SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 17
Download to read offline
Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2153128Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2153128
220
Imperfect Alternatives and the Invisible Elephant:
The Complex Nature of Environmental Governance
Jovita L. De Loatch
Environmental governance decisions, like other public policies, are often based upon the
assumption that having the ‘correct’ legal principles is the key to describing and prescribing the
law. Yet, one of the most inescapable and persistent issues in law is its very concept.99
Western civil
law and common law scholars have sought to understand where, how and in what form100
law
emerges. How do normative orders form legal orders, or juridicities?
Moreover, law is not only founded on legal principles but also set within a wider social, economic,
cultural as well as environmental context. As interdisciplinary approaches to the study of law
expand, disciplines such as the sociology of law and legal anthropology have exposed how
dogmatic principles can often be incongruent with the legal reality or law in practice.101
Instead
alternative normative orders seem to emerge, each being complex and imperfect. By contrast, the
economic analysis of law generally has sought to view normative behavior through the narrower
lens of market exchange in which an ‘invisible hand’ simply guides ‘rational’ agents to the optimal
solution.102
In recent years much has been learned from nonlinear dynamics and complex adaptive
systems about how complex and imperfect [normative] behaviors can emerge from simple rules
(Miller and Page 2007). The approach taken here unites these seemingly contradictory perspectives
in order to portray the emergence of self-organizing governance alternatives. The article proposes a
means to structure a multi-disciplinary analysis of Corsican governance to better understand the
underlining decision-making process and frame the corresponding forces that form legal orders.
99
See classic works such as Max Weber’s 1922 Economy and Society and Émile Durkheim’s 1895 The Rules of
Sociological Method, as well as the seminal 1961 The Concept of Law by L. H. A. Hart placing law into a social
context among others.
100
Pierre Bourdieu defined the process ”[t]o codify (the law), it is simultaneously to formulate and to formalize. There
is an inherent virtue of the form (created), and cultural control is always a master of the forms.” (Bourdieu 1993 : 60).
All translations from the original versions of non-Enllish texts have been made by the author.
101
See Moore 1978, Ost and van de Kerchove 2002 and supra at note 1.
102
For the historical context and critique of commonly applied neoclassical law and economic models promoted in neo-
liberal politics see Fried 1998 and Pollinsky 1974.
Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2153128Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2153128
221
1) Constructing Fields of Juridicity
The challenges posed by complex legal phenomena including discovering how a process of
informal governance that is rooted in local, communal, extra-territorial or even global interactions,
can evolve largely autonomous from state doctrine, the juridicity of which may be affirmed on the
simple basis of the ‘acceptance’ by a group or community. Étienne Le Roy asserts that juridicity
comprises: 1) general and impersonal norms, 2) models of proper behavior and 3) as introduced by
Bourdieu, systems of durable dispositions (Le Roy 1999: 201-202).103
By creating a complex
adaptive framework of Le Roy’s paradigm, quantitative and qualitative social science methods will
mutually benefit from the closer integration of cultural observations and learned hypotheses on the
emergence of legal orders. It can serve to “…compress the social, economic, political, and juridical
elements together with the levels international, national, and local, in a single…” (Moore 2006:
134) not simply symbolic formula, but as a scaffold for a practicable quantifiable adaptive
framework that may be replicated and tested.
In an adaptive framework of this paradigm, general and impersonal norms can be expressed in
terms of individual efficiency assessments compared to socially efficient assessment of the
community where models of proper behavior seek to align the individual with the social incentives
of the community through pressures exerted by the relevant and enduring community institutions.104
Bourdieu defined the concept of habitus as “…systems of durable, transposable dispositions,
structured structures predisposed to function as structuring structures, that is, as principles of the
generation and structuring of practices and representations… without presupposing a conscious
aiming… being all this, collectively orchestrated without being the product of … a conductor.”
(Bourdieu 1977: 72). Habitus is itself a generative dynamic structure that adapts and accommodates
itself to other dynamic structures and sub-structures composed primarily of other actors, situated
practices and durable institutions (fields) (Lizardo 2004: 375–401). In the same manner, Le Roy
underlines, “… the field of ‘juridicity’ of ‘habitus’ is not predetermined. It lives, ebbs and flows, as
in inter-normativity phenomena studies of Jean Carbonnier” (Le Roy 1999: 200).
Thus, it is a system of lasting, transposable dispositions that, integrates past experiences, functions
at every moment as a matrix of perceptions, appreciations, and actions, and makes possible the
achievement of infinitely diversified tasks, thanks to analogical transfers of schemes permitting the
solution of similarly shaped problems (Lizardo 2004: 375–401). This is where habitus becomes a
103
See also Le Bris, Le Roy & Matthieu 1991 : 13-14.
104
For a discussion of this concept see De Loatch 2009.
Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2153128Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2153128
222
helpful and flexible way to conceptualize social structure and uncover the most deeply buried
structures of the different social worlds that form the social universe, as well as the "mechanisms"
that tend to ensure their reproduction or transformation. Bourdieu adds “…habitus is the structures
constitutive of a particular type of environment. [T]he practices produced by the habitus [are] the
strategy-generating principle enabling agents to cope with unforeseen and ever-changing
situations” (Bourdieu 1977: 72).
2) A Functional Concept of Community
In order to further envisage the field of juridicity of habitus, my starting place consisted in
establishing a functional concept of a community105
that a law intended to benefit. As an American
researcher in Paris conducting initial fieldwork on the French island of Corsica (De Loatch 2009),
the identity and nationalism of the Corsican people was crucial to the question of a proposed French
environmental policy for the Corsican littoral. Who are the Corsicans, exactly? Dare I ask the taboo
question of whether the Corsicans are a separate people from the French?106
Without a clearer
understanding of their identity in relation to the island of Corsica and to France, one cannot
penetrate below the surface.
The stated objective of the PADDUC proposal107
by the French government was to alter current
land use practices to promote its vision of ‘sustainable’ economic development of coastal lands,
many of which have been historically under the management of village collectives on Corsica.
Conducting fieldwork in a small village near the coast in the Balagne region of Corsica allowed the
opportunity to observe the bond between people and place. This bond reveals a major symbolic
relationship or rapport system with the occupied land and the process of association by a particular
culture108
or social group. Bourdieu, among others, observed that social groups are the result of a
continuous process rather than the expressions of fixed structures or species (Bourdieu 1980). A
society is durable because it is an assembly of people and objects, and the impact of the society
105
Étienne Le Roy provides three appealing challenges in the identification of communities of concern to ‘patrimonial
governance,’ of which I find two relevant to this paradigm: 1) the need to identify the diversity of the interests and 2)
the conception of a functional design of the community. (Le Roy 2008).
106
I have been told that this is quite a taboo question in France actually; as France emphasizes the unity of the Republic
and does not officially recognize diverse cultural communities, just French citizens.
107
Le Plan d'aménagement et de développement durable de la Corse (PADDUC) or the Management and Sustainable
Development Plan of Corsica was assigned to the Territorial Community of Corsica (CTC) by the French Law of
January 22, 2002 (n°2002-92), on Corsica (article 12).
108
The local laws regarding any act “… include a priori all the practices of uses, occupation, of the grounds, on
territories (within the meaning of delimited spaces), defined by them, according to rules locally recognized”
(Rochegude 2006: 87)
223
comes partly from these objects (such as the land) that are intricately woven into its fabric. Without
these interconnections, the society loses its contextual interaction and cultural / human social
rapport, and its roots in time, ground and territorial space. The habitus of the Corsican peoples i.e.,
a vision of “the total man,” as put forth by Marcel Mauss (1934: 8), is a kind of connector of the
physiological, psychological components and societies of humans. This “system of provisions to
the practice” produces a “tendency to act in a regular way” and a manner of acting that “does not
find its principle in a rule or explicit law” (Bourdieu 1977: 72-95). Habitus “is part dependent on
the blur and vagueness” of the Corsican people themselves.
One finds in Corsica, in fact, a lyrical and convivial society that allows each individual agent to find
its own place in the space. Formal and informal institutional associations prolong and deepen the
rooting of the symbolic system and connection with others. Through the Corsican village
institutions a bond is woven into the structure of the physical island space. It is this distinction from
the ‘French’ that Corsicans, as a people bonded to the island of Corsica, appear to claim.
These communal relationships encircling the island require membership based on adhesion to the
institutions embedded in the villages. Gauging the degree of this adhesion also helps to define the
parameters of it’s functional concept. Membership in these institutions implies acts of exclusion
and of border building. Opposition between the initiates and the foreigners rests on the way in
which one fosters close adhesion to the local institutional associations. Knowing one or more
families in the village, taking an interest in learning the Corsican language or Corsican music, or
being a member of an association or a closely affiliated outside group, such as the environmental
group Surfrider, can all play a part by blurring the lines between foreigners and the initiates.
Corsicans are influenced by their institutional membership in musical associations as well. The
power of this type of local knowledge also helps to give some visitors the advantage of gaining
adhesion and being distinguished from unknown foreigners. Music is very closely related to the
collective life of the Corsicans of the Balagne, and its interconnection with the Corsican community
emanates from the very heart of the island. Music-making in Corsica can serve to vehicle the
complexities of Corsican social structures, their memberships and the tensions through the
Corsicans’ dedication to seek, create, carry out and listen to their polyphonic songs and by their
negotiating the contexts to which the Corsican music belongs.109
109
In one case, villagers informed their welcomed visitors to remove their car radio antenna to reduce the theft risk of
the vehicle in a Corsican village. The antenna can be seen locally as a symbolic adhesion to the French on the continent,
because one can only listen to ‘la musique française’ with an antenna, but without it, one shows a subtle act of
solidarity with the local music traditions of Corsica. Moreover, there seems to be a distinction between the initiates,
224
Thus, forming community rapports requires social investment, not simply private investment (such
as through property ownership) to establish the bonds of membership. The social relationships that
form the foundation of community can be expressed in terms of economic factors, such as the
accumulation of capital and extraction of rent, in addition to the legal standards of appropriation
and methods of payment in the settlement of conflicts (Le Bris, Le Roy & Matthieu 1991: 13-14).
This ‘authorized’ capital facilitates abstract human exchange, ‘lubricates’ the civil society and
provides a voluntary supply of collective goods. It promotes confidence, increasing foreseeable
behavior and reducing the costs of transaction (Svensden and Svensden 2003), thus providing
incentives to form the bonds necessary to encourage mutual trust. The cornerstone of this kind of
social capital rests on the cultural foundations of trust and assurances of mutual cooperation.
These acts of investment in authorized capital can be seen in the efforts of a person with family ties
to a village using her notoriety and wealth to renovate the village church, a tourist (or researcher)
gaining acceptance in the village to become a `welcomed visitor' by taking part in a community
beach cleanup day, or summer vacationers uniting with the villagers to protect local vegetation
from a mountain flood. Following Bourdieu, the focus must be on the ‘economy in practice.’ In
other words, it should be on ‘economic’ calculations that are behind not only obvious economic
practices, but also the more hidden practices and more symbolic systems in order to better account
for less ‘rational’ behaviors. These acts have the collective value of establishing and enforcing
social norms and social relations, as well as allowing coordination of actions to achieve common
goals. They also affect attitudes and mental provisions supporting co-operation in village social life
(see, Coleman 1964 : 381-405).
Nevertheless, one must avoid the impulse to create a dualistic opposition between the initiates and
the foreigners, which would function only as an obstacle to a realistic construction of a theory of
cultural dynamics. A complex analysis involves a continuum that is not simply a question of
quantity of connections, but also of the individual quality of the relationship with the institutions of
the village. These connections include, but are not limited to: religious, musical or environmental
organizations, family antecedents in the village or on the island, the investment in and protection of
the communal grounds of the village, proximity of work, time spent in the village and, to a lesser
degree, the ownership of property in the region. The mechanisms that bind authorized capital are
networks of the reciprocal rapports that depend on trust and assist in the creation of reciprocity
who live as members of the village, and the foreigners, who are characterized as treating the local space like an object
without heart and simply exploit its resources.
225
norms (Ostrom 2005). For example, after having taken part in the shared activities of the village, a
welcomed visitor received a fruit basket from the garden of a local neighbor. Incorporating
Coleman, the authorized capital is a neutral resource that facilitates without regard to the nature or
the initiator or the transaction. This connection refers to the value assigned to the authorized capital
in the social networks, between the initiates and the local community, opening a bridge between the
two (Coleman 1964: 269-287).
Much like the social networks created by the shepherds in Sardinia (Ruffino 2005), one often notes
that each agent establishes bonds by occasional expressions or the sharing of local knowledge in
order to reveal social dimensions or maps. To do so in spatial terms is to recognize that the social
map results from plotting difference and diversity, and their actual outcomes (de Sousa Santos
1995: 399-473). These dimensions overlap and intertwine, producing a complex social map of
aspirations, reflecting and reinforcing its cultural, social and economic divisions. These maps are
also very effective in establishing the orientation of physical space rapports or symbolic systems.
According to Boaventura de Sousa Santos, maps capture three elements: scale, projection, and
symbolization. Each map is created by scale that is not only quantitative but also qualitative, and
projection that is “… the process used by the legal order to define the limits of its operation and to
organize this legal space…” (de Sousa Santos 1988: 363-388). The symbolization contained in
maps is the visible side of the representation of reality. Its operation is based on and conditioned by
the scale and projection, and relates to the representation with symbols of the characteristics and
details of the reality that were selected.
These maps consciously and subconsciously are established, recognized and negotiated, and the
need for maintaining them and for reinforcing the rapports through service, reciprocal hospitality,
and expressions of good will and friendship, is consciously identified. The maps are intricate in that
each individual has her bonds, her stakes, and her manner of becoming part of the community,
varying remarkably according to the bonds that are established and reinforced with time. The
aggregation of these individual maps shared by the social network forms the local knowledge that
helps to define the cultural map. Each act helps to reinforce and clarify the distinction between the
Corsicans and the continental French, or between the autochthones and the tourists. The unfolding
of these dynamics reflects the drive towards cultural self-definition and community identity
inherent in each, establishing cultural self-similarity. The use of network data aggregation and
analysis by social scientist, whether through direct fieldwork or cultural, economic, social and even
226
environmental informatics110
can help to recreate this map and provide a way to visualize a shared
scientific structure. By studying the ways this drive manifests (its origin and characteristics;
catalysts and inhibitors; and factors that support, sustain and reproduce), the dynamics of this
‘autopoietic’ or 'self-organizing’ system (often seen as resulting in unstable "turbulent-like" social
forces and associated with "chaotic" behavior - Teubner 1993) may also be investigated.
3) Institutional Incentives Effecting Cultural Translation
In addition to establishing a functional concept of the community, ascertaining the institutional
structures that are equipped to influence or coerce compliance to law in practice is also needed.
Neoclassical institutional approaches in the economic analysis of law have created models that
assume no transaction costs, and that assume the final allocation of rights (such as land use rights)
is always efficient, regardless of the initial entitlement (Coase 1937 and Coase 1960). However, by
failing to incorporate environmental, social and cultural externalities and transaction cost, these
simplistic models built directly from the neoclassical interpretation of Coase’s ‘theorem’ have
struggled to capture real world dynamics and more complex phenomena. These types of analyses
can prove to be too narrow, too simplistic, and rely too much on assertions and assumptions about
reality. Despite the fact that this limited interpretation of economic analysis of law has some
descriptive and explanatory power, many of the subtleties of human behavior are omitted or
unexplained. Game theory models and behavioral economics have moved beyond this limited view.
However, there still is a need to compare observations of real world behavior governing social
autopoiesis with theoretical and experimental models and simulations.
In fact, Ronald Coase and what has become New Institutional Economics (‘NIE’) have no interest
in the narrow “neoclassical assumptions that individuals have perfect information and unbounded
rationality and that transactions are costless and instantaneous (Menard 2000: 46-54). NIE “…
considers choices to be embedded in the institutions… [thus having] a much broader reach than
neoclassical economics, which has been largely concerned with prices and outcomes … As
Kenneth Arrow observed … [NIE ask questions as to] why economic institutions emerged the way
they did … [In addition, Douglas] North has pointed out [i]nstitutionalist …understand change by
110
Informatics has created new sources and tools for interdisciplinary research of networks with computational data
collection. “Informatics is the science of information. It studies the representation, processing, and communication of
information in natural and artificial systems. Since computers, individuals and organizations all process information,
informatics has computational, cognitive and social aspects.” See entry for ‘informatics’ in International Encyclopedia
of Information and Library Science (second edition) (0415259010) John Feather and Paul Sturges eds., Routledge,
2002.
227
understanding human incentives and intentions and the beliefs, norms and rules that they create in
pursuit of their goals” (Menard and Shirley 2005: 2). [Elinor] Ostrom stresses “…the regularized
plans that individuals make within the structure of incentives [is] produced by rules, norms, and
expectations of the likely behavior of others affected by relevant physical and material conditions.”
(Ostrom 2005a: 825).
The tools of NIE analysis of law can provide a way to frame how a community’s institutions
establish positive and negative social incentives for obtaining community adhesion. The costs of
transaction are evaluated according to the manner in which the institutional frameworks provide
incentives (or disincentives) for agents to engage in a given activity or behavior. In this way, an
individual’s personal incentives can fail to align with social incentives of the community, falling
well short of the optimal social equilibrium and outside the social norm determined by a communal
valuation of such things as the scarce natural resources of the Corsican coast. The pressures to align
with the norms of community create various incentives to align the individual with this social norm,
its optimal social balance.
Thus, the individual’s efficiency assessment conflicts with the socially efficient assessment. For
those individuals who do not understand or do not heed the community’s prescription for the
