharma marketsBalkan pharma markets
Balkan pharma markets
 
Laparotomia Exploratoria Bovina
Laparotomia Exploratoria Bovina Laparotomia Exploratoria Bovina
Laparotomia Exploratoria Bovina
 
Silicosis
SilicosisSilicosis
Silicosis
 
Tuberculosis: diagnóstico
Tuberculosis: diagnósticoTuberculosis: diagnóstico
Tuberculosis: diagnóstico
 

Similar to Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men

Advancing Effective Communication, Cultural Competence, and Patient and Famil...
Advancing Effective Communication, Cultural Competence, and Patient and Famil...Advancing Effective Communication, Cultural Competence, and Patient and Famil...
Advancing Effective Communication, Cultural Competence, and Patient and Famil...ksllnc
 
Nationwide Interoperability Roadmap draft version 1.0
Nationwide Interoperability Roadmap draft version 1.0Nationwide Interoperability Roadmap draft version 1.0
Nationwide Interoperability Roadmap draft version 1.0Ed Dodds
 
Health care interoperability roadmap released by HHS ONC
Health care interoperability roadmap released by HHS ONCHealth care interoperability roadmap released by HHS ONC
Health care interoperability roadmap released by HHS ONCDavid Sweigert
 
E-Health - Enabler for Australia\'s Healthcare Reform
E-Health - Enabler for Australia\'s Healthcare ReformE-Health - Enabler for Australia\'s Healthcare Reform
E-Health - Enabler for Australia\'s Healthcare Reformbartlettc
 
ICTs_for_Child_Protection_Case_Management_Research_HealthEnabled
ICTs_for_Child_Protection_Case_Management_Research_HealthEnabledICTs_for_Child_Protection_Case_Management_Research_HealthEnabled
ICTs_for_Child_Protection_Case_Management_Research_HealthEnabledwcphilbrick
 
2 supplementary-webappendix-if-lancet-paper
2 supplementary-webappendix-if-lancet-paper2 supplementary-webappendix-if-lancet-paper
2 supplementary-webappendix-if-lancet-paperIndonesia AIDS Coalition
 
2 supplementary-webappendix-if-lancet-paper
2 supplementary-webappendix-if-lancet-paper2 supplementary-webappendix-if-lancet-paper
2 supplementary-webappendix-if-lancet-paperIndonesia AIDS Coalition
 
ENERGY CONSUMPTION AND REAL GDP IN ASEAN.pdf
ENERGY CONSUMPTION AND REAL GDP IN ASEAN.pdfENERGY CONSUMPTION AND REAL GDP IN ASEAN.pdf
ENERGY CONSUMPTION AND REAL GDP IN ASEAN.pdfHanaTiti
 
A Comparative Analysis of Financial Inclusion A Study of Nigeria and the UK.pdf
A Comparative Analysis of Financial Inclusion  A Study of Nigeria and the UK.pdfA Comparative Analysis of Financial Inclusion  A Study of Nigeria and the UK.pdf
A Comparative Analysis of Financial Inclusion A Study of Nigeria and the UK.pdfSophia Diaz
 
36648_The Intelligent Board 2006 (Dr Foster)
36648_The Intelligent Board 2006 (Dr Foster)36648_The Intelligent Board 2006 (Dr Foster)
36648_The Intelligent Board 2006 (Dr Foster)Hilary Rowell
 
Sion Pickering - Masters Dissertation - 19.04.2016
Sion Pickering - Masters Dissertation - 19.04.2016Sion Pickering - Masters Dissertation - 19.04.2016
Sion Pickering - Masters Dissertation - 19.04.2016Sion Pickering
 
Undeniable Facts About Paper Writer And How It Can Affect You
Undeniable Facts About Paper Writer And How It Can Affect YouUndeniable Facts About Paper Writer And How It Can Affect You
Undeniable Facts About Paper Writer And How It Can Affect YouCourtney Bennett
 
Economic Evaluation of Nationally Scaled Point-of-Care Diagnostic Platforms f...
Economic Evaluation of Nationally Scaled Point-of-Care Diagnostic Platforms f...Economic Evaluation of Nationally Scaled Point-of-Care Diagnostic Platforms f...
Economic Evaluation of Nationally Scaled Point-of-Care Diagnostic Platforms f...HFG Project
 
HFG Project TB Strategic Purchasing Activity: Malawi Assessment Technical Report
HFG Project TB Strategic Purchasing Activity: Malawi Assessment Technical ReportHFG Project TB Strategic Purchasing Activity: Malawi Assessment Technical Report
HFG Project TB Strategic Purchasing Activity: Malawi Assessment Technical ReportHFG Project
 
Health insurance-2012 acharya-report
Health insurance-2012 acharya-reportHealth insurance-2012 acharya-report
Health insurance-2012 acharya-reportDr Lendy Spires
 
HBS Management Challenge - Telemedicine for Prisons Final
HBS Management Challenge - Telemedicine for Prisons FinalHBS Management Challenge - Telemedicine for Prisons Final
HBS Management Challenge - Telemedicine for Prisons FinalSitul Shah
 

Similar to Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men (20)

Advancing Effective Communication, Cultural Competence, and Patient and Famil...
Advancing Effective Communication, Cultural Competence, and Patient and Famil...Advancing Effective Communication, Cultural Competence, and Patient and Famil...
Advancing Effective Communication, Cultural Competence, and Patient and Famil...
 
Nationwide Interoperability Roadmap draft version 1.0
Nationwide Interoperability Roadmap draft version 1.0Nationwide Interoperability Roadmap draft version 1.0
Nationwide Interoperability Roadmap draft version 1.0
 
Health care interoperability roadmap released by HHS ONC
Health care interoperability roadmap released by HHS ONCHealth care interoperability roadmap released by HHS ONC
Health care interoperability roadmap released by HHS ONC
 
E-Health - Enabler for Australia\'s Healthcare Reform
E-Health - Enabler for Australia\'s Healthcare ReformE-Health - Enabler for Australia\'s Healthcare Reform
E-Health - Enabler for Australia\'s Healthcare Reform
 
ICTs_for_Child_Protection_Case_Management_Research_HealthEnabled
ICTs_for_Child_Protection_Case_Management_Research_HealthEnabledICTs_for_Child_Protection_Case_Management_Research_HealthEnabled
ICTs_for_Child_Protection_Case_Management_Research_HealthEnabled
 
2 supplementary-webappendix-if-lancet-paper
2 supplementary-webappendix-if-lancet-paper2 supplementary-webappendix-if-lancet-paper
2 supplementary-webappendix-if-lancet-paper
 
2 supplementary-webappendix-if-lancet-paper
2 supplementary-webappendix-if-lancet-paper2 supplementary-webappendix-if-lancet-paper
2 supplementary-webappendix-if-lancet-paper
 
43661_en
43661_en43661_en
43661_en
 
ENERGY CONSUMPTION AND REAL GDP IN ASEAN.pdf
ENERGY CONSUMPTION AND REAL GDP IN ASEAN.pdfENERGY CONSUMPTION AND REAL GDP IN ASEAN.pdf
ENERGY CONSUMPTION AND REAL GDP IN ASEAN.pdf
 
A Comparative Analysis of Financial Inclusion A Study of Nigeria and the UK.pdf
A Comparative Analysis of Financial Inclusion  A Study of Nigeria and the UK.pdfA Comparative Analysis of Financial Inclusion  A Study of Nigeria and the UK.pdf
A Comparative Analysis of Financial Inclusion A Study of Nigeria and the UK.pdf
 
36648_The Intelligent Board 2006 (Dr Foster)
36648_The Intelligent Board 2006 (Dr Foster)36648_The Intelligent Board 2006 (Dr Foster)
36648_The Intelligent Board 2006 (Dr Foster)
 
Sion Pickering - Masters Dissertation - 19.04.2016
Sion Pickering - Masters Dissertation - 19.04.2016Sion Pickering - Masters Dissertation - 19.04.2016
Sion Pickering - Masters Dissertation - 19.04.2016
 
Undeniable Facts About Paper Writer And How It Can Affect You
Undeniable Facts About Paper Writer And How It Can Affect YouUndeniable Facts About Paper Writer And How It Can Affect You
Undeniable Facts About Paper Writer And How It Can Affect You
 
Economic Evaluation of Nationally Scaled Point-of-Care Diagnostic Platforms f...
Economic Evaluation of Nationally Scaled Point-of-Care Diagnostic Platforms f...Economic Evaluation of Nationally Scaled Point-of-Care Diagnostic Platforms f...
Economic Evaluation of Nationally Scaled Point-of-Care Diagnostic Platforms f...
 
Official_ERM_Project
Official_ERM_ProjectOfficial_ERM_Project
Official_ERM_Project
 
HFG Project TB Strategic Purchasing Activity: Malawi Assessment Technical Report
HFG Project TB Strategic Purchasing Activity: Malawi Assessment Technical ReportHFG Project TB Strategic Purchasing Activity: Malawi Assessment Technical Report
HFG Project TB Strategic Purchasing Activity: Malawi Assessment Technical Report
 
Health insurance-2012 acharya-report
Health insurance-2012 acharya-reportHealth insurance-2012 acharya-report
Health insurance-2012 acharya-report
 
43653_en
43653_en43653_en
43653_en
 
HBS Management Challenge - Telemedicine for Prisons Final
HBS Management Challenge - Telemedicine for Prisons FinalHBS Management Challenge - Telemedicine for Prisons Final
HBS Management Challenge - Telemedicine for Prisons Final
 
Unfolding Algorithms
Unfolding AlgorithmsUnfolding Algorithms
Unfolding Algorithms
 

More from Jennie van de Weerd

Rapport contre vérification avril-mai 2015 projet 108050
Rapport contre vérification avril-mai 2015 projet 108050Rapport contre vérification avril-mai 2015 projet 108050
Rapport contre vérification avril-mai 2015 projet 108050Jennie van de Weerd
 
Using financial incentives to increase testing uptake versie 2
Using financial incentives to increase testing uptake versie 2Using financial incentives to increase testing uptake versie 2
Using financial incentives to increase testing uptake versie 2Jennie van de Weerd
 
The district response initiative on HIV AIDS Action Research - National synth...
The district response initiative on HIV AIDS Action Research - National synth...The district response initiative on HIV AIDS Action Research - National synth...
The district response initiative on HIV AIDS Action Research - National synth...Jennie van de Weerd
 
van de Weerd J 1995 Evaluatie doorstroomprogramma Huishoud en Consumentenwete...
van de Weerd J 1995 Evaluatie doorstroomprogramma Huishoud en Consumentenwete...van de Weerd J 1995 Evaluatie doorstroomprogramma Huishoud en Consumentenwete...
van de Weerd J 1995 Evaluatie doorstroomprogramma Huishoud en Consumentenwete...Jennie van de Weerd
 

More from Jennie van de Weerd (6)

9912 Arsenic prevention sticker
9912 Arsenic prevention sticker9912 Arsenic prevention sticker
9912 Arsenic prevention sticker
 
99 HE message 18DTP
99 HE message 18DTP99 HE message 18DTP
99 HE message 18DTP
 
Rapport contre vérification avril-mai 2015 projet 108050
Rapport contre vérification avril-mai 2015 projet 108050Rapport contre vérification avril-mai 2015 projet 108050
Rapport contre vérification avril-mai 2015 projet 108050
 
Using financial incentives to increase testing uptake versie 2
Using financial incentives to increase testing uptake versie 2Using financial incentives to increase testing uptake versie 2
Using financial incentives to increase testing uptake versie 2
 
The district response initiative on HIV AIDS Action Research - National synth...
The district response initiative on HIV AIDS Action Research - National synth...The district response initiative on HIV AIDS Action Research - National synth...
The district response initiative on HIV AIDS Action Research - National synth...
 
van de Weerd J 1995 Evaluatie doorstroomprogramma Huishoud en Consumentenwete...
van de Weerd J 1995 Evaluatie doorstroomprogramma Huishoud en Consumentenwete...van de Weerd J 1995 Evaluatie doorstroomprogramma Huishoud en Consumentenwete...
van de Weerd J 1995 Evaluatie doorstroomprogramma Huishoud en Consumentenwete...
 