optimal social balance, an explosive (and sometimes violent) form of communication can be
offered on the island of Corsica. The underlying problem with this individual efficiency assessment
is that a foreign individual may be unaware of or ignore the costs (or benefits) that she imposes on
others in the village. This “free rider” problem leads to, in the case of cost imposition, the under-
supply of the collective public good, and forces a reduction in the collective public interest of the
village. Accordingly, a sanction for ignorance of the custom can appear. This sanction can be a
legal consequence of an attitude or of a behavior relating to the social norms in which it is located.
Between these efficiency assessments it “... is not thus only to fight, it is also to get along on
legitimacy or illegitimacy of these practices … the law of a society is ordered thus around the limits
of the spheres of action of each one in these fields; it holds for vital: it is at the same time consensus
on these limits and practices, aiming or succeeding to confirm them or moving them” (Alliot 1983:
85–6).
Adopting the concept of fixed action patterns,111
the replication of norms promotes cultural pattern
111
Sharing with anthropology the concern of the importance of context, ethologist (who study animal subjects in their
environment) have defined a fixed action pattern as a behavior that occurs in a fairly intact form even in the absence of
experience or learning but can be further refined by experience. (Sapolsky 2005: 267-281 and 395). In this way cultural
action patterns embed its history and sense of identity within the social map as discussed below.
228
emergence in community behavior. The legal standards of ‘everyday life’ rest on the ideals and
criteria developed by the community. As a result, they build upon and cultivate their customary
laws. The individual is thus confronted by these community incentives as a method to cure the
conflict between the individual evaluation and social efficiency evaluation of the community. One
must also consider the level of pressure exerted by the community to have its norms replicated as an
exact translation or transposition, promoting a pattern in cultural behavior to emerge. Translation
factors modify a cultural action pattern’s emergence based on: an institution’s ability to promote or
repress a given cultural practice, valuation or use of an object such as the coastal land; the degree of
network connectivity affecting information exchange; the enforcement and reinforcement of norms;
the degree of norm rigidity (or conversely flexibility) of the community; and the variability of
cultural reproduction affecting the institutional structures.
Trade-offs calculations (the costs of exchanges) are made continuously among the structures, where
incentives alter the structural map of social norms. The power of these incentives rests on the threat
of symbolic sanctions and, from time to time, real sanctions. It is a risk that everyone in the
community must control. Risk is the median value of the consequences of the affected events. One
of the difficulties in risk management is the fact that the consequence is often uncertain. Direct
quantitative measurements and data collection can prove complicated. However, one can identify
and evaluate risks on a collective level of the social efficiency of the custom of the community.
Like the conscious or subconscious utilization of mathematical probabilities by an individual, one
can estimate the difference between an individual’s personal efficiency assessment and the
efficiency assessment of the community. It is through fieldwork techniques that one can observe
and measure ordinal preferences and the quality of the risk in a given social interaction. This
ordinal measurement of utility can be used to describe the bundle of rights or preferences of an
individual compared with the social evaluation of the customs of the community that define the
limits of the legal order and help to organize the legal space. This economic calculation is behind
not only the obvious economic practices, but also more hidden practices and more symbolic
systems that are characteristic and help to reveal the details of the reality of the community. Thus,
many material and immaterial economies may exist for ‘market’ exchange.
4) Juridicity as a Complex Adaptive System
The literature on complex systems has spread from the study of natural systems to the study of
229
social systems.112
Chaotic behaviors are beginning to be explained in terms of nonlinear dynamics
and arise naturally in areas as diverse as evolutionary biology, applied mathematics, game theory,
quantum mechanics, coding and information theory. Complexity theory’s impact on economics has
helped to shift focus from equilibrium models to nonlinear dynamics, “…as researchers recognize
that economics, like ecosystems, may never settle down into an equilibrium (Lansing 2003: 193).
Similarly, “…the aspects that may be of greatest interest to anthropologists have to do with the
emergent properties of social and behavioral systems (Lansing 2003: 193). By adapting economic
tools to nonlinear dynamics, empirical and measurable observations from anthropological and
sociological research may be able to be ordered, analyzed and compared with other observations in
the search for key institutions and explanatory variables. The idea that an institutional analysis of
social incentives, like much of the physical and biological world, is generated by a recursive
process creating a fractal structure,113
is an intriguing and potentially powerful direction for this
type of research. The ultimate goal is to begin to frame real world cultural dynamics in order to
compare alternatives, to determine the model’s descriptive and predictive capacities and to test it
against the theoretical and experimental models currently offered.
In a nonlinear dynamic construction of ‘juridicity,’ the transposition of dispositions can be ordered
in terms of 1) a ‘bounded’ social trajectory114
that serves to map the social norms of the
community, 2) institutional transposition or translation factors’ that effect the variance of
reproduction of the norm, 3) observation of or informatics on the scale of network and the quality
of its interconnections and 4) variation over interaction events, time or other intervals. The social
trajectory creates a map represented by a simple dichotomy of choices or a more complex range of
behaviors in which informatics analysis and ordinal measurements of utility can be used to describe
a bundle of rights or cultural preferences. On this map, in the abstract, cultural reproduction would
create an exact replica of social norms, an exact reflective mirror image of the dispositions in its
next iteration. In reality, errors in translation are introduced with each individual’s interpretation of
the norm despite the influence or coercive power of the institutions that guide and limit the cultural
action patterns used to define the limits of social behavior and to organize the legal space.115
For
112
For a general overview see Miller & Pages 2007 and Mitchell Melanie, 2009: 368. Specific examples include
Lansing J. Stephen, 2006: 240, and multi-disciplinary authors, Liu et al. 2007.
113
See Ruhl 1997 and Benoit Mandelbrot's theory of fractional dimensions highlights the relativity of measure with
respect to scale and emphasizes the kinship of his ideas with the emphasis on the perspective of the observer
(Mandelbrot and Hudson 2004: 97).
114
As defined in Bourdieu 1977: 86.
115
In another example, for the Swedish research program Sustainable Coastal Zone Management, in conflicts analysis
studies, its version of ‘mapping’ of stakeholders and their interest was included in the complex adaptive methodology,
noting that “[m]ore recently formulated criteria for sustainable resource management include socially robust systems
230
example, the degree of network connectivity affecting information exchange dramatically changed
when a collective in favor of the "coastal protection law" was launched on the internet gathering
scores of associations, ecologists and some local political parties (nationalist, greens, socialist,
communist…) in favor of this popular initiative. Enforcement and reinforcement of norms grew
denouncing “… the pressures exerted by some `property [and] recreational developers, architects,
[and] elected political within the framework of PADDUC.”116
It is this diachronic process of
constant renovation, generating a dynamic cultural action pattern that enables juridicities to
emerge. Mapping this space will help to organize observations and graphically illustrate how
individual agents as a group cope with unforeseen and ever-changing situations, thus managing risk
through the strategy-generating principles embedded in the structuring of practices and
representations. The bundle of rights that serve to apportion the risk can be used to identify
alternatives in governance. The ultimate goal of this emerging framework is to most efficiently
place the burden of that risk.117
What complex systems can do is highlight this connection by
demonstrating that risk premiums may be much higher than one would expect with a more
conventional statistical distribution (Farber 1997).
Analogous to scale in the de Sousa Santos maps discussed above, in this construction of the field of
juridicity, the aggregation of the individual information maps disseminate through the shared social
networks. In terms of quantity, institutional structures may exist on global, national, regional, local,
communal or other scales of connectivity. Qualitatively, scale also infers a kind of order that
requires transformations of scale to consistently replicate the same range of possibilities guiding
cultural action patterns across other active scales. In other words, when the influence or the
coercive power of institutions on each scale of connectivity exhibit the maximum of invariance
(thus the most similarity) in cultural action patterns.
This offers a new criterion to determine whether social incentives proposed in laws like PADDUC
on the scale of French national and regional bureaucracy will introduce scaling failures given the
wide variance between efficiency assessments of the official law of the French Republic compared
with the components of participation, knowledge integration, and maintaining biological and cultural diversity through
pluri-centric adaptive systems” (Bruckmeier 2005: 65-66).
116
The petition continues, “[PADDUC] is contrary to the collective interests of all the Corsicans. Indeed, its economic
priorities are founded on coastal tourist mono-activity and residential economy…” (Pétition contre le Projet de
PADDUC en Corse http://cll-corse.org/, accessed 09/05/09.) The network binding of the social trajectory reinforces the
mapping of social norms of the coastal area collectives. After the creation of this social network, musical associations
renewed their interest in taking part in island politics by opposing the proposed French legislative transposition, in spite
of the fact that many of the associations receive significant monetary support from the French regional Executive
council of the Corsican territorial collectivity. (De Loatch 2009 : 60).
231
to the scale of the customary law of the Corsicans or to the scale of global environmental
institutions reinforcing the public local competence.118
Scaling failures may also be seen when
PADDUC’s incentives are compared to a chosen efficiency criteria, such as based on an efficiency
principle for sustainable development (see De Loatch 2008) or compare with other theoretical or
experimental results. The degree of self-similarity of cultural action patterns can be tested across
scales by assessing translation factor incentives in each network’s implementation of norms.
4) The Complex Nature of Environmental Governance
Like an elephant, invisible when viewed in the darkness, one’s perspective is limited to only the
part of the elephant that one can grasp within a discipline. Thus, one can be misled into incorrect
conclusions and misinterpretations as to the whole. This is a modest attempt to take a step back, to
gain enough perspective that the elephant’s shape emerges out of obscurity and the myriad of
influencing variables. The courage of alternatives in environmental governance relies not only on
building an interdisciplinary framework that can better approximate the complex dynamics at work
but also in confronting our own rigid disciplinary constructs, exposing new perspectives in human
behavioral phenomenon.
This initial outline of a framework of juridicity in Corsican society suggests how institutional social
incentives help to regulate behaviors. Through legal anthropology and sociology we find a lucid
and critical analytical method of examining the crucial relationship between law, cultural and social
life in an age of increasing interconnectivity within the global economy. Equally, economic analysis
of law can help shine a harsh bright light on the murky area where the rule of law comes into
contact with and is shaped by economic power. For present purposes, the modest goal of this article
is a tentative exploration of the possibility of using nonlinear dynamics to provide a conceptual
framework for thinking about a wide variety of temporal progressions, based on dynamics of
complex systems and on preliminary empirical evidence. Complexity theory offers new ways to
explore the topoi at the bases of juridicity, continuing to broaden the multi-disciplinary structure of
social dynamics and perhaps providing a new means to confront the demands and challenges of
otherness, complexity and interculturality (Eberhard 2011: 23ss), while allowing for an intercultural
comparison of institutional structures within complex adaptive systems.
117
The burden of environmental risk is always borne somewhere, or more precisely, with someone (often less
developed third countries or future generations in the case of environmental damage). Someone, somewhere, at
sometime will bear the cost of the risks that are taken (De Loatch 2008).
118
See Rochegude 2005 : 59-72.
232
BIBLIOGRAPHY
ARROW Kenneth J., 1974, The Limits of Organization, New York, W. W. Norton & Company, 86
p.
ARROW Kenneth J., 1963, Social Choice and Individual Values, New Haven and London, Yale
University Press, Second Edition, 138 p.
ALLIOT Michel, 1983, « Anthropologie et juristique. Sur les conditions de l’élaboration d’une
science du droit », Bulletin de Liaison du Laboratoire d’Anthropologie Juridique de Paris, n°6, p
83–117.
BOURDIEU Pierre 1986, « Habitus, code et codification », Actes de la recherche en sciences
sociales, n°64, p 60-64.
BOURDIEU Pierre, 1980, Le sens pratique, Paris, Les Editions de Minuit, 475 p.
BOURDIEU Pierre, 1977, Outline of a Theory of Practice, Translated by Richard Nice, New York:
Cambridge University Press, 248 p.
BRUCKMEIER Karl, 2005, “Interdisciplinary Conflict Analysis and Conflict Mitigation in Local
Resource Management”, Ambio Vol. 34, No.2, March 2005, p. 65- 73.
COASE Ronald H., 1960, “The Problem of Social Cost”, 3 Journal of Law and Economics p 1-44.
COASE Ronald, 1937, “The Nature of the Firm”, reprinted from Economica, n.s., 4, p 386-405,
(November 1937), in WILLIAMSON Oliver E. and WINTER Sidney G. (Eds.) 1993, The Nature of the
Firm: Origins, Evolution and Development. Oxford University Press, New York, 244 p.
COLEMAN James S., 1964, An Introduction to Mathematical Sociology., New York, Free Press of
Glencoe, a division of the MacMillan Company, 554 p.
DE LOATCH Jovita L., 2009, Enquête corse sur la passion pour le littoral de l’île de beauté: Un
préalable épistémologique entre l’anthropologie juridique et l’analyse économique du droit,
Mémoire de Master de Droit - Mention Droit comparé- Spécialité recherche Anthropologie du
droit, Unitversité de Paris 1 (Panthéon- Sorbonne) Année Universitaire 2008-2009, 103 p.
DE LOATCH Jovita L., 2008, “A Sustainable ‘Middle Way’ to Economic Responsibility in
Environmental Governance : The Case of EC Salmon Aquaculture”, in EBERHARD Christoph (dir.),
Traduire nos responsabilités planétaires. Recomposer nos paysages juridiques, Bruxelles,
Bruylant, Col. Bibliothèque de l’Académie Européenne de Théorie du Droit, 756 p 583- 611.
233
de SOUSA SANTOS Boaventura, 1995, Toward a New Common Sense: Law, Science and Politics
in the Paradigmatic Transition, New York, Routledge, 614 p.
de SOUSA SANTOS Boaventura, 1988, « Une carte de la lecture déformée. Pour une conception
post-moderne du droit », Droit & Société, n° 10, p 363-388.
DYKE Chuck and DYKE Carl, 2002, “Indentities: The Dynamical Dimensions of Diversity”,
Diversity and Community: An Interdisciplinary Reader, Philip Alperson (Ed.), Oxford, Wiley-
Blackwell; First Edition, 351 p.
EBERHARD Christoph, 2011, Le droit au miroir des cultures. Pour une autre mondialisation,
Paris, LGDJ/Lextenso, 2ème edition, 254 p.
EBERHARD Christoph, 2006, « Trois problématiques pour une dynamique d’anthropologie du
Droit », in Le Roy Étienne (dir.), Juridicités, Cahiers d’Anthropologie du Droit, Hors série, Paris,
Karthala, 176 p 59-70.
EBERHARD Christoph (dir.), 2005, Droit, gouvernance et développement durable, numéro spécial
des Cahiers d’Anthropologie du Droit, Paris, Karthala, 376 p.
EBERHARD Christoph, 2001, “Towards an Intercultural Legal Theory: The Dialogical Challenge”,
Social & Legal Studies, Vol. 10(2), p 171–201.
FARBER Daniel A., 2003, “Probabilities Behaving Badly: Complexity Theory and Environmental
Uncertainty”, U.C. Davis Law Review, n° 37, p 145-173.
FRIED Barbara H., 1998, The Progressive Assault on Laissez Faire : Robert Hale and the First
Law and Economics Movement, Cambridge Mass., Harvard University Press, 352 p.
JAFFE Alexandra, 1999, Ideologies in Action: Language Politics in Corsica, (Language, power &
social process), Berlin, Mouton de Gruyter, 323 p.
LANSING Bali, Princeton Studies in Complexity, Princeton, Princeton University Press, 248 p.
LANSING J. Stephen, 2003, “Complex Adaptive Systems”, Annual Review Anthropology, n° 32,
183-204.
LE BRIS Émile, LE ROY Étienne, et MATHIEU Paul, 1991, L’appropriation de la terre en
Afrique noire. Manuel d’analyse, de décision et de gestion foncières, Paris, Karthala, 359 p.
LE ROY Étienne, 1999, Le jeu des lois. Une anthropologie « dynamique » du Droit, Paris, LGDJ,
Col. Droit et Société, Série anthropologique, 415 p.
LIZARDO Omar, 2004, “The Cognitive Origins of Bourdieu’s Habitus”, Journal for the Theory of
Social Behaviour, Volume 34, Issue 4, December 2004, p 375–401.
234
LIU Jianguo, Dietz Thomas, Carpenter Stephen R., Folke Carl, Alberti Marina, Redman Charles L.,
Schneider Stephen H., Ostrom Elinor, Pell Alice N., Lubchenco Jane, Taylor William W., Ouyang
Zhiyun, Deadman Peter, Kratz Timothy, and Provencher William, 2007, “The development of
Coupled Human and Natural Systems”, AMBIO: A Journal of the Human Environment, N°36 (8),
p 639-649.
MANDELBROT Benoit B., 1977, The Fractal Geometry of Nature. New York, Freeman, 480 p.
MANDELBROT Benoit B. and HUDSON Richard L., 2004, The (Mis)behavior of Markets: A
Fractal View of Risk, Ruin, and Reward, New York, Basic Books, 328 p.
MAUSS Marcel, 1934, « Les techniques du corps » Article originalement publié Journal de
Psychologie, XXXII, ne, 3-4, 15 mars - 15 avril 1936. Communication présentée à la Société de
Psychologie le 17 mai 1934, 23 p.
MÉNARD Claude and SHIRLEY Mary M. (eds.), 2005, Handbook of New Institutional
Economics, The Netherlands, Springer, AA Dordrecht, , 884 p.
MÉNARD Claude, 2000, “Ronald H. Coase and the emergence of a new approach to economics” in
MÉNARD Claude (ed.), 2000, Institutions, Contracts and Organizations: Perspectives from New
Institutional Economics, New York, Edward Elgar Publishing, p. 54-58.
MILLER John H., PAGES Scott E., 2007, Complex Adaptive Systems: An Introduction to
Computational Models of Social Life (Princeton Studies in Complexity), Princeton, Princeton
University Press, p 284.
MOORE Sally Falk, 2006, « The Sociologic of Land Law”, in EBERHARD Christoph et VERNICOS
Geneviève (Éds.), La quête anthropologique du droit. Autour de la démarche d'Étienne Le Roy,
Paris, Karthala, p 133-145.
MOORE Sally Falk, 1978, Law As Process: An Anthropological Approach, London Boston,
Routledge & K. Paul, 270 p.
OST François and van de KERCHOVE Michel (2002) De la pyramide au réseau? Pour une théorie
dialectique du droit, Bruxelles, Publications des Facultés universitaires Saint Louis, 596 p.
OSTROM Elinor, 2005a, Doing Institutional Analysis, in MÉNARD Claude and SHIRLEY Mary
M. (eds.), 2005, Handbook of New Institutional Economics, Netherlands, Springer, AA Dordrecht,
884 p.
OSTROM Elinor, 2005b, Understanding Institutional Diversity, Princeton, Princeton University
Press, 355 p.
235
OSTROM Elinor, and WALKER James, 2003, Trust & Reciprocity, Interdisciplinary Lessons from
Experimental Research, New York, Russell Sage Foundation, 409 p.
POLINSKY A. Mitchell, 1974, Economic Analysis as a Potentially Defective Product: A Buyer’s
Guide to Posner’s Economic Analysis of Law, 87 Harvard Law Review, p 1655-81.
ROCHEGUDE Alain, 2006, « Le Foncier, une préoccupation constante, un champ d’expertise
reconnue », Le Roy Étienne (dir.), Juridicités, Cahiers d’Anthropologie du Droit, Hors série,
Karthala, 176 p (87).
ROCHEGUDE Alain, 2005, « Le ‘droit d’agir’, une proposition pour la ‘bonne gouvernance
foncière », EBERHARD Christoph (éd.), 2005, Droit, gouvernance et développement durable, numéro
spécial des Cahiers d’Anthropologie du Droit, Paris, Karthala, 376 p (59-72).
RUHL J.B., 1997, “Thinking of Environmental Law as a Complex Adaptive System: How to Clean
Up the Environment by Making a Mess of Environmental Law”, 34 Houston Law Review, p 933-
1002.
RUFFINO Julio, 2005, "Disputing over Livestock in Sardinia", Law and Anthropology: a Reader,
Sally Falk Moore (Ed.), 2005, 384 p (135-153).
SAPOLSKY Robert, 2005, Biology and Human Behavior: The Neurological Origins of
Individuality, 2nd
Edition, Course No. 1597, Chantilly, The Teaching Company, 412 p (267-281).
SVENSDEN Gunnar Lind Haase et SVENDSEN Gert Tinggaard, 2003, « On the wealth of nations :
Bourdieuconomics and social capital », Theory and Society 32 : p 607-631.
TEUBNER Günther, 1993, Law as an Autopoietic System, (Anne Bankowska & Ruth Adler trans.),
Zenon Bankowski (ed.), European University Institute Press series, Blackwell Publishers, Oxford,
Cambridge, USA, Blackwell, 203 p.
WERIN Lars, 2000, “Ronald Coase and the New Microeconomics”, in Claude MENARD (ed.),
Institutions, Contracts and Organizations: Perspectives from New Institutional Economics, Edward
Elgar Publishing (Northhampton), p 42-47.
Imperfect Alternatives and the Invisible Elephant: The Complex Nature of Environmental Governance