Using financial incentives to increase HIV testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men

  • 1. Project report Using financial incentives to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men Masters in Public Health – Health System Management Candidate number: T6423 Jennie van de Weerd Submitted: 30 September 2010 Word count: 6963
  • 2.
  • 3. LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423 i Abstract Introduction Treatment will not stop the HIV epidemic in South Africa, but needs to be combined with cost-effective approaches to prevention for those hardest to reach. This research explores whether paying incentives could increase uptake of HIV-testing and behaviour change for daily labourers living in informal settlements in Cape Town. Method A literature review brought together 128 articles about behaviour change theories and economics, HIV-testing uptake, examples incentive paying schemes and ethics involved in paying incentives to patients. A calculation model looked at CE for incentive provision per HIA and potential cost saving per HIA. Results The IBM-model and behavioural economics provide concepts to explain why paying an incentive is effective. Motivation seems the most important factor to explain testing enrolment. Stigma and risk perception need addressing by provision of information and skills. Although incentive provision for simple tasks has shown results, limited evidence exists to support incentive payment for complex behaviour change. Careful balancing of the 7 elements of contingency management and the combination of incentive provision with behavioural interventions is called for while autonomy of the client should be considered. The extra cost of incentive provision can be justified by the potential cost savings in treatment.
  • 4. Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men ii Discussion The case for incentive provision for uptake of HIV-testing is clear, but not for behaviour change. The contingent link between sexual behaviour and HIV at individual level is weak. Incentive provision should therefore be combined with behavioural interventions and alternative reinforcements. The potential cost- effectiveness of incentive provision warrants further research.
  • 5. LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423 iii Foreword Today, I can only be happy to zip this document and upload it to the London School Website over the remains of my crashed laptop, using a laptop gracefully provided by the ICT department of my employer. My husband and children will be equally happy, since it will mean that I can participate again in our family life. And, it is high time to rediscover my friends and colleagues. All in all, writing this report was a heavy but interesting journey which made me grow. Charles Maisel of Indlu Yegazi and Nienke van Schaik en Linda Gail-Bekker of Desmond Tutu HIV Foundation (Tutu tester) triggered me to start this journey. I want to thank them for their support and wish them success in their on-going work. I would like to thank Piya Hanvoravongchai, my supervisor, and the PH project support team of LSHTM for pointing me in the right direction when I almost lost the way. Last but not least, I would like to thank the authors that sent their articles when requested and Nadine Pakker who made it possible to gather most of my data.
  • 6. Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men iv Table of contents Abstract ...................................................................................... i Foreword....................................................................................iii List of tables and figures ..............................................................vi Tables in Annex...........................................................................vi List of Abbreviations ...................................................................vii List of Abbreviations ...................................................................vii 1. Introduction ....................................................... 1 1.1. Background .......................................................................1 1.2. Incentivized testing: DTHF Tutu tester and Indlu Yegazi ..........3 1.3. Report lay out ....................................................................5 2. Methodology ....................................................... 6 2.1. Aim and objectives .............................................................6 2.2. Literature review ................................................................6 2.3. Potential Cost effectiveness................................................ 10 2.4. Ethical considerations........................................................ 13 3. Results................................................................. 14 3.1. Behaviour change Theories ................................................ 14 3.1.1. The IMB-model ........................................................... 14 3.1.2. Behavioural economics ................................................ 15 3.1.3. Motivation as entry point ............................................. 16 3.2. HIV-testing uptake determinants ........................................ 18 3.2.1. Costs and access to HIV-testing .................................... 18 3.2.2. Stigma....................................................................... 18 3.2.3. Risk perception ........................................................... 19 3.2.4. Motivation to test........................................................ 19 3.3. Lessons from incentivized schemes..................................... 20 3.3.1. Overview included studies and reviews .......................... 20 3.3.2. Target behaviour......................................................... 20 3.3.3. Target population........................................................ 22 3.3.4. Incentive ................................................................... 23 3.3.5. Incentive size ............................................................. 24 3.3.6. Incentive-provision: frequency and timing...................... 25 3.3.7. Incentive duration....................................................... 26 3.4. Ethical considerations........................................................ 27 4. Costing model results ....................................... 28 4.1. Number of men tested and HIV-infections averted ................ 28 4.2. Cost of incentive provision ................................................. 29 4.3. Potential cost saving ......................................................... 30 4.4. One-way sensitivity analysis .............................................. 30
  • 7. LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423 v 5. Discussion ........................................................ 32 5.1. Limitations....................................................................... 32 5.2. Theories .......................................................................... 33 5.3. Screening uptake.............................................................. 34 5.4. Incentivized schemes: Lessons learned ............................... 34 5.5. Ethics.............................................................................. 36 5.6. Cost effectiveness............................................................. 37 5.7. Conclusions...................................................................... 38 Literature....................................................................I Annex 1: The TUTU TESTER......................................................... IX Annex 2: Client risk assessment form ............................................ X Annex 3: Calculation of odds ratio ...............................................XII Annex 4: List of excluded articles ................................................ XV Annex 5: Explanation of parameters used.................................... XIX Annex 6: CRE form .................................................................. XXV Annex 7: Confidentiality agreement ........................................ XXXVI Annex 8: Health behaviour theories ....................................... XXXVII Annex 9: Overview of studies............................................... XXXVIII Annex 10: Ethical issues around payment of incentive..................XLIX Annex 11: Calculation results number of testers and HIA................. LI Annex 12: Calculation results additional cost of incentive ................LV Annex 13: Calculation results potential cost savings ..................... LIX Annex 14: Calculation results one-way sensitivity analysis........... LXIII Annex 15: Calculation results HIV-testing cost per DALY ............ LXVII
  • 8. Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men vi List of tables and figures Table 1: M&E data DTHF for Tutu tester 2009..............................................4 Table 2: Combination of search terms........................................................8 Table 3: Type of documents included ........................................................9 Table 4: Parameter values used in model ................................................. 12 Figure 1: No of AIDS deaths under 4 scenario's South Africa, ...........................2 Figure 2: Markov model MSR................................................................ 11 Figure 3: Fisher's IMB model (Fisher, 2005) .............................................. 15 Figure 4: Number of testers, HIA and HIV+ ............................................... 28 Figure 5: Cost incentive provision / HIA.................................................... 29 Figure 6: One-way sensitivity averaged over 2 years.................................... 31 Tables in Annex A-Table 1: Odds ratio using 2009 M&E data DTHF ..................................... XII A-Table 2: Odds of men compared to women .......................................... XIII A-Table 3: Odds MSR compared to other men ......................................... XIII A-Table 4: Odds MSR compared to women............................................. XIII A-Table 5: Odds MSR compared to all others ...........................................XIV A-Table 6: First time testers compared to others ........................................XIV
  • 9. LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423 vii List of Abbreviations AIDS - Acquired Immuno Deficiency Syndrome ART - Anti Retroviral Therapy ARV - Anti Retro Viral BMI - Body Mass Index BMJ - British Medical Journal CCT - Conditional Cash Transfer CE - Cost Effectiveness CE - Cost Effectiveness CI - Confidence Interval CINAHL - Cumulative Index to nursing and allied health literature CM - Contingency Management CPI - Consumer Price Index CRE - Combined Risk Assessment and Ethics form DALY - Disability Adjusted Life Years DTHF - Desmond Tutu HIV Foundation GDP - Gross Domestic Product HARP - Highly Active Retroviral Prevention HIA - HIV-infection Averted HIV - Human Immunodeficiency Virus IDU - Intravenous Drug Users IMB - Information, motivation, behaviour model IY - Indlu Yegazi KIU - Keep It Up LDL-C - Low-density lipoprotein-cholesterol LSHTM - London School of Hygiene and Tropical Medicine M&E - Monitoring and Evaluation MARP - Most At Risk Population MCH - Mother and Child Health MSR - Men on the Side of the Road na - Not applicable NDOH - National Department of Health (South Africa) NICE - National Institute of Clinical Excellence (UK) OR - Odds Ratio PIT - Provider Initiated Testing PMTCT - Prevention of Mother to Child Transmission PPD - Purified Protein Derivate RCT - Randomized Controlled Trial RSA - Republic of South Africa SASA - South African Statistical Agency STD / STI - Sexual Transmitted Disease / Infection TB - Tuberculosis UNAIDS - Joint United Nations Program on HIV/AIDS UNICEF - United Nations Childrens’ Fund US - United States VBRT - Voucher Based Reinforcement Therapy VCT - Voluntary Counselling and Testing WHO - World Health Organization ZAR - South African Rand
  • 10.
  • 11. LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423 1 1. Introduction 1.1. Background A South African survey found that 73.3% of women and 66.1% of men had tested for HIV in Western Cape (Shisana et al., 2009)1 compared to the universal access target of 75% by 20102 . Tests during the survey showed an HIV-prevalence of 12.8% in first-time testers and 16.3% for others (Peltzer et al., 2009). STIs accounted for more than 26% of all deaths and over 5 million DALYs in 2000 in South Africa and over 98% of this burden was due to HIV/AIDS (Johnson et al., 2007). African males (25- 49) have been identified as a country-specific most at risk group (MARP) with prevalence levels of 23.7%. Comprehensive knowledge of HIV/AIDS declined from 40.6% to 28%3 in this group (Shisana et al., 2009) while access to and utilization of HIV-services is significantly lower (NDOH, 2008). The need to seriously expand testing coverage is well acknowledged in the “Universal Access-campaign” (UNAIDS and WHO, 2004). But reaching the next client will be increasingly expensive as more effort is needed to convince him (Glick, 2005; Marseille et al., 2007). Over the last years, with treatment becoming more and more available, different delivery models of HIV-testing are introduced to increase uptake (Western Cape Province, 2009). 1 South Africa overall data of 2008 indicate that only 43% of men and 56.7% of women ever received an HIV test and test results (UNAIDS et al., 2009). Cape Town is in Western Cape Province. 2 Accessed from www.unaidsrstesa.org on 18 June 2010. 3 Comparing 2008 with 2005 data.
  • 12. Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men 2 Cost-effective prevention efforts are needed, because for every two persons put on treatment another five get infected (Global HIV prevention working group, 2010). Figure 1 shows four scenarios for South Africa indicating that only a combination of treatment and prevention can reduce HIV deaths in the country (Johnson et al., 2007). Figure 1: No of AIDS deaths under 4 scenario's South Africa, Source Johnson et al., 2007 The importance of HIV-testing as a gateway to treatment and as a secondary prevention method by inducing behaviour change in those testing HIV positive is acknowledged (Valdiserri et al., 2003; Glick, 2005; Global HIV Prevention working group, 2010) and has been shown to be a cost-effective intervention (Galárraga et al., 2009; Denison et al., 2009). Evidence of testing as an effective prevention intervention for those testing negative is inconclusive (Elwy et al, 2002; Hageman et al., 2009). Could this be caused by the fact that even the newly proposed service-delivery methods are still focussed on increasing access to testing from a supply side perspective? In “Three letter Plague” (Steinberg, 2008) the struggle of a young South African black man to decide whether
  • 13. LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423 3 or not to take an HIV-test is narrated. In the end, although being aware of the threat HIV poses, knowing where to go for a test and the fact that treatment is available, the main character decides not to take an HIV-test. He is not alone. 1.2. Incentivized testing: DTHF Tutu tester and Indlu Yegazi In the Cape Town metropolitan area, the Desmond Tutu HIV Foundation reaches out to hard to reach populations with their Tutu Tester mobile tester (see Annex 1). The Tutu tester frequents informal settlements. Clients are given a comprehensive health check, including tests for hypertension, diabetes and obesity. As part of HIV counselling, clients are helped to complete a risk assessment form and make a plan to reduce their risk of attracting AIDS (Annex 2). Condom demonstrations are given and condoms are provided free of charge. DTHF works together with Indlu Yegazi (IY), a NGO offering HIV-testing to daily labourers4 . They are paid an incentive of around ZAR 75/- to motivate them to test5 . When testing negative, these men on the side of the road (MSR) can come back after 6 months to test again6 . It is assumed that this can provide the men the necessary motivation to stay negative and come back to test. Table 1 shows data from Desmond Tutu HIV Foundation Tutu mobile tester (DTHF) for 2009. While 29% of women tested reported that this is their first test, this is 47% for men7 . 4 These men stand at the side of the road each day waiting for a prospective employer and are therefore called Men on the side of the road (MSR). 5 Level of incentive varies depending on the average wage per day paid. 6 Limited demographic information is available on the MSR targeted by IY and limited data is collected. Most of the men are African and have lower educational levels (unskilled jobs). Men testing positive are referred to the care and treatment services of DTHF. Indlu Yegazi is contemplating offering a different incentive for men adhering to care services. 7 While 27% is comparable to the mean of Western Cape, 47% for men is much higher.
  • 14. Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men 4 Table 1: M&E data DTHF for Tutu tester 2009 Female Male No-incentive With incentiveTutu tester 2009 data8 n % n % n % n % Total 3191 41 4648 59 3001 65 1647 35 First test 925 29 2169 47 1281 43 888 54 HIV positive 207 6 405 9 155 5 250 15 1st test, HIV+ 75 36 260 12 85 7 175 20 Zooming in on the results of the MSR over 2009, one might conclude that specific attention for this group is necessary since 54% have not tested before (20% above the provincial level) and 20% of this group’s first testers is positive. MSR have significant higher odds of testing for the first time (1.57), testing HIV+ (3.29) and testing HIV+ for the first time (especially when compared to other men: 3.45). Some real differences seem to exist between the populations in terms of uptake of HIV- testing and HIV prevalence. Annex 3 gives an overview of odds ratio calculated for this group of testers. Seen these results, it is not surprising that the Western Cape province indicates that uptake of testing by men has their focus (Western Cape Province, 2009). Since transmission from male to female is much easier and due to power inequalities it is men’s behaviour placing women at risk, men are key to controlling the spread of HIV and STI (Elwy et al., 2002). 8 Derived from monitoring and evaluation data from the DTHF – Tutu tester. This is a mobile testing unit deployed in Cape Town, South Africa (Nyanga and Masiphumele district). Data reflect 201 days testing without incentive and 45 times with incentive.
  • 15. LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423 5 1.3. Report lay out With a big burden of disease caused by unhealthy behaviour9 , incentives directed towards patients may have a great impact on public health and cost of care (Volpp et al, 2009; Volpp et al, 2009a). The question is whether providing incentives would indeed increase testing uptake and behaviour change. The incentivized testing intervention can be termed a contingency management approach defined as “the systematic reinforcement of desired behaviour and the withholding of reinforcement or punishment of undesired behaviour” (Higgins and Petry, 1999). Conditional Cash Transfers (CCT) are considered to fall in this definition. Different incentive type interventions exist, though application of these principles in Africa or on HIV risk-reduction is so far limited (Volmink and Garner, 1997; Haug and Sorensen, 2006). Interventions using material incentives provided to patients mainly focus on interventions to reduce substance abuse in Europe and America while Conditional Cash Transfer (CCT) programs have been successful in Latin America. One proof of concept CCT pilot study is currently underway in Tanzania assessing effectiveness of the use of incentives for young adults to test negative for STIs (DeWalque et al., 2010). This report presents available evidence from interventions aimed at changing behaviour or increasing service uptake using incentives. Chapter 2 provides the methodology of the research. In chapter 3, the results from the literature research are presented followed by the cost modelling in chapter 4. The concluding chapter discusses the results. 9 Preventable disease estimated at 40% for the US by Volpp et al (2009a). To compare STIs in South Africa consists of 26% of DALY of which 98% is due to AIDS.
  • 16. Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men 6 2. Methodology 2.1. Aim and objectives The aim of the research is to explore whether providing incentive based HIV-testing for men could be an effective10 way of HIV prevention. Specific objectives of the research are: 1) Conduct a literature review on the use of incentive-based systems to increase uptake of preventive services and change behaviour with a focus on HIV-testing. 2) Based on available cost data, assess the potential cost-effectiveness of incentive provision for HIV-testing and behaviour change in South Africa. 2.2. Literature review To address objective 1 “the use of incentive-based systems to increase uptake of preventive services and change behaviour”, six databases were searched (Cochrane, Pubmed, Embase, BMJ, Google scholar and CINAHL) to address the following search questions. 1) Which theories exist to explain the motivation and determinants for men to take up HIV-testing and change behaviours? 2) What are determinants for HIV-testing uptake in South Africa? 10 Effective is defined as increasing uptake of testing and reducing risky behaviour measured by a lower incidence of HIV.
  • 17. LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423 7 3) Which examples exist of increases in uptake of services, strengthened adherence to treatment or changed behaviour due to the use of material11 incentives? 4) What are the ethics of providing a financial incentive (to a specific group)? A number of key terms were identified based on these research questions. Different spelling options for words were used12 . Table 2 presents searches using a combination of key terms. Boolean operators “AND” and “OR” were used to respond to the research questions13 . A total of 2720 articles were found. Articles that focussed on provider-incentives, incentives to recruit patients in trials or non-material incentives were excluded after reviewing the summary. 11 Cash or no-cash 12 See example in table 2: behaviour change / behavior change but also men / male 13 Only articles published from 1995 were included. Language was no restriction.
  • 18. Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men 8 Table 2: Combination of search terms Combination of search terms Cochrane14 Pubmed 15 Embase BMJ GoogleScholar CINAHL Total Total (T) and Relevant (R) articles T R T R T R T R T R T R T R [“HIV testing” or “HIV test”] AND incentive 5 1 15 4 6 0 50 7 200 16 1 4 2 280 13 17 Incentive AND [patient OR client] AND [financial OR material OR economic] 83 20 137 7 29 6 32 5 200 18 7 125 9 606 38 19 Intervention AND promotion AND incentive 29 8 11 4 20 2 162 10 200 20 13 15 3 437 35 21 [HIV or AIDS or STI or STD] AND [intervention or promotion or prevention or testing] AND [incentive or cash or reward or payment or gift or remuneration or compensation or bonus or prize or lottery] 51 8 164 12 194 12 83 3 181 22 4 86 10 759 25 23 [HIV or STD or STI or AIDS ] AND [“Conditional Cash Transfer” or “Contingency Management”] 13 3 22 10 22 8 1 1 26 5 11 5 95 20 24 Sexual AND “Behaviour change” AND [incentive or cash or reward or payment or gift or remuneration or compensation or bonus or prize or lottery] 6 1 32 1 0 0 - 0 - 200 16 7 0 245 18 “risk reduction” AND [male OR men] AND incentive AND HIV 10 0 84 3 3 1 - 0 200 1 1 1 298 4 25 Total 197 41 465 41 274 29 328 26 1207 47 249 30 2720 118 26 14 Search in fields: title, abstract and key words 15 Search in fields: title and abstract 16 The first 200 of 5670 articles were reviewed by title and abstract 17 2 articles were overlapping across databases 18 The first 200 of a total of 6460 documents were reviewed by title and abstract 19 16 articles were overlapping across databases 20 The first 200 of a total 19,400 documents were reviewed by title and abstract 21 5 articles overlapping across databases 22 Search in field: intitle 23 24 articles were overlapping across databases 24 12 articles overlapping across databases 25 2 articles overlapping across databases 26 35 articles overlapping across searches
  • 19. LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423 9 Of these 118 articles, 7 could not be retrieved, 7 were already included in a review which was part of the research and 31 were excluded after full text review. Reasons are listed in Annex 4. This resulted in a final number of 73 documents. A further search of article references and websites was conducted to find additional information on theories underlying the provision of incentives, information on determinants for HIV-testing uptake in South Africa and the ethics of incentive provision. This resulted in a final number of 128 articles and books as presented in table 3. Table 3: Type of documents included StudyQuestion RCT 28 Cohort Cross- sectional Review Other 27 Total 1 2 1 1 5 10 19 2 1 14 2 4 21 3 3029 10 2 9 24 75 4 2 4 7 13 Total 32 12 19 20 45 128 27 Other includes books, background articles, reports, editorial notes and letters in journals. 28 Randomized controlled trial 29 2 pilot studies were not randomized, but worked with control group
  • 20. Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men 10 2.3. Potential Cost effectiveness To respond to objective 2 “assess the potential cost-effectiveness of incentive provision for HIV-testing and behaviour change in the context of South Africa” a model was developed to compare the DTHF normal mobile testing intervention without incentive (control group) with the DTHF/IY incentivized intervention modelled on the MSR population (intervention group). Calculations were made based on the full capacity of one mobile testing unit in one year using accounting costs from a provider perspective thus excluding cost to the tester or society due to the limited costing data available (UNAIDS, 2000). The two outcomes of interest are the additional cost of providing an incentive per additional HIV-infection averted (HIA) and the potential cost saving per HIA30 . A Markov model was developed to answer the following questions, compared with the current mobile testing intervention of DTHF: 1. What is the additional cost of providing an incentive per HIA over a five-year period to a cohort of men? 2. What is the potential cost saving per HIA over a five-year period to a cohort of men? 3. What is the necessary reduction in the chance of getting infected with HIV and the necessary time-span to justify the current provision of an incentive31 ? 4. How are the outcomes of the calculation model influenced by different values of the key variables (sensitivity analysis)? 30 Potential cost saving per HIV-infection prevented is the cost of providing an incentive minus the cost that otherwise would have been paid to treatment. 31 ZAR75 per test, 2 tests a year, n=4416 men
  • 21. LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423 11 The model (see figure 2) describes the chance of a man to become infected in a given time period (year) based on his initial state. Whether or not the man has tested before – his ‘history’ – is not considered (Sanderson and Gruen, 2006). Thus it assumes that chance of getting infected and loss to follow up will stay the same over time. Except for the incentive and parameter values, the flow of the model will be the same for the control group. Figure 2: Markov model MSR Four positive effects of providing an incentive are assumed by DTHF/IY. First, more men will be interested to take up testing. This is reflected in the utilization rates (77% vs. 92%) of the DTHF vs. DTHF/IY intervention32 . Secondly, more men will test regularly at the recommended intervals. Thus, the percentage of men lost to follow up (nl) will be lower in the incentivized group and the number of tests (and thus incentive) performed will be higher in the incentivized group (nt). Third, because of 32 The 2009 M&E data show that on DTHF/IY days, a number close to the full capacity of 40 testers a day is tested. Motivated to test = n HIV+ HIV- On ART treatment Not on ART treatment Lost to follow up Men on the side of the Road (MSR) Men on the side of the Road (MSR) 1-nl p 1-p nl t 1-t nl: % of men lost to follow up p: chance of becoming infected ?: chance that when HIV+ treatment is initiated immediately Incentive I