More Related Content

What's hot

Interrelation between Cross-Border Cooperation (CBC) and Social Capital: Conc...
Interrelation between Cross-Border Cooperation (CBC) and Social Capital: Conc...Interrelation between Cross-Border Cooperation (CBC) and Social Capital: Conc...
Interrelation between Cross-Border Cooperation (CBC) and Social Capital: Conc...Środkowoeuropejskie Studia Polityczne
 
Identity, Integration and Estonia
Identity, Integration and EstoniaIdentity, Integration and Estonia
Identity, Integration and Estoniamisakonverents
 
Power&difference 2012
Power&difference 2012Power&difference 2012
Power&difference 2012Markus Ojala
 
Pragmatism and institutionalism
Pragmatism and institutionalismPragmatism and institutionalism
Pragmatism and institutionalismHek de Hektor
 
Revival of spirit formation of freedom; solidarity economy development pers...
Revival of spirit   formation of freedom; solidarity economy development pers...Revival of spirit   formation of freedom; solidarity economy development pers...
Revival of spirit formation of freedom; solidarity economy development pers...Barka Foundation
 
Integration of migrants contribution of local and regional authorities
Integration of migrants contribution of local and regional authoritiesIntegration of migrants contribution of local and regional authorities
Integration of migrants contribution of local and regional authoritiesIntegraLocal
 
11.pp.0199www.iiste.org call for paper-216
11.pp.0199www.iiste.org call for paper-21611.pp.0199www.iiste.org call for paper-216
11.pp.0199www.iiste.org call for paper-216Alexander Decker
 
To Bit Or Not To Bit
To Bit Or Not To BitTo Bit Or Not To Bit
To Bit Or Not To Bitjennywallace
 
Sociology of Max Weber
Sociology of Max WeberSociology of Max Weber
Sociology of Max WeberSheikh Ahmed
 
The rational choice theory
The rational choice theoryThe rational choice theory
The rational choice theoryClark Cayran
 
Mini-research: Pierre BOURDIEU’S THEORIES in relation to organizational behav...
Mini-research: Pierre BOURDIEU’S THEORIES in relation to organizational behav...Mini-research: Pierre BOURDIEU’S THEORIES in relation to organizational behav...
Mini-research: Pierre BOURDIEU’S THEORIES in relation to organizational behav...Fernanda Vasconcelos Dias
 
Exploratory theory network_society_castells
Exploratory theory network_society_castellsExploratory theory network_society_castells
Exploratory theory network_society_castellsJulim Coelho
 

What's hot (18)

Interrelation between Cross-Border Cooperation (CBC) and Social Capital: Conc...
Interrelation between Cross-Border Cooperation (CBC) and Social Capital: Conc...Interrelation between Cross-Border Cooperation (CBC) and Social Capital: Conc...
Interrelation between Cross-Border Cooperation (CBC) and Social Capital: Conc...
 
Identity, Integration and Estonia
Identity, Integration and EstoniaIdentity, Integration and Estonia
Identity, Integration and Estonia
 
Power&difference 2012
Power&difference 2012Power&difference 2012
Power&difference 2012
 
Article Community
Article CommunityArticle Community
Article Community
 
Pragmatism and institutionalism
Pragmatism and institutionalismPragmatism and institutionalism
Pragmatism and institutionalism
 
Revival of spirit formation of freedom; solidarity economy development pers...
Revival of spirit   formation of freedom; solidarity economy development pers...Revival of spirit   formation of freedom; solidarity economy development pers...
Revival of spirit formation of freedom; solidarity economy development pers...
 
Integration of migrants contribution of local and regional authorities
Integration of migrants contribution of local and regional authoritiesIntegration of migrants contribution of local and regional authorities
Integration of migrants contribution of local and regional authorities
 
Max Weber
Max WeberMax Weber
Max Weber
 
11.pp.0199www.iiste.org call for paper-216
11.pp.0199www.iiste.org call for paper-21611.pp.0199www.iiste.org call for paper-216
11.pp.0199www.iiste.org call for paper-216
 
021
021021
021
 
To Bit Or Not To Bit
To Bit Or Not To BitTo Bit Or Not To Bit
To Bit Or Not To Bit
 
Sociology of Max Weber
Sociology of Max WeberSociology of Max Weber
Sociology of Max Weber
 
The rational choice theory
The rational choice theoryThe rational choice theory
The rational choice theory
 
Mini-research: Pierre BOURDIEU’S THEORIES in relation to organizational behav...
Mini-research: Pierre BOURDIEU’S THEORIES in relation to organizational behav...Mini-research: Pierre BOURDIEU’S THEORIES in relation to organizational behav...
Mini-research: Pierre BOURDIEU’S THEORIES in relation to organizational behav...
 
Where to be?
Where to be?Where to be?
Where to be?
 
Bourdieu
BourdieuBourdieu
Bourdieu
 
Jle 2010 Week 2
Jle 2010 Week 2Jle 2010 Week 2
Jle 2010 Week 2
 
Exploratory theory network_society_castells
Exploratory theory network_society_castellsExploratory theory network_society_castells
Exploratory theory network_society_castells
 

Viewers also liked

Barclays ESG_Brochure_US_18_small Sustainable Investing and bond returns NOV ...
Barclays ESG_Brochure_US_18_small Sustainable Investing and bond returns NOV ...Barclays ESG_Brochure_US_18_small Sustainable Investing and bond returns NOV ...
Barclays ESG_Brochure_US_18_small Sustainable Investing and bond returns NOV ...Andrew Bellak
 
Certified islamic-fintech-professional.pdf
Certified islamic-fintech-professional.pdfCertified islamic-fintech-professional.pdf
Certified islamic-fintech-professional.pdfShahzad Arshad
 
Entrepreneurship fintech & islamic finance v1.4
Entrepreneurship   fintech & islamic finance v1.4Entrepreneurship   fintech & islamic finance v1.4
Entrepreneurship fintech & islamic finance v1.4Jamal Nassar
 
ISLAMIC BANKING AND FINANCE: MALAYSIA’S EXPERIENCE AND ACHIEVEMENTS
ISLAMIC BANKING AND FINANCE: MALAYSIA’S EXPERIENCE AND ACHIEVEMENTSISLAMIC BANKING AND FINANCE: MALAYSIA’S EXPERIENCE AND ACHIEVEMENTS
ISLAMIC BANKING AND FINANCE: MALAYSIA’S EXPERIENCE AND ACHIEVEMENTSbrighteyes
 
Development of the Malaysian Islamic Financial System
Development of the Malaysian Islamic Financial SystemDevelopment of the Malaysian Islamic Financial System
Development of the Malaysian Islamic Financial SystemMahyuddin Khalid
 
Tracxn FinTech SEA Startup Landscape, July 2016
Tracxn FinTech SEA Startup Landscape, July 2016Tracxn FinTech SEA Startup Landscape, July 2016
Tracxn FinTech SEA Startup Landscape, July 2016Tracxn
 
Islamic financial
Islamic financialIslamic financial
Islamic financialFarah Najwa
 
Thailand Fintech landscape 2016 special report by techsauce
Thailand Fintech landscape 2016 special report by techsauce Thailand Fintech landscape 2016 special report by techsauce
Thailand Fintech landscape 2016 special report by techsauce Techsauce Media
 
Bank: Trends, Tech and Future
Bank: Trends, Tech and FutureBank: Trends, Tech and Future
Bank: Trends, Tech and FutureIvano Digital
 
MERGER AND ACQUISITION OF BANKS
MERGER AND ACQUISITION OF BANKS MERGER AND ACQUISITION OF BANKS
MERGER AND ACQUISITION OF BANKS Sardaar Saab
 
Fintech and Transformation of the Financial Services Industry
Fintech and Transformation of the Financial Services IndustryFintech and Transformation of the Financial Services Industry
Fintech and Transformation of the Financial Services IndustryRobin Teigland
 

Viewers also liked (16)

Barclays ESG_Brochure_US_18_small Sustainable Investing and bond returns NOV ...
Barclays ESG_Brochure_US_18_small Sustainable Investing and bond returns NOV ...Barclays ESG_Brochure_US_18_small Sustainable Investing and bond returns NOV ...
Barclays ESG_Brochure_US_18_small Sustainable Investing and bond returns NOV ...
 
final thesis for submission
final thesis for submissionfinal thesis for submission
final thesis for submission
 
Alhuda CIBE - The State of Islamic Capital Markets and Future Prospects
Alhuda CIBE - The State of Islamic Capital Markets and Future ProspectsAlhuda CIBE - The State of Islamic Capital Markets and Future Prospects
Alhuda CIBE - The State of Islamic Capital Markets and Future Prospects
 
Certified islamic-fintech-professional.pdf
Certified islamic-fintech-professional.pdfCertified islamic-fintech-professional.pdf
Certified islamic-fintech-professional.pdf
 
Key Debates in Environmental Governance
Key Debates in Environmental GovernanceKey Debates in Environmental Governance
Key Debates in Environmental Governance
 
Entrepreneurship fintech & islamic finance v1.4
Entrepreneurship   fintech & islamic finance v1.4Entrepreneurship   fintech & islamic finance v1.4
Entrepreneurship fintech & islamic finance v1.4
 
Islamic Finance
Islamic FinanceIslamic Finance
Islamic Finance
 
Fintech in Asia
Fintech in AsiaFintech in Asia
Fintech in Asia
 
ISLAMIC BANKING AND FINANCE: MALAYSIA’S EXPERIENCE AND ACHIEVEMENTS
ISLAMIC BANKING AND FINANCE: MALAYSIA’S EXPERIENCE AND ACHIEVEMENTSISLAMIC BANKING AND FINANCE: MALAYSIA’S EXPERIENCE AND ACHIEVEMENTS
ISLAMIC BANKING AND FINANCE: MALAYSIA’S EXPERIENCE AND ACHIEVEMENTS
 
Development of the Malaysian Islamic Financial System
Development of the Malaysian Islamic Financial SystemDevelopment of the Malaysian Islamic Financial System
Development of the Malaysian Islamic Financial System
 
Tracxn FinTech SEA Startup Landscape, July 2016
Tracxn FinTech SEA Startup Landscape, July 2016Tracxn FinTech SEA Startup Landscape, July 2016
Tracxn FinTech SEA Startup Landscape, July 2016
 
Islamic financial
Islamic financialIslamic financial
Islamic financial
 
Thailand Fintech landscape 2016 special report by techsauce
Thailand Fintech landscape 2016 special report by techsauce Thailand Fintech landscape 2016 special report by techsauce
Thailand Fintech landscape 2016 special report by techsauce
 
Bank: Trends, Tech and Future
Bank: Trends, Tech and FutureBank: Trends, Tech and Future
Bank: Trends, Tech and Future
 
MERGER AND ACQUISITION OF BANKS
MERGER AND ACQUISITION OF BANKS MERGER AND ACQUISITION OF BANKS
MERGER AND ACQUISITION OF BANKS
 
Fintech and Transformation of the Financial Services Industry
Fintech and Transformation of the Financial Services IndustryFintech and Transformation of the Financial Services Industry
Fintech and Transformation of the Financial Services Industry
 

Similar to Imperfect Alternatives and the Invisible Elephant: The Complex Nature of Environmental Governance

Article: Rousseau, Rio, and the Green Economy - 2015
Article: Rousseau, Rio, and the Green Economy - 2015Article: Rousseau, Rio, and the Green Economy - 2015
Article: Rousseau, Rio, and the Green Economy - 2015Africa Cheetah Run
 
The Evolution of Functionalism,Positivism and Sociology
The Evolution of Functionalism,Positivism and SociologyThe Evolution of Functionalism,Positivism and Sociology
The Evolution of Functionalism,Positivism and SociologyNudrat Saleem
 
Studying History And Culture
Studying History And CultureStudying History And Culture
Studying History And CulturePeter Cullen
 
What is just and moral in international politics
What is just and moral in international politicsWhat is just and moral in international politics
What is just and moral in international politicsDaria Globenko
 
13Chapter 7 SummaryCHAPTER SUMMARYContemporary Integ.docx
13Chapter 7 SummaryCHAPTER SUMMARYContemporary Integ.docx13Chapter 7 SummaryCHAPTER SUMMARYContemporary Integ.docx
13Chapter 7 SummaryCHAPTER SUMMARYContemporary Integ.docxdrennanmicah
 
Understanding the concepts of culture, society and politics
Understanding the concepts of culture, society and politicsUnderstanding the concepts of culture, society and politics
Understanding the concepts of culture, society and politicsMaryjoydailo
 
Understanding the concepts of culture, society and politics
Understanding the concepts of culture, society and politicsUnderstanding the concepts of culture, society and politics
Understanding the concepts of culture, society and politicsMaryjoydailo
 
11.pp.0199www.iiste.org call for paper-216
11.pp.0199www.iiste.org call for paper-21611.pp.0199www.iiste.org call for paper-216
11.pp.0199www.iiste.org call for paper-216Alexander Decker
 
Outlines on environmental philosophy part 6
Outlines on environmental philosophy   part 6Outlines on environmental philosophy   part 6
Outlines on environmental philosophy part 6Steven Ghezzo
 
The Importance Of Historical Knowledge In Business
The Importance Of Historical Knowledge In BusinessThe Importance Of Historical Knowledge In Business
The Importance Of Historical Knowledge In BusinessPeter Cullen
 
Chapter 15 chapter summary
Chapter 15 chapter summaryChapter 15 chapter summary
Chapter 15 chapter summarydaleshine
 
The Unesco Universal Ethics Project
The Unesco Universal Ethics ProjectThe Unesco Universal Ethics Project
The Unesco Universal Ethics ProjectViryadhika Desfrian
 
The Socio Cultural Evolution Of Our Species Copia
The Socio Cultural Evolution Of Our Species CopiaThe Socio Cultural Evolution Of Our Species Copia
The Socio Cultural Evolution Of Our Species CopiaTony Valderrama
 
Blockchain Narrative Ontologies
Blockchain Narrative OntologiesBlockchain Narrative Ontologies
Blockchain Narrative OntologiesNicolae Sfetcu
 
Key Concepts! Anomie! Social facts! Social solidarity.docx
Key Concepts! Anomie! Social facts! Social solidarity.docxKey Concepts! Anomie! Social facts! Social solidarity.docx
Key Concepts! Anomie! Social facts! Social solidarity.docxDIPESH30
 
Prof. Janet Blake (Shahid Beheshti University, Iran) - Cultural heritage as a...
Prof. Janet Blake (Shahid Beheshti University, Iran) - Cultural heritage as a...Prof. Janet Blake (Shahid Beheshti University, Iran) - Cultural heritage as a...
Prof. Janet Blake (Shahid Beheshti University, Iran) - Cultural heritage as a...Crew Project
 