  • 22. Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men 12 the incentive, men will be motivated to change behaviour thus reducing the chance (p) to become infected compared to the control group. Furthermore, men will be diagnosed with HIV earlier on, so the percentage of men needing to go on ART immediately will be lower (t). Due to the limitations in available data, the model however assumes that all diagnosed HIV+ will be put on treatment. The Markov model formed the basis for the development a costing model prepared in Microsoft Excel 200333 . Cost data were retrieved for the provision of HIV/AIDS testing, ART treatment and other services in South Africa (Cape Town) in the last 5 years. Parameter values are presented in table 4. Table 4: Parameter values used in model Model parameters 34 Current situation (control) 35 Incentive effect Chance to become infected (p) 0.20 0.15, 0.10, 0.05, 0.00 Incentive value (I) 0 10.22 US$ Number of testers (n) 3696 441636 Number of tests (nt) 2 2 Loss to follow up (nl) 37 0.15 0.00, 0.05, 0.10 Two outcomes of interest were calculated: the incentive cost per HIV+ case directly prevented and the potential cost saving per HIV-infection directly prevented38 . Budget data from IY were utilized to calculate the cost of providing an incentive. 33 Attached as separate file to this report. 34 All parameters in the model can be changed. 35 Based on the M&E 2009 data for MSR 36 In 2009, utilisation rate was 77% of full capacity per day (40 testers) without incentive and 92% with incentive 37 No data could be retrieved from DTHF/IY. Rutledge et al, 2002 found average attrition over 12 sexually transmitted HIV prevention interventions based upon social learning to be 15%. The normal intervention of DTHF could be considered an intervention like this. The incentive is an added extra. 38 Potential cost saving per HIV-infection prevented is the cost of providing an incentive minus the total cost that would have been paid to treatment if the infection was not averted.
  • 23. LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423 13 A one-way sensitivity analysis was performed testing the influence of varying the value of variables n, nl, nt, I and p in the intervention (i) group on the overall outcome of the intervention. Annex 5 presents underlying assumptions, data sources and limitations of the parameters used. All costs are standardized to 2009 using the consumer price indexes of South African Statistical Agency39 . A discounting rate of 3% is used (Mathers et al, 2006). Discounting enables to take into account the fact that people would like to have benefits now and pay later so cost in the future are decreased with this percentage (Belli et al., 1998). 2.4. Ethical considerations Ethics clearance was obtained from LSHTM (reference 009/06). Annex 6 presents the Approved CRE form. After obtaining the ethical clearance, the scope of the study was limited. Only M&E data from DTHF Tutu tester were used. Annex 7 presents the confidentiality agreement signed with the DTHF. 39 http://www,statssa,gov,za/timeseriesdata/excel_format,asp accessed on 7July 2010
  • 24. Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men 14 3. Results 3.1. Behaviour change Theories 3.1.1. The IMB-model Fisher states that prevention interventions fail because they are not rooted in theory40 , provide information only – which is not sufficient to change behaviour - and focus on general patterns of behaviour rather than information, skills and motivational support specially targeting the group addressed (Fishbein and Guinan, 1996; Rutledge, 2002; Fisher, 2005; Albarracín et al., 2005; Medlin et al., 2008). According to the Information – Motivation – Behaviour model (IMB), any intervention aimed at behaviour change should 1) give information which is relevant to the intended behaviour change and the specific population, 2) also work on social support systems and motivation of the individual and lastly 3) train skills of the individual so that he is able to behave in the intended manner41 . The model is simple and has been validated in various settings (DiClementi et al, 2009; Mimiaga et al., 2009). A US-RCT found the model to be most effective for men (Kalichman et al., 2005). Figure 3 presents the model. 40 Annex 8 provides background on three main categories of health behaviour theories. 41 Five skills are identified as necessary for HIV prevention: Self-acceptance of sexuality, acquisition of behaviourally relevant information, negotiation of preventive behaviour with partner, performance of public prevention acts and consistent performance of prevention behaviour (Mimiaga et al., 2009).
  • 25. LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423 15 Figure 3: Fisher's IMB model (source Fisher, 2005)42 The model was generalized to the South African context although with special attention on AIDS related stigma as an important environmental factor which adversely influences all three elements of the model (Kalichman and Simbayi, 2003; Kalichman et al., 2006). Effective prevention should also include interventions to increase service availability, promotion of testing at population level and biomedical strategies (Coates et al., 2008). Evidence suggests that for the short term, a full IMB counselling model is most effective for men (Kalichman et al., 2005). 3.1.2. Behavioural economics Behavioural economics helps to explain why paying an incentive will increase the motivation for individuals to change behaviour. People prefer to have a reward now than the ‘may-be’ risk of acquiring HIV in the future (time-preference) (Loewenstein et al., 2007; Volpp et al., 2009a). By putting a price on staying HIV-, the opportunity cost of risky sex increases. Neoclassical theory assumes individuals to be rational, making the choices that maximize utility subject to constraints in time and budget (Eichler, 2006; Jochelson, 2007; Finkelstein et al., 2008). Preferences – which may 42 Kalichman et al. (2006) uses the terms AIDS knowledge (HIV prevention information), behavioural intentions (motivation) and self-efficacy (behavioural skills). HIV Prevention Information HIV Prevention Motivation HIV Prevention Behavioral Skills HIV Preventive Behavior
  • 26. Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men 16 vary from day to day (Kiene et al., 2008) - also influence the perceived opportunity costs of engaging in risky sex. When the next opportunity to receive an incentive is too far off or the incentive is too small, time-preference can actually explain engagement in risk-sex if the individual wants to maximize his utility (Medlin and DeWalque, 2008). 3.1.3. Motivation as entry point The IMB model suggests that for different populations, the trigger for behaviour change will be different. Paying an incentive assumes that motivation is the entry point to behaviour change. The incentive can overcome stigma and thus have men enrol for a test and participate in a risk assessment. The question however, is also how to change behaviour43 . Paying an incentive increases external motivation. How long an incentive needs to be paid to internalize motivation? Also, should the incentive be stable over time, increase or decrease to maintain the level of motivation. A reduction in opportunity cost attracts people that are less interested to change behaviour (Glick, 2005; Cahill and Perera, 2008). Economic theory would suggest that when an incentive is no longer paid, there is no reason to sustain the behaviour. The intrinsic motivation for individuals to change behaviour is their aim to maximize utility which they do when they get the incentive. When the incentive is stopped behaviour which is maximizing utility – which could be risky sexual behaviour rather than using condoms – is again adopted (Kane et al., 2004a). 43 The transtheoretical model identifies 5 stages of change: 1) precontemplative (no intention to change), 2) contemplative stage (considering change), 3) ready for action stage (exploratory attempts to adopt behaviour), 4) action stage and finally 5) maintenance stage (behaviour has become routine) (Fishbein and Guinan, 1996).
  • 27. LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423 17 Behavioural learning theory suggests that after several rounds of rewards, the behaviour is automated so even though payment is stopped, behaviour will be sustained (Kellog et al., n.d.). Cognitive dissonance theory suggests that even though initial engagement with the program depends on the payment of the incentive, communication with the service providers, enhancement of skills and provision of information can influence motivation so that individuals as social creatures want to comply with behaviour which is advocated as being good (Corrigan et al., 2005). Communication theory implies that therapeutic alliance will be built by regular interaction and this regular reinforcement will in time be sufficient to sustain the desired behaviour (Kiene et al., 2008).
  • 28. Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men 18 3.2. HIV-testing uptake determinants 3.2.1. Costs and access to HIV-testing In Western Cape44 , men test significantly less than women (Western Cape Province, 2009). An Eastern Cape study found that every one kilometre a man lives away from a testing facility, reduces the likelihood that a man will test (Hutchinson and Mahlalela, 2006). PIT45 might therefore not be the only answer to increase testing uptake by men. Mobile testing, a strategy suggested to reach Most At Risk Populations (MARP) brings testing facilities closer to people. Black African Males between 25 and 49 years are identified as a country specific MARP for South Africa (Shisana et al., 2009). Physical access to a testing facility is important, but also the willingness and ability to absorb the monetary and time-related costs to go for a test. (Weinreb and Stecklov, 2009; Nyanzi-Wakholi et al., 2009; Peltzer et al., 2009; Jepson et al., 2000). A meta- analysis of HIV risk-reduction interventions in the US found that tangible incentives had a positive effect on the participation and retention of men in screening programs (Durantini and Albarracín, 2009). 3.2.2. Stigma Stigma is another important influence on the decision to go for testing. Men indicated that they preferred to live in doubt and would only go for VCT when they were sick. Men do not fear family based stigma so much, but are more scared to loose their position in the community (Day et al., 2003; Holzemer and Uys, 2004; Nyanzi- 44 Cape Town is located in the Western Cape province of South Africa. 45 Provider initiated testing has been introduced in all public health facilities in the Western Cape.
  • 29. LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423 19 Wakholi et al., 2009). The possibility of testing HIV+ and the stigma attached to this, thus reduces the acceptability and uptake. Embedding HIV-testing in a more comprehensive health check could address the issue of stigma and acceptability, and result in higher uptake (O’Donnell, 2009). 3.2.3. Risk perception For many people, the motivation to use VCT is low because they do not see themselves as at risk for HIV/AIDS, even in high-prevalence areas or following high- risk behaviour (Hutchinson and Mahlalela, 2006; Kalichman et al., 2008; Hageman et al., 2009; Johnston et al., 2010). But even if they consider themselves at risk, HIV is only one of the threats they face most of which are considered more pressing and immediate than HIV/AIDS (Kalichman et al., 2006). In Western Cape, self reported condom use is very low pointing to high-risk sexual intercourse (Johnson and Budlender, 2002; Shisana et al., 2009). The DTHF/IY M&E data indicate that MSR are 2.88 times more likely to test HIV+ while they are much less likely to have tested before (see Annex 3). Social networks strongly influence the individual’s perceptions of risk surrounding HIV/AIDS and their preventive behaviours (Hutchinson et al., 2007). 3.2.4. Motivation to test With high opportunity costs to go for testing, high levels of stigma and low risk perception possibly due to incorrect knowledge, motivation to test will be low. Correct knowledge of HIV transmission – positively associated with being tested for HIV - is only 43.8% in Black African Male overall and 34.1% in Western Cape (Shisana et al., 2009). The fact that DTHF provides mobiles HIV-testing embedded in a more comprehensive health check apparently does not overcome the barriers to test for
  • 30. Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men 20 MSR. The next paragraph explores evidence to assess if, as stated by the men (Indlu Yegazi, 2009) a financial incentive could increase uptake and change behaviour. 3.3. Lessons from incentivized schemes 3.3.1. Overview included studies and reviews Fifty-one articles were included referring to 49 studies: 30 RCTs, 10 cohorts, 2 cross sectional designs and 9 reviews. Of these 37 were conducted in the US and only 2 in Africa46 (Malawi and Tanzania). Fifteen studies referred to HIV-related incentive interventions. Others were related to compliance (5), uptake of preventive health services (4), smoking cessation (4), substance abuse (4), tuberculosis (6) and weight loss (4). The 9 reviews referred to 7 studies covering a total of 235. None of the reviews specifically targeted HIV-related behaviour change. Annex 9 provides information on the studies. Lessons from the included articles are presented along the 7 core issues to be considered when looking at or designing a contingency management program are 1) Targeted behaviour, 2) Choice of target population, 3) Choice of incentive, 4) Incentive magnitude, 5) Frequency of incentive distribution, 6) Timing of incentive and 7) Duration of the incentive provision (Razavi et al., 2009; Kellog et al., n.d.). 3.3.2. Target behaviour Target behaviour is complex or simple (Kane et al., 2004 and 2004a). Simple behaviours are one-off activities, treatment adherence, return visits to collect results, attendance at educational activities, completion of a procedure, enrolment. Twenty- two of the included studies refer to such simple behaviours and show that incentive 46 Malawi and Tanzania.
  • 31. LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423 21 provision results in higher success rates, higher enrolment and attraction of MARP (Chaisson et al., 1996; Fitzgerald et al., 1999; White et al, 1998; Kelen, 1996; Bloch et al., 2006; Corrigan et al., 2005; Corrigan and Bogner, 2007; Haukoos et al., 2005). The more complex and sustained the targeted behavioural outcomes47 , the weaker the evidence of effectiveness of incentives. After the incentives stop, relapses occur and differences with the control group diminish or disappear completely (Kane et al., 2004; Cahill and Perera, 2008; Haug et al, 2006; Brandon et al., 2007; Forde and Zeuner, 2009; Oliver, 2009; Volpp, 2009; Marteau et al., 2009). Results from CCTs suggest that the programs increase the use of preventive services and improve intermediate outcome measures, but long-term effectiveness has not been assessed (Anderson, 2010; Lagarde et al, 2007; Lagarde et al, 2009; Razavi et al., 2009). Ten of the 15 HIV-related studies referred to simple behaviour. In the five referring to complex behaviour, one used self-report of behaviour change to measure behaviour change (Petry et al., 2010) while it is important that target behaviour can be measured objectively to avoid bias. Two studies saw risk behaviour change not related to risky sex but substance abuse48 (Ghitza at al., 2008; Hanson et al., 2008). The Tanzania-study used STI infection as proxy for HIV-infection since chances to get infected with HIV are small and distant even when engaging in risky sex (Medlin and DeWalque, 2008)49 . The Malawi study used pregnancy rates and early marriage as proxy for risky sexual behaviour (Baird et al, 2009)50 . 47 Smoking cessation, weight loss, substance abuse. 48 Harm reduction measures like bleaching of needles, syringes exchange etc. 49 Risk of HIV transmission in men during penile-vaginal intercourse is 0.01-0.1%. Risk of transmission will be higher if an STI is present (Baggaley et al., 2008). 50 The main target behaviour of the incentive provision was to increase school attendance and reduce drop-out for girls. Effect on sexual behaviour and early marriage were a by-product of the increase in school attendance (both in number of girls and length of attendance).
  • 32. Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men 22 While stimulating demand is important, the capacity of the supply side system to offer quality services in sufficient quantity also needs to be addressed (Morris et al., 2004; Lagarde et al., 2007; Medlin and DeWalque, 2008; Adato and Bassett, 2009; Bassett, 2008; Baird et al., 2009; Lagarde et al., 2009; Schafer, 2010; Banerjee et al., 2010; Lim et al., 2010) 3.3.3. Target population Paying an incentive increases the cost of normal treatment, therefore it is suggested to target for specific populations and behaviour with high public health impact (Higgins et al., 2002; DeWalque et al., 2010; Lim et al., 2010)51 . The studies show that paying an incentive is effective in reaching MARP which were targeted in 24 of the included studies. But the more targeted the intervention and the more conditioned, the more expensive it becomes administratively. Furthermore, targeting can induce stigma (Forde and Zeuner, 2009). And the incentive will be paid to people that already behave as intended (Lagarde et al, 2007; Volpp et al, 2009a). In 12 studies attrition was still high, attributed to the height of the incentive, the physical distance to the service and/or the quality of service provision (White et al., 1998; Carey et al., 2005; Gift et al., 2005; Ghitza et al., 2008; Petry et al., 2010). Two studies found that success rates were higher in men than women (Tulsky et al., 2000; Chaisson et al., 1996). 51 Populations to be addressed are treatment recalcitrant, hard-to-reach or most at risk populations (MARP).
  • 33. LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423 23 3.3.4. Incentive The first question is whether incentive provision is necessary. Since incentive provision is expensive compared to other interventions, cost-effectiveness might easier be achieved with another intervention (Chaisson et al., 1996; Villano et al., 2002; Morris et al., 2004; Petry et al., 2004; Adato and Bassett, 2009; Heil et al., 2008; Ghitza et al., 2008; Banerjee et al., 2010). This is especially true when looking from a provider-perspective as potential cost-savings might benefit another budget. Incentives can be conditional or unconditional. While unconditional cash transfers have shown to improve health seeking behaviour, it is not likely that people with low risk perception and high stigma will change HIV-related risk behaviour when no condition applies to the cash transfer (Stitzer, 2006). Incentives can be positive or negative. Positive approaches seem to be more effective possibly because it reinforces individuals’ sense of personal achievement (Jochelson, 2007; Heil et al., 2008). Positive reinforcement is also more enjoyable for clients and providers (Kellog et al., n.d.). Incentives can be in-kind, vouchers or cash. In-kind incentives are less appreciated by clients than the more flexible vouchers or cash and require more time and effort from the service provider52 . With cash, clients could purchase unintended items53 and the necessity to keep stocks of cash at the service-delivery point carries a security risk (DTHF/IY, personal comment; Alfers and Butterfoss, 2000; Kane et al., 2004 and 2004a; Hanson et al., 2008; Cahill and Perera, 2009). Flat payments for task completion or regular flat payments were provided in 22 studies. Escalating incentives with a reset value were used in 12. These incentives grow, the longer you do (not) exhibit the behaviour, the higher your payment 52 Staff need to go buy the items in sufficient quantities. Articles have to be stored somewhere etc. 53 Alcohol, drugs etc.
  • 34. Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men 24 becomes. Once you relapse, payments are reset to the original value (Pilling et al., 2007; Mayor, 2007; Volpp et al., 2009; Heil et al., 2008; Cahill and Perera, 2008). Nine researches used a lottery system. Participants can win draws for big prices. Lottery systems were introduced to enable continuous or escalating reinforcement at a lesser cost. The incentive provided is the right to take a draw in the lottery with a chance to win a price varying from 0 to 1. Lottery and escalating incentives are more effective in longer-term reinforcement (Petry et al., 2004; Cahill and Perera, 2009). The HIV-interventions saw a mix of flat payments, lottery and escalating incentives. Interventions that combined incentives with strengthened provider interaction, support groups, information provision, skills building or other supportive interventions were more successful to sustain behaviour after incentive provision ceased (Chaisson et al., 1996; Corrigan and Bogner, 2007; Jochelson, 2007; Finkelstein et al., 2008; Higgins et al., 2002, Kane et al., 2004a). 3.3.5. Incentive size The success of the incentives depends on the size of the incentive. Determining the exact threshold to inducing change is difficult (Lagarde et al, 2007; Volpp et al, 2009a). If the incentive is too high, the target group might not be motivated to change behaviour but to earn the money (Higgins et al., 2002; Forde and Zeuner, 2009; Volpp et al.,2009; Kane et al, 2004; Volpp et al, 2008; Seaverson et al, 2009). If the latter, after stopping the incentive, people will fall back in their old behaviour (Kane et al, 2004; Volpp et al., 2008; Higgins et al, 2002). Lottery-type incentives included in this study could grow very large. Flat and/or recurrent payments were more modest ranging from 2 to 30 US$ per event. The HIV study in Tanzania linked
  • 35. LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423 25 the payment of either US$30 or US$60 per year which is 7.5-15% of GDP and 12- 24% of the average annual income of participants54 . As a result, the STI infection reduced (from 12 to 9%) and only for the higher incentive (Anonymous, 2010). 3.3.6. Incentive-provision: frequency and timing Incentives should be distributed frequent enough to keep it ever-present in the minds of the target group but not too frequent in order to contain costs (Medlin and DeWalque, 2008). The studies included pay incentives for each successful measurement. Frequency of payment can be daily in case of substance abuse treatment, weekly, monthly, one-off payment, monthly or every four months. In case of lotteries, big price draws are sometimes organised for the attainment of a ‘super- goal’ on top of escalating incentives or regular lotteries. Reinforcement should be applied as soon as possible following the target behaviour to establish a strong contingent link (Haug and Sorensen, 2006; Stitzer et al., 2006; Medlin and DeWalque, 2008). It is therefore necessary to define a target behaviour which is close to the consequence and objectively quickly and cheaply measurable. Frequency and timing are strongly linked to the magnitude of the incentive and the expected behaviour. If the frequency is high and the target behaviour is wanted by the target group, a lower incentive will suffice (Rigsby et al., 2000; Schroeder et al., 2006; Volpp et al, 2008; Seaverson et al., 2009). If the target behaviour is wanted for the public and frequency of reinforcement is lower55 , the incentive should be higher (Bloch et al., 2006; Volpp et al., 2006; Volpp et al., 2009; Anonymous, 2010). 54 GDP in Tanzania was US$400 and the average annual income earned by participants in this study was US$250. DTHF/IY pays half a day’s wage (ZAR 75 or US$10.22) to go for HIV-testing. 55 A reduction in sexual behaviour might not be a felt need by the targeted group (as is the case in MSR). Therefore, more effort is necessary to convince them to change behaviour. If cost of
  • 36. Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men 26 3.3.7. Incentive duration The studies show that incentives - as extrinsic motivators - are useful to initiate behaviour change, though sustaining this behaviour after the incentive has stopped will depend on whether the person is or has become intrinsically motivated and the norms in his social network (Corrigan et al., 2005; Jochelson, 2007; Sorensen et al., 2007; Volpp et al., 2008; Hanson et al., 2008; Rigsby et al., 2000; Petry et al., 2010). Therefore it is necessary to focus on increasing the individual’s perception of skill, competence and desire to change behaviour (Gaither et al., 2009). Self belief and confidence to change are critical to sustain behaviour (Forde and Zeuner, 2009). Of 20 included studies aiming at complex behaviour change, seven provided incentives for 3 or less months of which six reported no or limited long-term behaviour change56 . Incentive-provision for three months seems insufficient to change complex behaviour. What the optimal time of reinforcement will depend on the combination of all 7 principles of CM (Kellog et al., n.d.). measurement is high, there is a need to have limited reinforcement moments or to otherwise pay without measurement in some instances. Another option is to have intermediate steps (proxy indicators) which are less distant and/or cheaper to measure. 56 No follow up was reported in the last study.
  • 37. LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423 27 3.4. Ethical considerations All studies retrieved justified paying an incentive from a public health or an economic efficiency point of view. The economic rational to pay an incentive to go for HIV- testing can be found in the fact that it creates positive externalities57 that warrant its subsidy to maximize uptake by the population (Jepson et al, 2000; Childress et al., 2002; Lagarde et al., 2009). At individual level, the picture is more complicated. Annex 10 provides an overview of arguments found in the literature. Looking at the four dimensions of humanity in health58 , the key issue to consider here is how to ensure autonomy and informed uptake. If the incentive is too high, MSR will not bother informing themselves about possible consequences. In that case, to maximize utility, they should test. However, if the incentive is too low or non- existent, MSR will not test. This can also not be termed as informed or autonomous decision making seen the low level of correct knowledge and the high levels of stigma. Thus the height of the incentive and the way the testing is provided will determine whether autonomy and informed decision making is ensured. 57 Individual can access treatment earlier which leads to better treatment results. Testing positive has shown to lead to behaviour change and possible reduction in rates of HIV-transmission. 58 Smith et al. (2005) distinguishes autonomy, dignity, beneficence and non-maleficence as the four elements of humanity in health.
  • 38. Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men 28 4. Costing model results The costing model was used to make calculations varying the chance to become infected and loss to follow up as an effect of the incentive over time59 . 4.1. Number of men tested and HIV-infections averted Since the uptake of testing increases due to the incentive and the loss to follow up is estimated to be lower in this group, the average number of men that tests per year will be higher compared to the control group. Because of this, even with lower prevalence, more HIV-infections can be discovered. HIA can therefore even be negative as shown in figure 4. Complete calculations for different (discounted) values of p(i) and nl are included in Annex 11. -500 0 500 1.000 1.500 2.000 2.500 1 2 3 4 5 Testers p(i)=0,15 Testers p(i)=0,00 HIA with p(i)=0.15 HIA with p(i)=0.00 Extra HIV+ with p(i)=0.15 Figure 4: Number of testers, HIA and HIV+ 59 Control group parameters p(c)=0.20, nl(c)=0.15, n(c)= 3696. Intervention group n(i)=4416. For explanation of parameters and limitations, see Annex 5.