How to think of ‘socialreality’SOSC 1
How to think of ‘socialreality’SOSC 1How to think of ‘socialreality’SOSC 1
How to think of ‘socialreality’SOSC 1PazSilviapm
 

Similar to Imperfect Alternatives and the Invisible Elephant: The Complex Nature of Environmental Governance (20)

Article: Rousseau, Rio, and the Green Economy - 2015
Article: Rousseau, Rio, and the Green Economy - 2015Article: Rousseau, Rio, and the Green Economy - 2015
Article: Rousseau, Rio, and the Green Economy - 2015
 
The Evolution of Functionalism,Positivism and Sociology
The Evolution of Functionalism,Positivism and SociologyThe Evolution of Functionalism,Positivism and Sociology
The Evolution of Functionalism,Positivism and Sociology
 
Studying History And Culture
Studying History And CultureStudying History And Culture
Studying History And Culture
 
What is just and moral in international politics
What is just and moral in international politicsWhat is just and moral in international politics
What is just and moral in international politics
 
13Chapter 7 SummaryCHAPTER SUMMARYContemporary Integ.docx
13Chapter 7 SummaryCHAPTER SUMMARYContemporary Integ.docx13Chapter 7 SummaryCHAPTER SUMMARYContemporary Integ.docx
13Chapter 7 SummaryCHAPTER SUMMARYContemporary Integ.docx
 
Understanding the concepts of culture, society and politics
Understanding the concepts of culture, society and politicsUnderstanding the concepts of culture, society and politics
Understanding the concepts of culture, society and politics
 
CAG Contactdag 2017: Workshop ICE en ethiek
CAG Contactdag 2017: Workshop ICE en ethiekCAG Contactdag 2017: Workshop ICE en ethiek
CAG Contactdag 2017: Workshop ICE en ethiek
 
Understanding the concepts of culture, society and politics
Understanding the concepts of culture, society and politicsUnderstanding the concepts of culture, society and politics
Understanding the concepts of culture, society and politics
 
11.pp.0199www.iiste.org call for paper-216
11.pp.0199www.iiste.org call for paper-21611.pp.0199www.iiste.org call for paper-216
11.pp.0199www.iiste.org call for paper-216
 
Outlines on environmental philosophy part 6
Outlines on environmental philosophy   part 6Outlines on environmental philosophy   part 6
Outlines on environmental philosophy part 6
 
The Importance Of Historical Knowledge In Business
The Importance Of Historical Knowledge In BusinessThe Importance Of Historical Knowledge In Business
The Importance Of Historical Knowledge In Business
 
Chapter 15 chapter summary
Chapter 15 chapter summaryChapter 15 chapter summary
Chapter 15 chapter summary
 
ethics.2
ethics.2ethics.2
ethics.2
 
The Unesco Universal Ethics Project
The Unesco Universal Ethics ProjectThe Unesco Universal Ethics Project
The Unesco Universal Ethics Project
 
The Socio Cultural Evolution Of Our Species Copia
The Socio Cultural Evolution Of Our Species CopiaThe Socio Cultural Evolution Of Our Species Copia
The Socio Cultural Evolution Of Our Species Copia
 
Blockchain Narrative Ontologies
Blockchain Narrative OntologiesBlockchain Narrative Ontologies
Blockchain Narrative Ontologies
 
Comparing legal cultures - student copy, by Joxerramon Bengoetxea
Comparing legal cultures - student copy, by Joxerramon BengoetxeaComparing legal cultures - student copy, by Joxerramon Bengoetxea
Comparing legal cultures - student copy, by Joxerramon Bengoetxea
 
Key Concepts! Anomie! Social facts! Social solidarity.docx
Key Concepts! Anomie! Social facts! Social solidarity.docxKey Concepts! Anomie! Social facts! Social solidarity.docx
Key Concepts! Anomie! Social facts! Social solidarity.docx
 
Prof. Janet Blake (Shahid Beheshti University, Iran) - Cultural heritage as a...
Prof. Janet Blake (Shahid Beheshti University, Iran) - Cultural heritage as a...Prof. Janet Blake (Shahid Beheshti University, Iran) - Cultural heritage as a...
Prof. Janet Blake (Shahid Beheshti University, Iran) - Cultural heritage as a...
 
How to think of ‘socialreality’SOSC 1
How to think of ‘socialreality’SOSC 1How to think of ‘socialreality’SOSC 1
How to think of ‘socialreality’SOSC 1
 

Recently uploaded

Visit to a blind student's school🧑‍🦯🧑‍🦯(community medicine)
Visit to a blind student's school🧑‍🦯🧑‍🦯(community medicine)Visit to a blind student's school🧑‍🦯🧑‍🦯(community medicine)
Visit to a blind student's school🧑‍🦯🧑‍🦯(community medicine)lakshayb543
 
FILIPINO PSYCHology sikolohiyang pilipino
FILIPINO PSYCHology sikolohiyang pilipinoFILIPINO PSYCHology sikolohiyang pilipino
FILIPINO PSYCHology sikolohiyang pilipinojohnmickonozaleda
 
USPS® Forced Meter Migration - How to Know if Your Postage Meter Will Soon be...
USPS® Forced Meter Migration - How to Know if Your Postage Meter Will Soon be...USPS® Forced Meter Migration - How to Know if Your Postage Meter Will Soon be...
USPS® Forced Meter Migration - How to Know if Your Postage Meter Will Soon be...Postal Advocate Inc.
 
4.16.24 21st Century Movements for Black Lives.pptx
4.16.24 21st Century Movements for Black Lives.pptx4.16.24 21st Century Movements for Black Lives.pptx
4.16.24 21st Century Movements for Black Lives.pptxmary850239
 
How to Add Barcode on PDF Report in Odoo 17
How to Add Barcode on PDF Report in Odoo 17How to Add Barcode on PDF Report in Odoo 17
How to Add Barcode on PDF Report in Odoo 17Celine George
 
Keynote by Prof. Wurzer at Nordex about IP-design
Keynote by Prof. Wurzer at Nordex about IP-designKeynote by Prof. Wurzer at Nordex about IP-design
Keynote by Prof. Wurzer at Nordex about IP-designMIPLM
 
Student Profile Sample - We help schools to connect the data they have, with ...
Student Profile Sample - We help schools to connect the data they have, with ...Student Profile Sample - We help schools to connect the data they have, with ...
Student Profile Sample - We help schools to connect the data they have, with ...Seán Kennedy
 
INTRODUCTION TO CATHOLIC CHRISTOLOGY.pptx
INTRODUCTION TO CATHOLIC CHRISTOLOGY.pptxINTRODUCTION TO CATHOLIC CHRISTOLOGY.pptx
INTRODUCTION TO CATHOLIC CHRISTOLOGY.pptxHumphrey A Beña
 
Grade 9 Quarter 4 Dll Grade 9 Quarter 4 DLL.pdf
Grade 9 Quarter 4 Dll Grade 9 Quarter 4 DLL.pdfGrade 9 Quarter 4 Dll Grade 9 Quarter 4 DLL.pdf
Grade 9 Quarter 4 Dll Grade 9 Quarter 4 DLL.pdfJemuel Francisco
 
GRADE 4 - SUMMATIVE TEST QUARTER 4 ALL SUBJECTS
GRADE 4 - SUMMATIVE TEST QUARTER 4 ALL SUBJECTSGRADE 4 - SUMMATIVE TEST QUARTER 4 ALL SUBJECTS
GRADE 4 - SUMMATIVE TEST QUARTER 4 ALL SUBJECTSJoshuaGantuangco2
 
HỌC TỐT TIẾNG ANH 11 THEO CHƯƠNG TRÌNH GLOBAL SUCCESS ĐÁP ÁN CHI TIẾT - CẢ NĂ...
HỌC TỐT TIẾNG ANH 11 THEO CHƯƠNG TRÌNH GLOBAL SUCCESS ĐÁP ÁN CHI TIẾT - CẢ NĂ...HỌC TỐT TIẾNG ANH 11 THEO CHƯƠNG TRÌNH GLOBAL SUCCESS ĐÁP ÁN CHI TIẾT - CẢ NĂ...
HỌC TỐT TIẾNG ANH 11 THEO CHƯƠNG TRÌNH GLOBAL SUCCESS ĐÁP ÁN CHI TIẾT - CẢ NĂ...Nguyen Thanh Tu Collection
 
MULTIDISCIPLINRY NATURE OF THE ENVIRONMENTAL STUDIES.pptx
MULTIDISCIPLINRY NATURE OF THE ENVIRONMENTAL STUDIES.pptxMULTIDISCIPLINRY NATURE OF THE ENVIRONMENTAL STUDIES.pptx
MULTIDISCIPLINRY NATURE OF THE ENVIRONMENTAL STUDIES.pptxAnupkumar Sharma
 
4.18.24 Movement Legacies, Reflection, and Review.pptx
4.18.24 Movement Legacies, Reflection, and Review.pptx4.18.24 Movement Legacies, Reflection, and Review.pptx
4.18.24 Movement Legacies, Reflection, and Review.pptxmary850239
 
Transaction Management in Database Management System
Transaction Management in Database Management SystemTransaction Management in Database Management System
Transaction Management in Database Management SystemChristalin Nelson
 
Karra SKD Conference Presentation Revised.pptx
Karra SKD Conference Presentation Revised.pptxKarra SKD Conference Presentation Revised.pptx
Karra SKD Conference Presentation Revised.pptxAshokKarra1
 
Procuring digital preservation CAN be quick and painless with our new dynamic...
Procuring digital preservation CAN be quick and painless with our new dynamic...Procuring digital preservation CAN be quick and painless with our new dynamic...
Procuring digital preservation CAN be quick and painless with our new dynamic...Jisc
 

Recently uploaded (20)

Visit to a blind student's school🧑‍🦯🧑‍🦯(community medicine)
Visit to a blind student's school🧑‍🦯🧑‍🦯(community medicine)Visit to a blind student's school🧑‍🦯🧑‍🦯(community medicine)
Visit to a blind student's school🧑‍🦯🧑‍🦯(community medicine)
 
YOUVE GOT EMAIL_FINALS_EL_DORADO_2024.pptx
YOUVE GOT EMAIL_FINALS_EL_DORADO_2024.pptxYOUVE GOT EMAIL_FINALS_EL_DORADO_2024.pptx
YOUVE GOT EMAIL_FINALS_EL_DORADO_2024.pptx
 
FILIPINO PSYCHology sikolohiyang pilipino
FILIPINO PSYCHology sikolohiyang pilipinoFILIPINO PSYCHology sikolohiyang pilipino
FILIPINO PSYCHology sikolohiyang pilipino
 
Raw materials used in Herbal Cosmetics.pptx
Raw materials used in Herbal Cosmetics.pptxRaw materials used in Herbal Cosmetics.pptx
Raw materials used in Herbal Cosmetics.pptx
 
FINALS_OF_LEFT_ON_C'N_EL_DORADO_2024.pptx
FINALS_OF_LEFT_ON_C'N_EL_DORADO_2024.pptxFINALS_OF_LEFT_ON_C'N_EL_DORADO_2024.pptx
FINALS_OF_LEFT_ON_C'N_EL_DORADO_2024.pptx
 
USPS® Forced Meter Migration - How to Know if Your Postage Meter Will Soon be...
USPS® Forced Meter Migration - How to Know if Your Postage Meter Will Soon be...USPS® Forced Meter Migration - How to Know if Your Postage Meter Will Soon be...
USPS® Forced Meter Migration - How to Know if Your Postage Meter Will Soon be...
 
4.16.24 21st Century Movements for Black Lives.pptx
4.16.24 21st Century Movements for Black Lives.pptx4.16.24 21st Century Movements for Black Lives.pptx
4.16.24 21st Century Movements for Black Lives.pptx
 
How to Add Barcode on PDF Report in Odoo 17
How to Add Barcode on PDF Report in Odoo 17How to Add Barcode on PDF Report in Odoo 17
How to Add Barcode on PDF Report in Odoo 17
 
Keynote by Prof. Wurzer at Nordex about IP-design
Keynote by Prof. Wurzer at Nordex about IP-designKeynote by Prof. Wurzer at Nordex about IP-design
Keynote by Prof. Wurzer at Nordex about IP-design
 
Student Profile Sample - We help schools to connect the data they have, with ...
Student Profile Sample - We help schools to connect the data they have, with ...Student Profile Sample - We help schools to connect the data they have, with ...
Student Profile Sample - We help schools to connect the data they have, with ...
 
INTRODUCTION TO CATHOLIC CHRISTOLOGY.pptx
INTRODUCTION TO CATHOLIC CHRISTOLOGY.pptxINTRODUCTION TO CATHOLIC CHRISTOLOGY.pptx
INTRODUCTION TO CATHOLIC CHRISTOLOGY.pptx
 
Grade 9 Quarter 4 Dll Grade 9 Quarter 4 DLL.pdf
Grade 9 Quarter 4 Dll Grade 9 Quarter 4 DLL.pdfGrade 9 Quarter 4 Dll Grade 9 Quarter 4 DLL.pdf
Grade 9 Quarter 4 Dll Grade 9 Quarter 4 DLL.pdf
 
GRADE 4 - SUMMATIVE TEST QUARTER 4 ALL SUBJECTS
GRADE 4 - SUMMATIVE TEST QUARTER 4 ALL SUBJECTSGRADE 4 - SUMMATIVE TEST QUARTER 4 ALL SUBJECTS
GRADE 4 - SUMMATIVE TEST QUARTER 4 ALL SUBJECTS
 
HỌC TỐT TIẾNG ANH 11 THEO CHƯƠNG TRÌNH GLOBAL SUCCESS ĐÁP ÁN CHI TIẾT - CẢ NĂ...
HỌC TỐT TIẾNG ANH 11 THEO CHƯƠNG TRÌNH GLOBAL SUCCESS ĐÁP ÁN CHI TIẾT - CẢ NĂ...HỌC TỐT TIẾNG ANH 11 THEO CHƯƠNG TRÌNH GLOBAL SUCCESS ĐÁP ÁN CHI TIẾT - CẢ NĂ...
HỌC TỐT TIẾNG ANH 11 THEO CHƯƠNG TRÌNH GLOBAL SUCCESS ĐÁP ÁN CHI TIẾT - CẢ NĂ...
 