  • 39. LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423 29 4.2. Cost of incentive provision Figure 5 shows that costs of incentive per HIA rapidly increases after year 2, more so for lower loss to follow up and bigger reductions in the chance to get infected since more testers means more incentive costs. 0 500 1.000 1.500 2.000 2.500 3.000 3.500 4.000 4.500 5.000 1 2 3 4 5 Year US$ HIA nl(i) = 0.10 p(i)=0.10 HIA nl(i) = 0.10 Disc. p(i)=0.10 HIA nl(i) = 0.00 p(i)=0.10 HIA nl(i) = 0.00 Disc. p(i)=0.10 Figure 5: Cost incentive provision / HIA The average cost of incentive provision per HIA for p(i)=0.15 for different levels of follow up in the first two years is US$8065. After this cost increases considerably, since the number of HIA plummet. Average costs of incentive provision vary from US$346 to US$95660 averaged over 2 years and US$351 to US$ 200961 over 5 years. For all calculations, see annex 12. 60 Nl(i)=0.10 and p(i)=0.00 (lowest) to nl(i)=0.00 and p(i)=0.10 (highest) 61 Nl(i)=0.10 and p(i)=0.00 (lowest) to nl(i)=0.00 and p(i)=0.10 (highest)
  • 40. Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men 30 4.3. Potential cost saving Potential cost saving was calculated using treatment cost derived from Cape Town plus the cost of incentive provision. Over time, potential cost saving per HIA slowly increases. If an incentive is paid for two years, the average potential savings are negative for p(i)=0.15 regardless which level of loss to follow up is chosen. This is not the case when calculating average savings over 5 years. Highest average cost savings per HIA of US$3472 over 2 years are found for p(i)=0.00 and nl(i)=0.00 for 1242 HIA. Over 5 years, the highest cost savings per HIA is US$6515 for p(i)=0.10 and nl(i)=0.00 but with 166 HIA. Annex 13 provides more detail. 4.4. One-way sensitivity analysis Different levels of loss to follow up and chance to get infected for the intervention group were presented above. Three other situations are modelled. The first assumes that for both control and intervention, the number of men tested starts at 4800. The second foresees an increase of the current incentive to a full-day salary (US$16.32) to attract all the MSR and encourage follow-up visits even when labour is available for the day. Lastly, a 6 month interval might be insufficient to reinforce behaviour change so what happens when 4 tests need to be performed to achieve a chance in behaviour. Loss to follow up in the intervention group was set at nl(i)=0.10. Starting with the same number of men in each group leads to a reduction of average cost of incentive provision per HIA since the total number of testers is higher and because both groups have the same size now relatively more HIV+ men will be
  • 41. LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423 31 discovered in the control group62 . Testing 4 times a year is only possible when n=240063 . This results in a significantly higher number of HIA averted compared to the original situation and thus to a lower cost of incentive provision per HIA. The reason is however not the more intensive testing, but the fact that less men are tested in the incentive situation thus less potential HIV+ cases are detected. The cost of incentive provision per HIA is mostly influenced by variations in the cost of the incentive itself. Cost presented in figure 6 are averaged over 2 years, cost over 5 years show a similar pattern. 0 200 400 600 800 1000 1200 1400 1600 p(i)=0.10 p(i)=0.05 p(i)=0.00 Different chances of infection Averagecostofincentiveper HIAUS$ Base situation n=4800 Incentive US$16.32 4 tests Figure 6: One-way sensitivity averaged over 2 years This analysis shows that the model is responsive for changes in important parameters and reacts as expected. The potential cost saving per HIA averaged over 2 years strongly reduces from an average of about US$5.000 across different values of p(i) to around US$3.000 for all scenarios. Calculation tables can be found in Annex 14. 62 Model so far assumed differential intake based on the data from DTHF which saw an increased utilization of the DTHF tester when an incentive is provided. 63 Full capacity of one mobile tester is 9600 tests per year.
  • 42. Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men 32 5. Discussion 5.1. Limitations This research set out to explore whether providing incentive based HIV-testing for men could be an effective64 way of HIV prevention. Although a variety of databases were consulted and considerable time was spent searching literature, it is possible that relevant publications (especially grey literature) were missed. Publication bias might have resulted in a too positive impression if failed experiments were not officially published. Several of the studies published had small numbers of participants which might have affected the power of the research and thus its conclusions. Assessing publications for inclusion in the research was done by only one person which might have caused bias as well. The literature search found a very limited number of studies referring to incentive provision and focussing on men, on Africa and on HIV-related risk behaviour, let alone a combination of these three elements. The calculations made with the developed model were based on limited data. There are real opportunities to expand the model by including the costs of mobile test provision65 , mortality figures for both groups, differential initiation on ART66 , changing infection risk over time67 , using real life data of a cohort of DTHF men68 and including 64 Effective is defined as increasing uptake of testing and reducing risky behavior measured by a lower incidence of HIV. 65 When more people test, the unit cost per test decreases due to better capacity utilisation. 66 Now assumed that all testing HIV+ started ART. CD4 count information would be necessary to include different initiation timing. Cleary et al. (2006) found mortality in the first year on ART. Ideally, in the intervention group HIV would be detected earlier, resulting in later initiation on ART and lower mortality once on ART compared to the control group. 67 Markov model is memoryless. It assumes that the chances to become infected will remain stable over time. 68 Were not available in time to be included.
  • 43. LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423 33 indirect HIA because of behaviour change of MSR69 . Including these details is expected to result in a stronger case for incentive provision since cost ART provision will be lower and higher utilisation leads to lower unit cost (Marseille et al., 2007) and the number of HIA will be higher due to the effects outside the targeted population. The adopted provider perspective does not include cost and benefits for the MSR or the society as a whole. DTHF integrates both testing and treatment in its activities, therefore cost saving could be included here in the provider model. An incentive is not likely to be a cost-effective intervention for a stand-alone testing unit or a unit with a separate budget since cost-savings will be made under another budget (Kahn et al., 2006). Taking a broader perspective could accommodate this, but was not possible in the available time and budget for this thesis. 5.2. Theories According to behavioural economics, MSR will want to maximize utility and will not change behaviour when the opportunity costs to do so are higher than maintaining their behaviour. The incentive lowers the opportunity costs of HIV-testing. Men will be able to overcome the barriers caused by stigma since the incentive appeals to the most important role MSR identify for themselves – the breadwinner role (Indlu Yegazi, 2009). Regular return visits will allow the building of therapeutic alliance with the provider thus internalizing this external motivation and reinforcing the ‘good’ behaviour. The 69 Kahn et al. (2006) mentions that each infected individual is responsible for one other new infection. Thus one HIA directly prevented should actually count double. Seen the expected high risk behaviour of MSR, the indirect-HIA might actually be higher than 1.
  • 44. Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men 34 risk-assessment format which is filled can help build the necessary skills. Thus combining the incentive and regular DTHF HIV-testing provision will work on all elements of the IMB model and make sustained behaviour change possible. 5.3. Screening uptake The DTHF approach already brings testing close to the men, embedding it in a comprehensive health check which will reduce stigma and opportunity costs of utilisation. One-day testing plus the availability of an on-site CD4-count machine and possibility to refer to a treatment program also contribute to high uptake. However, the 2009 DTHF M&E data show that MSR are not effectively reached even with this program. Paying an incentive can has attracted MARP in several other settings. However, it is important to realize that it is the incentive that makes the MSR test for HIV and not the intention to change behaviour70 . After enrolment, engaging the men will be of key importance. 5.4. Incentivized schemes: Lessons learned Targeting must be kept simple to avoid extra cost. In the DTHF/IY example, all MSR are eligible to enrol at specific sites. This simple approach avoids problems at the site, since it will be difficult to pay one person but not the next and is administratively easy. But how do you treat a MSR coming for a follow up visit at a non-IY site? It is probably more cost-effective to attach the incentive to the MSR and have vouchers available in the Tutu tester at each testing site. 70 Pre-contemplative stage in the trans-theoretical theory of change (Fishbein and Guinan, 1996).
  • 45. LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423 35 Uptake of HIV-testing is simple behaviour with a clear target which can be immediately reinforced with a payment. Payment is made once, irrespective of the testing result. Testing positive has shown to induce a positive behaviour change. Since because of the incentive, more MSR will test, incentive provision will have a public health impact. The expected behaviour change for those testing positive might be less than otherwise observed since men will enrol in the pre-contemplative stage. Using financial incentives to reduce risk behaviour in MSR is more complicated. First of all, testing for HIV is not a good proxy for safe sexual behaviour since even with unsafe sex the chance of contracting HIV is distant. The contingent link is weak. A MSR might have engaged in unsafe sex, test negative and get an incentive plus the message to change behaviour. By why would he? To ensure immediate reinforcement, other proxies need to be chosen. The Tanzania study uses STI which might be a better proxy, but providing immediate tests on site will be very expensive (Anonymous, 2010). Payment of an incentive combined with other support activities working on information, motivation and skills of people have shown promising results (Villano et al., 2002; Gift et al., 2005; Jochelson, 2007). DTHF/IY could therefore consider combining monthly visits for health education talks or peer support group meetings with an incentive (possibly escalating) with a half yearly check up which in the case of DTHF also includes testing for syphilis. Incentives for monthly visits could be smaller especially if they are organised at times when the MSR do not work. The incentive needs to be meaningful for the participant. The Tanzania study saw behaviour change only in the arm which received 24% of the average annual income of the participants (Anonymous, 2010). The Malawi example saw a change in
  • 46. Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men 36 behaviour with payments of 2 to 8% of monthly income. However, payments were not to the main income-earner of the family and behaviour was to be avoided not changed (Baird et al., 2009). DTHF/IY provides an incentive which is less than the daily wage of MSR. Paying a full day’s wage will make going for testing a real choice for MSR, not only those that did not get work. Although it is not likely that a lottery approach will appeal to the target group, after an initial period of intensive contact and establishing therapeutic alliance one can start playing around with the incentive – increasing or decreasing it. This might allow reduction of payments over time. It is assumed that after some time, behaviour is automated and/or motivation is internalized. For complex behaviour change, 3 months of reinforcement is insufficient and incentive provision alone will not suffice to change behaviour. Seen the possible cost effectiveness of providing the incentives, one might ask why not pay the incentive over a much longer time. 5.5. Ethics DTHF/IY ensures informed uptake of testing through the pre- and post-test counselling. After counselling MSR can decide not to the test. However, payment of the incentive depends on doing the test (though not on the test result)71 . Men that come to test, have no work for the day. Seen their economic situation, they need money to keep themselves going. This will affect their freedom to choose to reject the test. This however can be justified by the public health benefit of behaviour change. For the individual, early detection of HIV virus through regular tests will enhance treatment outcomes. 71 MSR testing positive are referred to the treatment program of DTHF.