MULTIDISCIPLINRY NATURE OF THE ENVIRONMENTAL STUDIES.pptx
MULTIDISCIPLINRY NATURE OF THE ENVIRONMENTAL STUDIES.pptxMULTIDISCIPLINRY NATURE OF THE ENVIRONMENTAL STUDIES.pptx
MULTIDISCIPLINRY NATURE OF THE ENVIRONMENTAL STUDIES.pptx
 
4.18.24 Movement Legacies, Reflection, and Review.pptx
4.18.24 Movement Legacies, Reflection, and Review.pptx4.18.24 Movement Legacies, Reflection, and Review.pptx
4.18.24 Movement Legacies, Reflection, and Review.pptx
 
Model Call Girl in Tilak Nagar Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝
Model Call Girl in Tilak Nagar Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝Model Call Girl in Tilak Nagar Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝
Model Call Girl in Tilak Nagar Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝
 
Transaction Management in Database Management System
Transaction Management in Database Management SystemTransaction Management in Database Management System
Transaction Management in Database Management System
 
Karra SKD Conference Presentation Revised.pptx
Karra SKD Conference Presentation Revised.pptxKarra SKD Conference Presentation Revised.pptx
Karra SKD Conference Presentation Revised.pptx
 
Procuring digital preservation CAN be quick and painless with our new dynamic...
Procuring digital preservation CAN be quick and painless with our new dynamic...Procuring digital preservation CAN be quick and painless with our new dynamic...
Procuring digital preservation CAN be quick and painless with our new dynamic...
 

Imperfect Alternatives and the Invisible Elephant: The Complex Nature of Environmental Governance