  • 47. LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423 37 5.6. Cost effectiveness The calculation model suggests that incentive provision seems to be most cost- effective after two years. After this, potential cost savings per HIA decrease while the cost of incentive provision per HIA increase for all levels of p(i) and nl(i). With current utilization levels, a reduction of p(i) to 0.15 will not be cost effective averaging US$8065 for incentive provision and a negative potential cost saving. The commission on macroeconomics and health recommends that when the cost of an intervention per DALY is below the GDP per capita, it is very cost-effective (Cleary et al., 2006). Combining VCT CE estimates and cost for mobile testing from literature72 with the cost of incentive provision from the model, the total cost of VCT per DALY using a high cost estimate for VCT ranges from US$233-USS$311 per DALY for different values of p(i). A low cost estimate for VCT brings the total cost of VCT per DALY at US$54 to US$132. Both are well below the GDP rate of South Africa73 . Annex 15 provides the full calculations. Seen the above, there is room to increase the value of the incentive and the frequency of provision to attain low attrition and high reduction of chances to become infected without affecting the cost-effectiveness of incentive provision. 72 A generalized CE estimate for VCT in sub-Saharan Africa reported US$1956/- per HIA (Galárraga et al., 2009). Kahn et al. (2006) reported cost for testing per HIA from a South African Primary Health Care unit at US$ 162. A Kenyan study found that mobile testing results in a US$17.54 extra cost per test done (Grabbe et al., 2010). 73 The World Bank puts GDP per capita for South Africa at US$10,291 in 2009, accessed on 16 June 2010 from http://data.worldbank.org/country/south-africa.
  • 48. Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men 38 5.7. Conclusions This research shows that while supply side activities are important, specific attention to stimulate the demand for services by MARP is important. Incentive provision is one way to reach them. But, even though CE is expected to be high, incentive provision needs to be combined with intense follow up and behavioural interventions to internalize motivation and sustain behaviour change. The approach however is promising and needs further testing in order to design a less resource intensive but effective approach which can be scaled up.
  • 49. LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423 I Literature Adato M and Bassett L, 2008, What is the potential of cash transfers to strengthen families affected by HIV and AIDS? A review of the evidence on impacts and key policy debates, Paper submitted by IFPRI to learning group 1: Strengthening Families of the Joint Learning initiative on children and HIV/AIDS (JLICA), co-chaired by Richter L and Sherr L. Albarracín D, Gilette JC, Earl AN, Glasman LR, Durantini MR and Ho MH, 2005, A test of major assumptions about behavior change: A comprehensive look at the effect of the passive and active HIV-prevention interventions since the beginning of the epidemic, Psychol Bull. 2005; 131(6): 856-897 Alfers D and Butterfoss FD, 2000, Evaluation on a shoestring: key to success for Virginia prenatal incentive program, Health Promotion Practice, 2000 Jul; 1 (3): 259-67 Anderson T, 2010, How can child and maternal mortality be cut?, BMJ 2010;340:c431, doi: 10.1136/bmj.c431 Anonymous, 2010, Result brief:: The RESPECT study – Evaluating Conditional cash transfers for HIV/STI prevention in Tanzania, Downloaded on 27 September 2010 from http://siteresources.worldbank.org/DEC/Resources/HIVExeSummary(Tanzania).pdf Baggaley R, Bakobaki J, Brown M, Carter Francis J, Corbett E, Foster C, Glynn J, Grant A, Grassly N, Grosskurth H, Hayman A, Martinez-Alier N, McDonald B, Moffatt C, Morison L, Nascimento MC, Pittrof R, Platt L, Quigley M, De Silva S, Tanton C, Thomas E, Weiss H and Willley S, 2008, Module ID501: AIDS – Study guide, London School of Hygiene and Tropical Medicine, UK. Baird S, Chirwa E, McIntosh C and Özler B, 2009, The short-term impacts of a schooling conditional cash transfer program on the sexual behavior of young women, World Bank Policy Research Working paper No. 5089, The World Bank, Washington, USA. Banerjee AV, Duflo E, Glennerster R and Kothari D, Improving immunisation coverage in rural India: clustered randomised controlled evaluation of immunisation campaigns with and without incentives, BMJ 340:doi:10.1136/bmj.c2220 (Published 17 May 2010)) Bassett, 2008, Can Conditional Cash Transfer Programs Play a greater role in reducing child undernutrition, SP Discussion paper No.0835, WorldBank, Washington Belli P, Anderson J, Barnum H, Dixon J and Tan J-P, 1998, Handbook on economic analysis of investment operations, Operational Course Services Network Learning and Leadership Center Bloch MJ, Armstrong DS, Dettling L, Hardy A, Caterino K and Barrie S, 2006, Partners in lowering cholesterol: comparison of a multidisciplinary educational program, monetary incentives, or usual care in the treatment of dyslipidemia identified among employees, Journal of occupational and environmental medicine / American College of Occupational and Environmental Medicine 48: 7: 675-81. Bock NN, Sales RM, Rogers T and DeVoe B, 2001, A spoonful of sugar...: improving adherence to tuberculosis treatment using financial incentives, Int J Tuberc Lung Dis. 2001 Jan;5(1):96-8. Brandon TH, Vidrine JL, Litvin EB, 2007, Relapse and relapse prevention, Annual Review Clinical Psychology 2007;3:257-84 Burns T and Shaw J, 2007, Is it acceptable for people to be paid to adhere to medication?, BMJ 2007; 335: 232-233 Cahill K and Perera R, 2009, Competitions and incentives for smoking cessation, Cochrane Database of Systematic Reviews: Reviews 2008 Issue 3 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd Chichester, UK DOI: 10.1002/14651858.CD004307.pub3 Carey MP, Vanable PA, Senn TE, Coury-Doniger P and Urban MA, 2005, Recruiting patients from a sexually transmitted disease clinic to sexual risk reduction workshops: are monetary incentives necessary? Journal of Public Health Management & Practice, 2005 Nov-Dec; 11 (6): 516-21 Chaisson RE, Barnes LG, Hackman J, Watkinson L, Kimbrough L, Metha S, Cavalcante S and Moore
  • 50. Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men II RD, 2001, A randomized Controlled trial of interventions to improve adherence to isoniazid therapy to prevent tuberculosis in injection drug users, Am J Med. 2001;110:610-615 Chaisson RE, Keruly JC, McAvinue S, Gallant JE and Moore RD, 1996, Effects of an incentive and education program on return rates for PPD test reading in patients with HIV infection, J Acquir Immune Defic Syndr Hum Retrovirol. 1996 Apr 15;11(5):455-9. Childress JF, Faden RR, Gaare RD, Gostin LO, Kahn J, Bonnie RJ, Kass NE, Mastroianni AC, Moreno JD and Nieburg P, 2002, Public health ethics: Mapping the terrain, Journal of law, medicine and ethics, 30 (2002): 170-178 Choe HM, Stevenson JG, Streetman DS, Heisler M, Sandiford CJ and Piette JD, 2007, Impact of patient financial incentives on participation and outcomes in a statin pill-splitting program, Am J Manag Care. 2007 Jun;13(6 Part 1):298-304 Claassen D, 2007, Financial incentives for antipsychotic depot medication: ethical issues, Journal of Medical Ethics, 2007 Apr; 33 (4): 189-93 Cleary SM, Mcintyre D and Boulle AM, 2006, The cost-effectiveness of Antiretroviral Treatment in Khayelitsha, South Africa – a primary data analysis, Cost effectiveness and Resources allocation 2006, 4:20, doi:10.1186/1478-7547-4-20 Coates TJ, Richter L and Caceres C, 2008, Behavioural strategies to reduce HIV Transmission: how to make them work better, Lancet DOI:10.1016/S0140-6736(08)60886-7, 36-51. Corrigan JD and Bogner J, 2007, Interventions to promote retention in substance abuse treatment, Brain Inj. 2007 Apr;21(4):343-56 Corrigan JD, Bogner J, Lamb-Hart G, Heinemann AW and Moore D, 2005, Increasing substance abuse treatment compliance for persons with traumatic brain injury, Psychology of Addictive Behaviors. 19(2)(pp 131-139), 2005. Day JH, Miyamura K, Grant AD, Leeuw A, Munsamy J, Baggaley R and Churchyard GJ, 2003, Attitudes to HIV voluntary counselling and testing among mineworkers in South Africa: will availability of antiretroviral therapy encourage testing?, AIDS Care, 15: 5, 65-672 Denison JA, Higgins DL and Sweat MD, 2009, HIV testing and counseling, In: Mayer KH and Pizer HF(eds) HIV prevention: A comprehensive approach, Academic press, USA. DeWalque D, Dow WH and Nathan R, 2010, Evaluating Conditional Cash transfers to prevent HIV and other STIs in Tanzania, presentation at ASSA Meetings Atlanta. DiClemente RJ, Crosby RA and Kegler MC, 2009, Emerging theories in health promotion, practice and research, John Wiley and Sons, USA Durantini MR and Albarracín D, 2009, Material and social incentives to participation in behavioral interventions: A meta-analysis of gender disparities in enrollment and retention in experimental human immunodeficiency Virus prevention interventions, Health Psychology 2009:28:5; 631- 640, American Psychological Association. Eaton L, 2009, Trial that pays patients to take antipsychotic drugs comes under attack, BMJ 2009;339:b4202, doi: 10.1136/bmj.b4202. Eichler R, 2006, Can “Pay for Performance” increase utilization by the poor and improve the quality of health services?, Discussion paper for the first meeting of the working group on Performance Based Incentives, Center for Global Development Elwy AR, Hart GJ, Hawkes S and Petticrew M, 2002, Effectiveness of interventions to prevent sexually transmitted infections and human immunodeficiency virus in heterosexual men, Arch intern med.vol 162, sep 9, 1818-1830 Family Health International, 2002, Behavior change – A summary of four major theories, AIDSCAP, USA. Finkelstein EA, Brown DS, Brown DR and Buchner DM, 2008, A randomized study of financial incentives to increase physical activity among sedentary older adults, Preventive medicine 47: 2: 182-7 Fishbein M and Guinan M, 1996, Behavioral science and public health: A necessary partnership for HIV
  • 51. LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423 III prevention, Public Health Rep. 1996; 111(Suppl 1): 5–10. Fisher JD, 2005, HIV Risk Behavior Change Interventions for Seropositives: Initial Ideas on Theory and Practice, Presentation at 7th International AIDS impact Conference, Cape Town, South Africa FitzGerald JM, Patrick DM, Strathdee S, Rekart M, Elwood RK, Schecter MT, Montaner J and O'Shaughnessy M, 1999, Use of incentives to increase compliance for TB screening in a population of intravenous drug users. Vancouver Injection Drug Use Study Group, Int J Tuberc Lung Dis. 1999 Feb;3(2):153-5 Forde I and Zeuner D, 2009, Financial incentives to promote social mobility, BMJ 2009;339:b3219, doi: 10.1136/bmj.b3219 Gaither P, Brown W, Metz D, Nelson C and Bjornaraa J, 2009, Healthy Incentives, Healthyroads Inc. Galárraga O, Colchero MA, Wamai RG and Bertozzi SM, 2009, HIV prevention cost-effectiveness: a systematic review, BMC Public Health 2009, 9 (Suppl I):S5, doi:10.1186/1471-2458-9-S1-S5 Ghitza UE, Epstein DH and Preston KL, 2008, Contingency management reduces injection-related HIV risk behaviors in heroin and cocaine using outpatients, Addictive Behaviors, 2008 Apr; 33 (4): 593-604 Gift TL, Malotte CK, Ledsky R, Hogben M, Middlestadt S, Vandevanter NL, St Lawrence JS and GCAP Study Group, 2005, A cost-effectiveness analysis of interventions to increase repeat testing in patients treated for gonorrhea or chlamydia at public sexually transmitted disease clinics, Sex Transm Dis. 2005 Sep;32(9):542-9. Giuffrida A and Torgerson DJ, 1997, Should we pay the patient? Review of financial incentives to enhance patient compliance, BMJ 1997;315:703-707 Glick P, 2005, Scaling up HIV voluntary counseling and testing in Africa; What can evaluation studies tell us about potential prevention impacts?, Eval Review, 2005; 29(4): 331-57 Global HIV Prevention working group, 2008, Behaviour change and HIV prevention: (Re) considerations for the 21st century, accessed from www.globalhivprevention.org on 8 January 2010 Global HIV prevention working group, 2010, Global HIV prevention Progress report card 2010; Executive summary, accessed from www.globalhivprevention.org on 29 August 2010. Grabbe KL, Menzies N, Taegtmeyer M, Emukule G, Angala P, Mwega I, Musango G and Marum E, 2010, Increasing Access to HIV Counseling and Testing Through Mobile Services in Kenya: Strategies, Utilization, and Cost-Effectiveness, J. Acquir Immune Defic Syndr. 2010 1;54(3):317- 23. Hageman K, Tichacek A and Allen S, 2009, Couples’ voluntary counseling and testing, In: Mayer KH and Pizer HF(eds) HIV prevention: A comprehensive approach, Academic press, USA. Hagenzieker MP, Bijleveld FD, Davidse RJ, 1997, Effects of incentive programs to stimulate safety belt use: a meta-analysis, Accident Analysis & Prevention, Volume 29, Issue 6, November 1997, Pages 759-777 Halpern SD, 2005, Towards evidence based bioethics, BMJ 2005;331:901-903, doi: 10.1136/bmj.331.7521.901 Hanson T, Alessi SM and Petry NM, 2008, Contingency management reduces drug-related human immunodeficiency virus risk behaviors in cocaine-abusing methadone patients, Addiction. 2008 Jul;103(7):1187-97. Epub 2008 May 20. Harling G and Wood R, 2007, The evolving cost of HIV in South Africa: changes in health care cost with duration on antiretroviral therapy for public sector patients, J Acquir Immune Defic Syndr. 2007 Jul 1;45(3):348-54. Haug NA and Sorensen JL, 2006, Contingency management interventions for HIV-related behaviors, Curr HIV/AIDS Rep. 2006 Nov;3(4):154-9.. Haukoos JS, Witt MD, Coil CJ and Lewis RJ, 2005, The effect of financial incentives on adherence with outpatient human immunodeficiency virus testing referrals from the emergency department, Acad Emerg Med. 2005 Jul;12(7):617-21 Heil SH, Higgins ST, Bernstein IM, Solomon LJ, Rogers RE, Thomas CS, Badger GJ and Lynch ME,
  • 52. Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men IV 2008, Effects of voucher-based incentives on abstinence from cigarette smoking and fetal growth among pregnant women, Addiction 103: 6: 1009-18 Higgins ST and Petry NM, 1999, Contingency management: Incentives for sobriety, Alcohol research and Health, 1999, vol 23, no. 2:122-127 Higgins ST, Alessi SM and Dantona RL, 2002, Voucher-based incentives; A substance abuse treatment innovation, Addictive behaviors 27(2002) 887-910 Higgins ST, Heil SH, Solomon LJ, Bernstein IM, Lussier JP, Abel RL, Lynch ME, Badger GJ, 2004, A pilot study on voucher-based incentives to promote abstinence from cigarette smoking during pregnancy and postpartum, Nicotine Tob Res. 2004 Dec;6(6):1015-20. Holzemer WL and Uys LR, 2004, Managing AIDS Stigma, Journal of Social Aspects of HIV/AIDS, 2004, 1; 3; 165-170 Hutchinson PL and Mahlalela X, 2006, Utilization of voluntary counseling and testing services in the Eastern Cape, South Africa, AIDS Care July 2006; 18(5):446-455 Hutchinson PL, Mahlalela X and Yukich J, 2007, Mass media, Stigma and diwsclosure of HIV test results: Multilevel analysis in the Eastern Cape, South Africa, Aids education and prevention 2007, 19(6), 489-510 Indlu Yegazi, 2009, Program application (unpublished document) Jepson R, Clegg A, Forbes C, Lewis R, Sowden A and Kleijnen J, 2000, The determinants of screening uptake and interventions for increasing uptake: a systematic review, NHS Centre for reviews and dissemination, University of York, UK Jochelson K, 2007, Paying the patient: Improving health using financial incentives, King’s Fund, UK. Johnson L and Budlender D, 2002, HIV Risk Factors: A review of the demographic, socio-economic, biomedical and behavioural determinants of HIV prevalence in South Africa, Care Monograph No.8, Centre for Actuarial Research (CARE), Cape Town. Johnson L, Bradshaw D, Dorrington R and the South African Comparative Risk Assessment Collaborating Group, 2007, The burdens of disease attributable to sexually transmitted infections in South Africa in 2000, SAMJ 2007, Vol. 97, No.8; 658-662 Johnston L, O’Bra H, Chopra M, Mathews C, Townsend L, Sabin K, Tomlinson M, Kendall C, 2010, The associations of voluntary counseling and testing acceptance and the perceived likelihood of being HIV-infected among men with multiple sex partners in a South African Township, AIDS & Behavior 2010; 14; 4; 922-931 Kahn JG, Marseille E and Auvert B, 2006, Cost-effectiveness of male circumcision for HIV prevention in a South African setting, PLoS Medicine, 2006; 3;12; 2349-2358 Kalichman SC and Sambayi LC, 2003, HIV testing attitudes, AIDS stigma, and voluntary HIV Counselling and testing in a black township in Cape Town, South Africa, Sex Transm Infect 2003;79:442-447 Kalichman SC, Cain D, Weinhardt L, Benotsch E, Presser K, Zweben A, Bjodstrup B and Swain GR, 2005, Experimental Components Analysis of Brief Theory-Based HIV/AIDS Risk-Reduction Counseling for Sexually Transmitted Infection Patients, Health Psychology, Vol 24(2), Mar 2005, 198-208. doi: 10.1037/0278-6133.24.2.198 Kalichman SC, Simbayi LC, Cain D, Jooste S, Skinner D and Cherry C, 2006, Generalizing a model of health behaviour change and AIDS stigma for use with sexually transmitted infection clinic patients in Cape Town, South Africa, AIDS Care, 2006; 18(3):178-182 Kalichman SC, Simbayi LC, Cain D and Jooste S, 2008, Perceived HIV/AIDS Prevalence, burden and risk, Cape Town, South Africa, American Journal of Health Behavior (AM J HEALTH BEHAV), 2008 Nov-Dec; 32(6): 693-700 (14 ref) Kane RL, Johnson PE, Town RJ and Butler M, 2004, Economic incentives for preventive care, Evidence report/Technology Assessment nr. 101, AHRQ Publication No.04-E024-2 Kane RL, Johnson PE, Town RJ, Butler M, 2004a, A structured review of the effect of economic incentives on consumers' preventive behavior, American Journal of Preventive Medicine,
  • 53. LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423 V Volume 27, Issue 4, November 2004, Pages 327-352 Kelen GD, Hexter DA, Hansen KN, Humes R, Vigilance PN, Baskerville M and Quinn TC, 1996, Feasibility of an emergency department-based, risk-targeted voluntary HIV screening program, Ann Emerg Med. 1996 Jun;27(6):687-92 Kellog SH, Stitzer ML, Petry NM, Kreek MJ, no date, Contingency management: Foundation and principles, unpublished document, downloaded from http://www.nattc.org/pami/PDF/Contingency_Mgt_F_P.pdf on 27 September 2010 Kiene SM, Tennen H and Armeli S, 2008, Today I’ll use a condom, but who knows about tomorrow: A daily process study of variability in predictors of condom use, Health Psychology 2008; 27(4):463-472 Lagarde M, Haines A and Palmer N, 2007, Conditional cash transfers for improving uptake of health interventions in low-and middle income countries: A systematic review, JAMA. 2007; 298 (16): 1900-1910 (doi: 10.1001/jama.298.16.1900) Lagarde M, Haines A and Palmer N, 2009, The impact of conditional cash transfers on health outcomes and use of health services in low and middle income countries, Cochrane Database of systematic reviews 2009, Issue 4 Art.no.: CD008137. Leisegang R, Cleary S, Hislop M, Davidse A, Regensberg L, Little F and Maartens G, 2009, Early and late direct costs in a Southern African Antiretroviral treatment programme; a retrospective cohort analysis, Plos medicine 2009; 6; 12; e1000189 Lim SS, Dandona L, Hoisington JA, James SI, Hogan MC and Gakidou E, 2010, India’s Janani Suraksha Yojana, a conditional cash transfer programme to increase births in health facilities: an impact evaluation, Lancet 2010; 375: 2009-23 Loewenstein G, Brennan T and Volpp KG, 2007, Asymmetric paternalism to improve health behaviors, JAMA 2007; 298 (20): 2415-2417. Marseille E, Dandona L, Marshall N, Gaist P, Bautista-Arredondo S, Rollins B, Brtozzi SM, Coovadia J, Saba J, Lioznov D, Du Plessis JA, Krupitsky E, Stanley N, Over M, Peryshkina A, Kumar SGP, Muyingo S, Pitter C, Lundberg M and Kahn JG, 2007, HIV prevention costs and program scale: data from the PANCEA project in five low and middle-income countries, BMC Health Services Resarch 2007: 7: 108, accessed from http://www.biomedcentral.com/1472-6963/7/108 on 1 September 2010 Marteau TM, Ashcroft RE and Oliver A, 2009, Using financial incentives to achieve healthy behaviour, BMJ 2009;338:b1415, doi: 10.1136/bmj.b1415 Mathers CD, Salomon JA, Ezzati M, Begg S, Vander Hoorn S, Lopez AD, 2006, Global burden of disease and risk factors, chapter 5, http://www.dcp2.org/pubs/GBD/5/Section/864 accessed on 8 September 2010. Mayor S, 2007, NICE proposes incentives to keep addicts free of drugs, BMJ 2007;334:229, doi: 10.1136/bmj.39112.429190.DB Medlin C and DeWalque, 2008, Potential application of conditional cash transfers for prevention of sexual transmitted infections and HIV in Sub-Saharan Africa, Policy research working paper 4673, World Bank, Washington. Medlin C, Balkus J and Padian N, 2008, Developing minimum quality standards for HIV prevention interventions, UNAIDS Geneva. Mimiaga MJ, Reisner SL, Reilly L, Soroudi N and Safren SA, 2009, Individual interventions. In: Mayer KH and Pizer HF(eds) HIV prevention: A comprehensive approach, Academic press, USA. Morris SS, Flores R, Olinto P and Medina JM, 2004, Monetary incentives in primary health care and effects on use and coverage of preventive health care interventions in rural Honduras: cluster randomised trial, Lancet 2004; 364; 9450: 2030-2037 Munro S, Lewin S, Swart T and Volmink J., 2007, A review of health behaviour theories: how useful are these for developing interventions to promote long-term medication adherence for TB and HIV/AIDS, BMC Public health 2007, 7:104 NDOH - National Department of Health South Africa, 2008, The national HIV and Syphilis prevalence
  • 54. Using financial incentive to increase testing uptake and reduce risk behaviour in men VI survey South Africa 2007, South Africa Nyanzi-Wakholi B, Lara AM, Watera C, Munderi P, Gilks C and Grosskurth H, 2009, The role of HIV testing, counselling and treatment in coping with HIV/AIDS in Uganda: a qualitative analysis, AIDS Care, 21:7, 903-908 O’Donnell L, Bonaparte B, Joseph H, Agronick G, McLean LD, Myint-U A and Stueve A, 2009, Keep it up: development of a community-based helath screening and HIV prevention strategy for reaching young African men, AIDS Education and Prevention, 21(4), 299-313 Oliver A, 2009, Can financial incentives improve health equity? BMJ 2009;339:b3847, doi: 10.1136/bmj.b3847 Peltzer K, Matseke G, Mzolo T and Majaja M, 2009, Determinants of knowledge of HIV status in South Africa: results from a population-based HIV survey, BMC Public Health 2009, 9:174, doi:10.1186/1471-2458-9-174 Petry NM, 2010, Contingency management treatment: controversies and challenges, Addiction 2010; 105; 1507 Petry NM, Martin B and Finocche C, 2001, Contingency management in group treatment: a demonstration project in an HIV drop-in center, Subst Abuse Treat. 2001 Sep;21(2):89-96. Petry NM, Tedord J, Austin M, Nick C, Caroll KM and Rounsaville BJ, 2004, Prize reinforcement contingency management for treating cocaine users; how low can we go, and with whom?, Addiction; 99; 349-360. Petry NM, Weinstock J, Alessi SM, Lewis MW and Dieckhaus K, 2010, Group-based randomized trial of contingencies for health and abstinence in HIV patients, J Consult Clin Psychol. 2010 Feb;78(1):89-97. Pilling S, Strang J and Gerada C, 2007, Psychosocial interventions and opioid detoxification for drug misuse: summary of NICE guidance, BMJ 2007;335:203-205, doi: 10.1136/bmj.39265.639641.AD Pisani E, 2008, The wisdom of whores, W.w. Norton and Company, New York (USA) Powers CL, Mathu-Muju KR and Bush HM, 2009, Effect of a financial incentive on returning for post- operative care following general anesthesia, J Clin Pediatr Dent 33(4):374-350 Razavi MS, Gaumer G and Wallack S (eds), 2009, What is known about demand and other related interventions to improve access and strengthen health care systems in low- and middle income countries?, Schneider Institutes for Health policy, Brandeis University, USA. Rigsby MO, Rosen MI, Beauvais JE, Cramer JA, Rainey PM, O'Malley SS, Dieckhaus KD and Rounsaville BJ , 2000, Cue-dose training with monetary reinforcement; pilot study of an antiretroviral adherence intervention, J. Gen Intern Med 2000;15:841-847 Roll JM, Petry NM, Stitzer ML, Brecht ML, Peirce JM, McCann MJ, Blaine J, MacDonald M, DIMaria J, Lucero L and Kellog S, 2006, Contingency management for the treatment of methamphetamine use disorders, Am. J. Psychiatry, 2006; 163; 1993-1999. Rosen MI, Dieckhaus K, McMahon TJ, Valdes B, Petry NM, Cramer J and Rounsaville B, 2007, Improved adherence with contingency management, AIDS Patient Care & STDs, 2007 Jan; 21 (1): 30-40 Rutledge SE, Roffman RA, Picciano JF, Kalichman SC and Berghuis JP, 2002, HIV prevention and attrition: Challenges and Opportunities, AIDS & Behavior, 2002 Mar; 6(1): 69-82 (63 ref) Sanderson C and Gruen R, 2006, Analytical models for decision making, Open University Press, LSHTM. Schafer M, 2010, Using conditional cash transfers to control sexual transmitted infections and HIV, Discussion papers on Social protection, Issue no. 5, GTZ. Schmidt H, Gerber A and Stock S, 2009, What can we learn from German health incentive schemes?, BMJ 2009;339:b3504, doi: 10.1136/bmj.b3504 Schroeder JR, Epstein DH, Umbricht A and Preston KL, 2006, Changes in HIV risk behaviors among patients receiving combined pharmacological and behavioral interventions for heroin and
  • 55. LSHTM: MPH –HSM: T6423 VII cocaine dependence, Addict Behav. 2006 May;31(5):868-79. Epub 2005 Aug 8. Seaverson EL, Grossmeier J, Miller TM and Anderson DR, 2009, The role of incentive design, incentive value, communications strategy, and worksite culture on health risk assessment participation, Am J Health Promot. 2009 May-Jun;23(5):343-52 Shisana O, Rehle T, Simbayi L, Zuma K, Jooste S and Pillay-van-Wyk V, 2009, South African National HIV prevalence, incidence, behaviour and communication survey 2008: A turning tide among teenagers? HSRC, Cape Town. Sindelar J, Elbel B and Petry NM, 2007, What do we get for our money? Cost-effectiveness of adding contingency management, Addiction, 2007 Feb; 102 (2): 309-16 Smith S, Sinclair D, Raine R and Reeves B, 2005, Health care evaluation, Open University Press, LSHTM. Sorensen JL, Haug NA, Delucchi KL, Gruber V, Kletter E, Batki SL, Tulsky JP, Barnett P and Hall S, 2007, Voucher reinforcement improves medication adherence in HIV-positive methadone patients: a randomized trial, Drug and Alcohol Dependence 88 (2007) 54–63 Steinberg J, 2008, Three letter plague: A young men’s journey through a great epidemic, Jonathan Ball Publishers, Johannesburg. Stitzer ML and Petry NM, 2006, Contingency management for treatment of substance abuse, Annual Review Clinical Psychology 2; 411-431. Stone EG, Morton SC, Hulscher ME, Maglione MA, Roth EA, Grimshaw JM, Mittman BS, Rubenstein LV, Rubenstein LZ and Shekelle PG, 2002, Interventions that increase use of adult immunization and cancer screening services: A meta-analysis, Annals of Internal Medicine. 136(9)(pp 641-651), 2002. Szmukler G, 2009, Financial incentives for patients in the treatment of psychosis, J Med Ethics 2009, 35:224-228 Tulsky JP, Pilote L, Hahn JA, Zolopa AJ, Burke M, Chesney M and Moss AR, 2000, Adherence to isoniazid prophylaxis in the homeless: a randomized controlled trial, Archives of internal medicine 160: 5: 697-702 UNAIDS and WHO, 2004, Policy statement on HIV Testing, 2004, Geneva UNAIDS, 1999, Sexual behavior change for HIV: Where have theories taken us?, Geneva. UNAIDS, 2000, Costing guidelines for HIV prevention strategies, Geneva. UNAIDS, WHO and UNICEF, 2009, Towards Universal Access – Progress report, Geneva (Switzerland) Valdiserri RO, Ogden LL and McCray E, 2003, Accomplishments in HIV prevention science: implications for stemming the epidemic, Nature Medicine (2003), Vol 9: no 7: 881-886 Villano CL, Rosenblum A, Magura S and Fong C, 2002, Improving treatment engagement and outcomes for cocaine-using methadone patients, The American Journal of Drug and Alcohol Abuse, 28; 2; 213-230 Volmink J and Garner P, 1997, Systematic review of randomised controlled trials of strategies to promote adherence to tuberculosis treatment, BMJ 1997;315:1403-1406 Volpp KG, 2009, Paying people to loose weight and stop smoking, LDI Issue brief vol 14, no. 3, Leonard Davis Institute of Health Economics Volpp KG, John LK, Troxel AB, Norton L, Fassbender J and Loewenstein G, 2008a, Financial incentive- based approaches for weight loss: a randomized trial, JAMA : the journal of the American Medical Association; 2008; 300: 22: 2631-7 Volpp KG, Levy AG, Asch DA, Berlin JA, Murphy JJ, Gomez A, Sox H, Zhu J and Lerman C, 2006, A randomized controlled trial of financial incentives for smoking cessation, Cancer Epidemiol Biomarkers Prev 2006; 15(1):12-8 Volpp KG, Loewenstein G, Troxel AB, Doshi J, Price M, Laskin M and Kimmel SE, 2008, A test of financial incentives to improve warfarin adherence, BMC Health Services Research. 8, 2008. Article Number: 272.