  • 1. Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2153128Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2153128 220 Imperfect Alternatives and the Invisible Elephant: The Complex Nature of Environmental Governance Jovita L. De Loatch Environmental governance decisions, like other public policies, are often based upon the assumption that having the ‘correct’ legal principles is the key to describing and prescribing the law. Yet, one of the most inescapable and persistent issues in law is its very concept.99 Western civil law and common law scholars have sought to understand where, how and in what form100 law emerges. How do normative orders form legal orders, or juridicities? Moreover, law is not only founded on legal principles but also set within a wider social, economic, cultural as well as environmental context. As interdisciplinary approaches to the study of law expand, disciplines such as the sociology of law and legal anthropology have exposed how dogmatic principles can often be incongruent with the legal reality or law in practice.101 Instead alternative normative orders seem to emerge, each being complex and imperfect. By contrast, the economic analysis of law generally has sought to view normative behavior through the narrower lens of market exchange in which an ‘invisible hand’ simply guides ‘rational’ agents to the optimal solution.102 In recent years much has been learned from nonlinear dynamics and complex adaptive systems about how complex and imperfect [normative] behaviors can emerge from simple rules (Miller and Page 2007). The approach taken here unites these seemingly contradictory perspectives in order to portray the emergence of self-organizing governance alternatives. The article proposes a means to structure a multi-disciplinary analysis of Corsican governance to better understand the underlining decision-making process and frame the corresponding forces that form legal orders. 99 See classic works such as Max Weber’s 1922 Economy and Society and Émile Durkheim’s 1895 The Rules of Sociological Method, as well as the seminal 1961 The Concept of Law by L. H. A. Hart placing law into a social context among others. 100 Pierre Bourdieu defined the process ”[t]o codify (the law), it is simultaneously to formulate and to formalize. There is an inherent virtue of the form (created), and cultural control is always a master of the forms.” (Bourdieu 1993 : 60). All translations from the original versions of non-Enllish texts have been made by the author. 101 See Moore 1978, Ost and van de Kerchove 2002 and supra at note 1. 102 For the historical context and critique of commonly applied neoclassical law and economic models promoted in neo- liberal politics see Fried 1998 and Pollinsky 1974.
  • 2. Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2153128Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2153128 221 1) Constructing Fields of Juridicity The challenges posed by complex legal phenomena including discovering how a process of informal governance that is rooted in local, communal, extra-territorial or even global interactions, can evolve largely autonomous from state doctrine, the juridicity of which may be affirmed on the simple basis of the ‘acceptance’ by a group or community. Étienne Le Roy asserts that juridicity comprises: 1) general and impersonal norms, 2) models of proper behavior and 3) as introduced by Bourdieu, systems of durable dispositions (Le Roy 1999: 201-202).103 By creating a complex adaptive framework of Le Roy’s paradigm, quantitative and qualitative social science methods will mutually benefit from the closer integration of cultural observations and learned hypotheses on the emergence of legal orders. It can serve to “…compress the social, economic, political, and juridical elements together with the levels international, national, and local, in a single…” (Moore 2006: 134) not simply symbolic formula, but as a scaffold for a practicable quantifiable adaptive framework that may be replicated and tested. In an adaptive framework of this paradigm, general and impersonal norms can be expressed in terms of individual efficiency assessments compared to socially efficient assessment of the community where models of proper behavior seek to align the individual with the social incentives of the community through pressures exerted by the relevant and enduring community institutions.104 Bourdieu defined the concept of habitus as “…systems of durable, transposable dispositions, structured structures predisposed to function as structuring structures, that is, as principles of the generation and structuring of practices and representations… without presupposing a conscious aiming… being all this, collectively orchestrated without being the product of … a conductor.” (Bourdieu 1977: 72). Habitus is itself a generative dynamic structure that adapts and accommodates itself to other dynamic structures and sub-structures composed primarily of other actors, situated practices and durable institutions (fields) (Lizardo 2004: 375–401). In the same manner, Le Roy underlines, “… the field of ‘juridicity’ of ‘habitus’ is not predetermined. It lives, ebbs and flows, as in inter-normativity phenomena studies of Jean Carbonnier” (Le Roy 1999: 200). Thus, it is a system of lasting, transposable dispositions that, integrates past experiences, functions at every moment as a matrix of perceptions, appreciations, and actions, and makes possible the achievement of infinitely diversified tasks, thanks to analogical transfers of schemes permitting the solution of similarly shaped problems (Lizardo 2004: 375–401). This is where habitus becomes a 103 See also Le Bris, Le Roy & Matthieu 1991 : 13-14. 104 For a discussion of this concept see De Loatch 2009.
  • 3. Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2153128Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2153128 222 helpful and flexible way to conceptualize social structure and uncover the most deeply buried structures of the different social worlds that form the social universe, as well as the "mechanisms" that tend to ensure their reproduction or transformation. Bourdieu adds “…habitus is the structures constitutive of a particular type of environment. [T]he practices produced by the habitus [are] the strategy-generating principle enabling agents to cope with unforeseen and ever-changing situations” (Bourdieu 1977: 72). 2) A Functional Concept of Community In order to further envisage the field of juridicity of habitus, my starting place consisted in establishing a functional concept of a community105 that a law intended to benefit. As an American researcher in Paris conducting initial fieldwork on the French island of Corsica (De Loatch 2009), the identity and nationalism of the Corsican people was crucial to the question of a proposed French environmental policy for the Corsican littoral. Who are the Corsicans, exactly? Dare I ask the taboo question of whether the Corsicans are a separate people from the French?106 Without a clearer understanding of their identity in relation to the island of Corsica and to France, one cannot penetrate below the surface. The stated objective of the PADDUC proposal107 by the French government was to alter current land use practices to promote its vision of ‘sustainable’ economic development of coastal lands, many of which have been historically under the management of village collectives on Corsica. Conducting fieldwork in a small village near the coast in the Balagne region of Corsica allowed the opportunity to observe the bond between people and place. This bond reveals a major symbolic relationship or rapport system with the occupied land and the process of association by a particular culture108 or social group. Bourdieu, among others, observed that social groups are the result of a continuous process rather than the expressions of fixed structures or species (Bourdieu 1980). A society is durable because it is an assembly of people and objects, and the impact of the society 105 Étienne Le Roy provides three appealing challenges in the identification of communities of concern to ‘patrimonial governance,’ of which I find two relevant to this paradigm: 1) the need to identify the diversity of the interests and 2) the conception of a functional design of the community. (Le Roy 2008). 106 I have been told that this is quite a taboo question in France actually; as France emphasizes the unity of the Republic and does not officially recognize diverse cultural communities, just French citizens. 107 Le Plan d'aménagement et de développement durable de la Corse (PADDUC) or the Management and Sustainable Development Plan of Corsica was assigned to the Territorial Community of Corsica (CTC) by the French Law of January 22, 2002 (n°2002-92), on Corsica (article 12). 108 The local laws regarding any act “… include a priori all the practices of uses, occupation, of the grounds, on territories (within the meaning of delimited spaces), defined by them, according to rules locally recognized” (Rochegude 2006: 87)
  • 4. 223 comes partly from these objects (such as the land) that are intricately woven into its fabric. Without these interconnections, the society loses its contextual interaction and cultural / human social rapport, and its roots in time, ground and territorial space. The habitus of the Corsican peoples i.e., a vision of “the total man,” as put forth by Marcel Mauss (1934: 8), is a kind of connector of the physiological, psychological components and societies of humans. This “system of provisions to the practice” produces a “tendency to act in a regular way” and a manner of acting that “does not find its principle in a rule or explicit law” (Bourdieu 1977: 72-95). Habitus “is part dependent on the blur and vagueness” of the Corsican people themselves. One finds in Corsica, in fact, a lyrical and convivial society that allows each individual agent to find its own place in the space. Formal and informal institutional associations prolong and deepen the rooting of the symbolic system and connection with others. Through the Corsican village institutions a bond is woven into the structure of the physical island space. It is this distinction from the ‘French’ that Corsicans, as a people bonded to the island of Corsica, appear to claim. These communal relationships encircling the island require membership based on adhesion to the institutions embedded in the villages. Gauging the degree of this adhesion also helps to define the parameters of it’s functional concept. Membership in these institutions implies acts of exclusion and of border building. Opposition between the initiates and the foreigners rests on the way in which one fosters close adhesion to the local institutional associations. Knowing one or more families in the village, taking an interest in learning the Corsican language or Corsican music, or being a member of an association or a closely affiliated outside group, such as the environmental group Surfrider, can all play a part by blurring the lines between foreigners and the initiates. Corsicans are influenced by their institutional membership in musical associations as well. The power of this type of local knowledge also helps to give some visitors the advantage of gaining adhesion and being distinguished from unknown foreigners. Music is very closely related to the collective life of the Corsicans of the Balagne, and its interconnection with the Corsican community emanates from the very heart of the island. Music-making in Corsica can serve to vehicle the complexities of Corsican social structures, their memberships and the tensions through the Corsicans’ dedication to seek, create, carry out and listen to their polyphonic songs and by their negotiating the contexts to which the Corsican music belongs.109 109 In one case, villagers informed their welcomed visitors to remove their car radio antenna to reduce the theft risk of the vehicle in a Corsican village. The antenna can be seen locally as a symbolic adhesion to the French on the continent, because one can only listen to ‘la musique française’ with an antenna, but without it, one shows a subtle act of solidarity with the local music traditions of Corsica. Moreover, there seems to be a distinction between the initiates,
  • 5. 224 Thus, forming community rapports requires social investment, not simply private investment (such as through property ownership) to establish the bonds of membership. The social relationships that form the foundation of community can be expressed in terms of economic factors, such as the accumulation of capital and extraction of rent, in addition to the legal standards of appropriation and methods of payment in the settlement of conflicts (Le Bris, Le Roy & Matthieu 1991: 13-14). This ‘authorized’ capital facilitates abstract human exchange, ‘lubricates’ the civil society and provides a voluntary supply of collective goods. It promotes confidence, increasing foreseeable behavior and reducing the costs of transaction (Svensden and Svensden 2003), thus providing incentives to form the bonds necessary to encourage mutual trust. The cornerstone of this kind of social capital rests on the cultural foundations of trust and assurances of mutual cooperation. These acts of investment in authorized capital can be seen in the efforts of a person with family ties to a village using her notoriety and wealth to renovate the village church, a tourist (or researcher) gaining acceptance in the village to become a `welcomed visitor' by taking part in a community beach cleanup day, or summer vacationers uniting with the villagers to protect local vegetation from a mountain flood. Following Bourdieu, the focus must be on the ‘economy in practice.’ In other words, it should be on ‘economic’ calculations that are behind not only obvious economic practices, but also the more hidden practices and more symbolic systems in order to better account for less ‘rational’ behaviors. These acts have the collective value of establishing and enforcing social norms and social relations, as well as allowing coordination of actions to achieve common goals. They also affect attitudes and mental provisions supporting co-operation in village social life (see, Coleman 1964 : 381-405). Nevertheless, one must avoid the impulse to create a dualistic opposition between the initiates and the foreigners, which would function only as an obstacle to a realistic construction of a theory of cultural dynamics. A complex analysis involves a continuum that is not simply a question of quantity of connections, but also of the individual quality of the relationship with the institutions of the village. These connections include, but are not limited to: religious, musical or environmental organizations, family antecedents in the village or on the island, the investment in and protection of the communal grounds of the village, proximity of work, time spent in the village and, to a lesser degree, the ownership of property in the region. The mechanisms that bind authorized capital are networks of the reciprocal rapports that depend on trust and assist in the creation of reciprocity who live as members of the village, and the foreigners, who are characterized as treating the local space like an object without heart and simply exploit its resources.
  • 6. 225 norms (Ostrom 2005). For example, after having taken part in the shared activities of the village, a welcomed visitor received a fruit basket from the garden of a local neighbor. Incorporating Coleman, the authorized capital is a neutral resource that facilitates without regard to the nature or the initiator or the transaction. This connection refers to the value assigned to the authorized capital in the social networks, between the initiates and the local community, opening a bridge between the two (Coleman 1964: 269-287). Much like the social networks created by the shepherds in Sardinia (Ruffino 2005), one often notes that each agent establishes bonds by occasional expressions or the sharing of local knowledge in order to reveal social dimensions or maps. To do so in spatial terms is to recognize that the social map results from plotting difference and diversity, and their actual outcomes (de Sousa Santos 1995: 399-473). These dimensions overlap and intertwine, producing a complex social map of aspirations, reflecting and reinforcing its cultural, social and economic divisions. These maps are also very effective in establishing the orientation of physical space rapports or symbolic systems. According to Boaventura de Sousa Santos, maps capture three elements: scale, projection, and symbolization. Each map is created by scale that is not only quantitative but also qualitative, and projection that is “… the process used by the legal order to define the limits of its operation and to organize this legal space…” (de Sousa Santos 1988: 363-388). The symbolization contained in maps is the visible side of the representation of reality. Its operation is based on and conditioned by the scale and projection, and relates to the representation with symbols of the characteristics and details of the reality that were selected. These maps consciously and subconsciously are established, recognized and negotiated, and the need for maintaining them and for reinforcing the rapports through service, reciprocal hospitality, and expressions of good will and friendship, is consciously identified. The maps are intricate in that each individual has her bonds, her stakes, and her manner of becoming part of the community, varying remarkably according to the bonds that are established and reinforced with time. The aggregation of these individual maps shared by the social network forms the local knowledge that helps to define the cultural map. Each act helps to reinforce and clarify the distinction between the Corsicans and the continental French, or between the autochthones and the tourists. The unfolding of these dynamics reflects the drive towards cultural self-definition and community identity inherent in each, establishing cultural self-similarity. The use of network data aggregation and analysis by social scientist, whether through direct fieldwork or cultural, economic, social and even
  • 7. 226 environmental informatics110 can help to recreate this map and provide a way to visualize a shared scientific structure. By studying the ways this drive manifests (its origin and characteristics; catalysts and inhibitors; and factors that support, sustain and reproduce), the dynamics of this ‘autopoietic’ or 'self-organizing’ system (often seen as resulting in unstable "turbulent-like" social forces and associated with "chaotic" behavior - Teubner 1993) may also be investigated. 3) Institutional Incentives Effecting Cultural Translation In addition to establishing a functional concept of the community, ascertaining the institutional structures that are equipped to influence or coerce compliance to law in practice is also needed. Neoclassical institutional approaches in the economic analysis of law have created models that assume no transaction costs, and that assume the final allocation of rights (such as land use rights) is always efficient, regardless of the initial entitlement (Coase 1937 and Coase 1960). However, by failing to incorporate environmental, social and cultural externalities and transaction cost, these simplistic models built directly from the neoclassical interpretation of Coase’s ‘theorem’ have struggled to capture real world dynamics and more complex phenomena. These types of analyses can prove to be too narrow, too simplistic, and rely too much on assertions and assumptions about reality. Despite the fact that this limited interpretation of economic analysis of law has some descriptive and explanatory power, many of the subtleties of human behavior are omitted or unexplained. Game theory models and behavioral economics have moved beyond this limited view. However, there still is a need to compare observations of real world behavior governing social autopoiesis with theoretical and experimental models and simulations. In fact, Ronald Coase and what has become New Institutional Economics (‘NIE’) have no interest in the narrow “neoclassical assumptions that individuals have perfect information and unbounded rationality and that transactions are costless and instantaneous (Menard 2000: 46-54). NIE “… considers choices to be embedded in the institutions… [thus having] a much broader reach than neoclassical economics, which has been largely concerned with prices and outcomes … As Kenneth Arrow observed … [NIE ask questions as to] why economic institutions emerged the way they did … [In addition, Douglas] North has pointed out [i]nstitutionalist …understand change by 110 Informatics has created new sources and tools for interdisciplinary research of networks with computational data collection. “Informatics is the science of information. It studies the representation, processing, and communication of information in natural and artificial systems. Since computers, individuals and organizations all process information, informatics has computational, cognitive and social aspects.” See entry for ‘informatics’ in International Encyclopedia of Information and Library Science (second edition) (0415259010) John Feather and Paul Sturges eds., Routledge, 2002.
  • 8. 227 understanding human incentives and intentions and the beliefs, norms and rules that they create in pursuit of their goals” (Menard and Shirley 2005: 2). [Elinor] Ostrom stresses “…the regularized plans that individuals make within the structure of incentives [is] produced by rules, norms, and expectations of the likely behavior of others affected by relevant physical and material conditions.” (Ostrom 2005a: 825). The tools of NIE analysis of law can provide a way to frame how a community’s institutions establish positive and negative social incentives for obtaining community adhesion. The costs of transaction are evaluated according to the manner in which the institutional frameworks provide incentives (or disincentives) for agents to engage in a given activity or behavior. In this way, an individual’s personal incentives can fail to align with social incentives of the community, falling well short of the optimal social equilibrium and outside the social norm determined by a communal valuation of such things as the scarce natural resources of the Corsican coast. The pressures to align with the norms of community create various incentives to align the individual with this social norm, its optimal social balance. Thus, the individual’s efficiency assessment conflicts with the socially efficient assessment. For those individuals who do not understand or do not heed the community’s prescription for the optimal social balance, an explosive (and sometimes violent) form of communication can be offered on the island of Corsica. The underlying problem with this individual efficiency assessment is that a foreign individual may be unaware of or ignore the costs (or benefits) that she imposes on others in the village. This “free rider” problem leads to, in the case of cost imposition, the under- supply of the collective public good, and forces a reduction in the collective public interest of the village. Accordingly, a sanction for ignorance of the custom can appear. This sanction can be a legal consequence of an attitude or of a behavior relating to the social norms in which it is located. Between these efficiency assessments it “... is not thus only to fight, it is also to get along on legitimacy or illegitimacy of these practices … the law of a society is ordered thus around the limits of the spheres of action of each one in these fields; it holds for vital: it is at the same time consensus on these limits and practices, aiming or succeeding to confirm them or moving them” (Alliot 1983: 85–6). Adopting the concept of fixed action patterns,111 the replication of norms promotes cultural pattern 111 Sharing with anthropology the concern of the importance of context, ethologist (who study animal subjects in their environment) have defined a fixed action pattern as a behavior that occurs in a fairly intact form even in the absence of experience or learning but can be further refined by experience. (Sapolsky 2005: 267-281 and 395). In this way cultural action patterns embed its history and sense of identity within the social map as discussed below.
  • 9. 228 emergence in community behavior. The legal standards of ‘everyday life’ rest on the ideals and criteria developed by the community. As a result, they build upon and cultivate their customary laws. The individual is thus confronted by these community incentives as a method to cure the conflict between the individual evaluation and social efficiency evaluation of the community. One must also consider the level of pressure exerted by the community to have its norms replicated as an exact translation or transposition, promoting a pattern in cultural behavior to emerge. Translation factors modify a cultural action pattern’s emergence based on: an institution’s ability to promote or repress a given cultural practice, valuation or use of an object such as the coastal land; the degree of network connectivity affecting information exchange; the enforcement and reinforcement of norms; the degree of norm rigidity (or conversely flexibility) of the community; and the variability of cultural reproduction affecting the institutional structures. Trade-offs calculations (the costs of exchanges) are made continuously among the structures, where incentives alter the structural map of social norms. The power of these incentives rests on the threat of symbolic sanctions and, from time to time, real sanctions. It is a risk that everyone in the community must control. Risk is the median value of the consequences of the affected events. One of the difficulties in risk management is the fact that the consequence is often uncertain. Direct quantitative measurements and data collection can prove complicated. However, one can identify and evaluate risks on a collective level of the social efficiency of the custom of the community. Like the conscious or subconscious utilization of mathematical probabilities by an individual, one can estimate the difference between an individual’s personal efficiency assessment and the efficiency assessment of the community. It is through fieldwork techniques that one can observe and measure ordinal preferences and the quality of the risk in a given social interaction. This ordinal measurement of utility can be used to describe the bundle of rights or preferences of an individual compared with the social evaluation of the customs of the community that define the limits of the legal order and help to organize the legal space. This economic calculation is behind not only the obvious economic practices, but also more hidden practices and more symbolic systems that are characteristic and help to reveal the details of the reality of the community. Thus, many material and immaterial economies may exist for ‘market’ exchange. 4) Juridicity as a Complex Adaptive System The literature on complex systems has spread from the study of natural systems to the study of
  • 10. 229 social systems.112 Chaotic behaviors are beginning to be explained in terms of nonlinear dynamics and arise naturally in areas as diverse as evolutionary biology, applied mathematics, game theory, quantum mechanics, coding and information theory. Complexity theory’s impact on economics has helped to shift focus from equilibrium models to nonlinear dynamics, “…as researchers recognize that economics, like ecosystems, may never settle down into an equilibrium (Lansing 2003: 193). Similarly, “…the aspects that may be of greatest interest to anthropologists have to do with the emergent properties of social and behavioral systems (Lansing 2003: 193). By adapting economic tools to nonlinear dynamics, empirical and measurable observations from anthropological and sociological research may be able to be ordered, analyzed and compared with other observations in the search for key institutions and explanatory variables. The idea that an institutional analysis of social incentives, like much of the physical and biological world, is generated by a recursive process creating a fractal structure,113 is an intriguing and potentially powerful direction for this type of research. The ultimate goal is to begin to frame real world cultural dynamics in order to compare alternatives, to determine the model’s descriptive and predictive capacities and to test it against the theoretical and experimental models currently offered. In a nonlinear dynamic construction of ‘juridicity,’ the transposition of dispositions can be ordered in terms of 1) a ‘bounded’ social trajectory114 that serves to map the social norms of the community, 2) institutional transposition or translation factors’ that effect the variance of reproduction of the norm, 3) observation of or informatics on the scale of network and the quality of its interconnections and 4) variation over interaction events, time or other intervals. The social trajectory creates a map represented by a simple dichotomy of choices or a more complex range of behaviors in which informatics analysis and ordinal measurements of utility can be used to describe a bundle of rights or cultural preferences. On this map, in the abstract, cultural reproduction would create an exact replica of social norms, an exact reflective mirror image of the dispositions in its next iteration. In reality, errors in translation are introduced with each individual’s interpretation of the norm despite the influence or coercive power of the institutions that guide and limit the cultural action patterns used to define the limits of social behavior and to organize the legal space.115 For 112 For a general overview see Miller & Pages 2007 and Mitchell Melanie, 2009: 368. Specific examples include Lansing J. Stephen, 2006: 240, and multi-disciplinary authors, Liu et al. 2007. 113 See Ruhl 1997 and Benoit Mandelbrot's theory of fractional dimensions highlights the relativity of measure with respect to scale and emphasizes the kinship of his ideas with the emphasis on the perspective of the observer (Mandelbrot and Hudson 2004: 97). 114 As defined in Bourdieu 1977: 86. 115 In another example, for the Swedish research program Sustainable Coastal Zone Management, in conflicts analysis studies, its version of ‘mapping’ of stakeholders and their interest was included in the complex adaptive methodology, noting that “[m]ore recently formulated criteria for sustainable resource management include socially robust systems
  • 11. 230 example, the degree of network connectivity affecting information exchange dramatically changed when a collective in favor of the "coastal protection law" was launched on the internet gathering scores of associations, ecologists and some local political parties (nationalist, greens, socialist, communist…) in favor of this popular initiative. Enforcement and reinforcement of norms grew denouncing “… the pressures exerted by some `property [and] recreational developers, architects, [and] elected political within the framework of PADDUC.”116 It is this diachronic process of constant renovation, generating a dynamic cultural action pattern that enables juridicities to emerge. Mapping this space will help to organize observations and graphically illustrate how individual agents as a group cope with unforeseen and ever-changing situations, thus managing risk through the strategy-generating principles embedded in the structuring of practices and representations. The bundle of rights that serve to apportion the risk can be used to identify alternatives in governance. The ultimate goal of this emerging framework is to most efficiently place the burden of that risk.117 What complex systems can do is highlight this connection by demonstrating that risk premiums may be much higher than one would expect with a more conventional statistical distribution (Farber 1997). Analogous to scale in the de Sousa Santos maps discussed above, in this construction of the field of juridicity, the aggregation of the individual information maps disseminate through the shared social networks. In terms of quantity, institutional structures may exist on global, national, regional, local, communal or other scales of connectivity. Qualitatively, scale also infers a kind of order that requires transformations of scale to consistently replicate the same range of possibilities guiding cultural action patterns across other active scales. In other words, when the influence or the coercive power of institutions on each scale of connectivity exhibit the maximum of invariance (thus the most similarity) in cultural action patterns. This offers a new criterion to determine whether social incentives proposed in laws like PADDUC on the scale of French national and regional bureaucracy will introduce scaling failures given the wide variance between efficiency assessments of the official law of the French Republic compared with the components of participation, knowledge integration, and maintaining biological and cultural diversity through pluri-centric adaptive systems” (Bruckmeier 2005: 65-66). 116 The petition continues, “[PADDUC] is contrary to the collective interests of all the Corsicans. Indeed, its economic priorities are founded on coastal tourist mono-activity and residential economy…” (Pétition contre le Projet de PADDUC en Corse http://cll-corse.org/, accessed 09/05/09.) The network binding of the social trajectory reinforces the mapping of social norms of the coastal area collectives. After the creation of this social network, musical associations renewed their interest in taking part in island politics by opposing the proposed French legislative transposition, in spite of the fact that many of the associations receive significant monetary support from the French regional Executive council of the Corsican territorial collectivity. (De Loatch 2009 : 60).
  • 12. 231 to the scale of the customary law of the Corsicans or to the scale of global environmental institutions reinforcing the public local competence.118 Scaling failures may also be seen when PADDUC’s incentives are compared to a chosen efficiency criteria, such as based on an efficiency principle for sustainable development (see De Loatch 2008) or compare with other theoretical or experimental results. The degree of self-similarity of cultural action patterns can be tested across scales by assessing translation factor incentives in each network’s implementation of norms. 4) The Complex Nature of Environmental Governance Like an elephant, invisible when viewed in the darkness, one’s perspective is limited to only the part of the elephant that one can grasp within a discipline. Thus, one can be misled into incorrect conclusions and misinterpretations as to the whole. This is a modest attempt to take a step back, to gain enough perspective that the elephant’s shape emerges out of obscurity and the myriad of influencing variables. The courage of alternatives in environmental governance relies not only on building an interdisciplinary framework that can better approximate the complex dynamics at work but also in confronting our own rigid disciplinary constructs, exposing new perspectives in human behavioral phenomenon. This initial outline of a framework of juridicity in Corsican society suggests how institutional social incentives help to regulate behaviors. Through legal anthropology and sociology we find a lucid and critical analytical method of examining the crucial relationship between law, cultural and social life in an age of increasing interconnectivity within the global economy. Equally, economic analysis of law can help shine a harsh bright light on the murky area where the rule of law comes into contact with and is shaped by economic power. For present purposes, the modest goal of this article is a tentative exploration of the possibility of using nonlinear dynamics to provide a conceptual framework for thinking about a wide variety of temporal progressions, based on dynamics of complex systems and on preliminary empirical evidence. Complexity theory offers new ways to explore the topoi at the bases of juridicity, continuing to broaden the multi-disciplinary structure of social dynamics and perhaps providing a new means to confront the demands and challenges of otherness, complexity and interculturality (Eberhard 2011: 23ss), while allowing for an intercultural comparison of institutional structures within complex adaptive systems. 117 The burden of environmental risk is always borne somewhere, or more precisely, with someone (often less developed third countries or future generations in the case of environmental damage). Someone, somewhere, at sometime will bear the cost of the risks that are taken (De Loatch 2008). 118 See Rochegude 2005 : 59-72.
  • 13. 232 BIBLIOGRAPHY ARROW Kenneth J., 1974, The Limits of Organization, New York, W. W. Norton & Company, 86 p. ARROW Kenneth J., 1963, Social Choice and Individual Values, New Haven and London, Yale University Press, Second Edition, 138 p. ALLIOT Michel, 1983, « Anthropologie et juristique. Sur les conditions de l’élaboration d’une science du droit », Bulletin de Liaison du Laboratoire d’Anthropologie Juridique de Paris, n°6, p 83–117. BOURDIEU Pierre 1986, « Habitus, code et codification », Actes de la recherche en sciences sociales, n°64, p 60-64. BOURDIEU Pierre, 1980, Le sens pratique, Paris, Les Editions de Minuit, 475 p. BOURDIEU Pierre, 1977, Outline of a Theory of Practice, Translated by Richard Nice, New York: Cambridge University Press, 248 p. BRUCKMEIER Karl, 2005, “Interdisciplinary Conflict Analysis and Conflict Mitigation in Local Resource Management”, Ambio Vol. 34, No.2, March 2005, p. 65- 73. COASE Ronald H., 1960, “The Problem of Social Cost”, 3 Journal of Law and Economics p 1-44. COASE Ronald, 1937, “The Nature of the Firm”, reprinted from Economica, n.s., 4, p 386-405, (November 1937), in WILLIAMSON Oliver E. and WINTER Sidney G. (Eds.) 1993, The Nature of the Firm: Origins, Evolution and Development. Oxford University Press, New York, 244 p. COLEMAN James S., 1964, An Introduction to Mathematical Sociology., New York, Free Press of Glencoe, a division of the MacMillan Company, 554 p. DE LOATCH Jovita L., 2009, Enquête corse sur la passion pour le littoral de l’île de beauté: Un préalable épistémologique entre l’anthropologie juridique et l’analyse économique du droit, Mémoire de Master de Droit - Mention Droit comparé- Spécialité recherche Anthropologie du droit, Unitversité de Paris 1 (Panthéon- Sorbonne) Année Universitaire 2008-2009, 103 p. DE LOATCH Jovita L., 2008, “A Sustainable ‘Middle Way’ to Economic Responsibility in Environmental Governance : The Case of EC Salmon Aquaculture”, in EBERHARD Christoph (dir.), Traduire nos responsabilités planétaires. Recomposer nos paysages juridiques, Bruxelles, Bruylant, Col. Bibliothèque de l’Académie Européenne de Théorie du Droit, 756 p 583- 611.
  • 14. 233 de SOUSA SANTOS Boaventura, 1995, Toward a New Common Sense: Law, Science and Politics in the Paradigmatic Transition, New York, Routledge, 614 p. de SOUSA SANTOS Boaventura, 1988, « Une carte de la lecture déformée. Pour une conception post-moderne du droit », Droit & Société, n° 10, p 363-388. DYKE Chuck and DYKE Carl, 2002, “Indentities: The Dynamical Dimensions of Diversity”, Diversity and Community: An Interdisciplinary Reader, Philip Alperson (Ed.), Oxford, Wiley- Blackwell; First Edition, 351 p. EBERHARD Christoph, 2011, Le droit au miroir des cultures. Pour une autre mondialisation, Paris, LGDJ/Lextenso, 2ème edition, 254 p. EBERHARD Christoph, 2006, « Trois problématiques pour une dynamique d’anthropologie du Droit », in Le Roy Étienne (dir.), Juridicités, Cahiers d’Anthropologie du Droit, Hors série, Paris, Karthala, 176 p 59-70. EBERHARD Christoph (dir.), 2005, Droit, gouvernance et développement durable, numéro spécial des Cahiers d’Anthropologie du Droit, Paris, Karthala, 376 p. EBERHARD Christoph, 2001, “Towards an Intercultural Legal Theory: The Dialogical Challenge”, Social & Legal Studies, Vol. 10(2), p 171–201. FARBER Daniel A., 2003, “Probabilities Behaving Badly: Complexity Theory and Environmental Uncertainty”, U.C. Davis Law Review, n° 37, p 145-173. FRIED Barbara H., 1998, The Progressive Assault on Laissez Faire : Robert Hale and the First Law and Economics Movement, Cambridge Mass., Harvard University Press, 352 p. JAFFE Alexandra, 1999, Ideologies in Action: Language Politics in Corsica, (Language, power & social process), Berlin, Mouton de Gruyter, 323 p. LANSING Bali, Princeton Studies in Complexity, Princeton, Princeton University Press, 248 p. LANSING J. Stephen, 2003, “Complex Adaptive Systems”, Annual Review Anthropology, n° 32, 183-204. LE BRIS Émile, LE ROY Étienne, et MATHIEU Paul, 1991, L’appropriation de la terre en Afrique noire. Manuel d’analyse, de décision et de gestion foncières, Paris, Karthala, 359 p. LE ROY Étienne, 1999, Le jeu des lois. Une anthropologie « dynamique » du Droit, Paris, LGDJ, Col. Droit et Société, Série anthropologique, 415 p. LIZARDO Omar, 2004, “The Cognitive Origins of Bourdieu’s Habitus”, Journal for the Theory of Social Behaviour, Volume 34, Issue 4, December 2004, p 375–401.
  • 15. 234 LIU Jianguo, Dietz Thomas, Carpenter Stephen R., Folke Carl, Alberti Marina, Redman Charles L., Schneider Stephen H., Ostrom Elinor, Pell Alice N., Lubchenco Jane, Taylor William W., Ouyang Zhiyun, Deadman Peter, Kratz Timothy, and Provencher William, 2007, “The development of Coupled Human and Natural Systems”, AMBIO: A Journal of the Human Environment, N°36 (8), p 639-649. MANDELBROT Benoit B., 1977, The Fractal Geometry of Nature. New York, Freeman, 480 p. MANDELBROT Benoit B. and HUDSON Richard L., 2004, The (Mis)behavior of Markets: A Fractal View of Risk, Ruin, and Reward, New York, Basic Books, 328 p. MAUSS Marcel, 1934, « Les techniques du corps » Article originalement publié Journal de Psychologie, XXXII, ne, 3-4, 15 mars - 15 avril 1936. Communication présentée à la Société de Psychologie le 17 mai 1934, 23 p. MÉNARD Claude and SHIRLEY Mary M. (eds.), 2005, Handbook of New Institutional Economics, The Netherlands, Springer, AA Dordrecht, , 884 p. MÉNARD Claude, 2000, “Ronald H. Coase and the emergence of a new approach to economics” in MÉNARD Claude (ed.), 2000, Institutions, Contracts and Organizations: Perspectives from New Institutional Economics, New York, Edward Elgar Publishing, p. 54-58. MILLER John H., PAGES Scott E., 2007, Complex Adaptive Systems: An Introduction to Computational Models of Social Life (Princeton Studies in Complexity), Princeton, Princeton University Press, p 284. MOORE Sally Falk, 2006, « The Sociologic of Land Law”, in EBERHARD Christoph et VERNICOS Geneviève (Éds.), La quête anthropologique du droit. Autour de la démarche d'Étienne Le Roy, Paris, Karthala, p 133-145. MOORE Sally Falk, 1978, Law As Process: An Anthropological Approach, London Boston, Routledge & K. Paul, 270 p. OST François and van de KERCHOVE Michel (2002) De la pyramide au réseau? Pour une théorie dialectique du droit, Bruxelles, Publications des Facultés universitaires Saint Louis, 596 p. OSTROM Elinor, 2005a, Doing Institutional Analysis, in MÉNARD Claude and SHIRLEY Mary M. (eds.), 2005, Handbook of New Institutional Economics, Netherlands, Springer, AA Dordrecht, 884 p. OSTROM Elinor, 2005b, Understanding Institutional Diversity, Princeton, Princeton University Press, 355 p.
  • 16. 235 OSTROM Elinor, and WALKER James, 2003, Trust & Reciprocity, Interdisciplinary Lessons from Experimental Research, New York, Russell Sage Foundation, 409 p. POLINSKY A. Mitchell, 1974, Economic Analysis as a Potentially Defective Product: A Buyer’s Guide to Posner’s Economic Analysis of Law, 87 Harvard Law Review, p 1655-81. ROCHEGUDE Alain, 2006, « Le Foncier, une préoccupation constante, un champ d’expertise reconnue », Le Roy Étienne (dir.), Juridicités, Cahiers d’Anthropologie du Droit, Hors série, Karthala, 176 p (87). ROCHEGUDE Alain, 2005, « Le ‘droit d’agir’, une proposition pour la ‘bonne gouvernance foncière », EBERHARD Christoph (éd.), 2005, Droit, gouvernance et développement durable, numéro spécial des Cahiers d’Anthropologie du Droit, Paris, Karthala, 376 p (59-72). RUHL J.B., 1997, “Thinking of Environmental Law as a Complex Adaptive System: How to Clean Up the Environment by Making a Mess of Environmental Law”, 34 Houston Law Review, p 933- 1002. RUFFINO Julio, 2005, "Disputing over Livestock in Sardinia", Law and Anthropology: a Reader, Sally Falk Moore (Ed.), 2005, 384 p (135-153). SAPOLSKY Robert, 2005, Biology and Human Behavior: The Neurological Origins of Individuality, 2nd Edition, Course No. 1597, Chantilly, The Teaching Company, 412 p (267-281). SVENSDEN Gunnar Lind Haase et SVENDSEN Gert Tinggaard, 2003, « On the wealth of nations : Bourdieuconomics and social capital », Theory and Society 32 : p 607-631. TEUBNER Günther, 1993, Law as an Autopoietic System, (Anne Bankowska & Ruth Adler trans.), Zenon Bankowski (ed.), European University Institute Press series, Blackwell Publishers, Oxford, Cambridge, USA, Blackwell, 203 p. WERIN Lars, 2000, “Ronald Coase and the New Microeconomics”, in Claude MENARD (ed.), Institutions, Contracts and Organizations: Perspectives from New Institutional Economics, Edward Elgar Publishing (Northhampton), p 42-47.