SlideShare une entreprise Scribd logo
1  sur  6
Télécharger pour lire hors ligne
Interdisciplinary, unpaid research opportunities are available. Various academic specialties are required. If interested, email me at
dr.freedom@hotmail.ca.
The Benefits of Canadian Food Aid Policy to the Canadian Economy
By Oleg Nekrassovski
Tied aid involves a developed country giving a loan or a grant to a developing country
while dictating where in the world they should buy what they need with that money. This
generally amounts to the recipient country being told to spend the given money in the donor
country (i.e. on the goods and services produced by that country) (Tied aid, n.d.). Untied aid, on
the other hand, involves a similar transaction between a developed and a developing country,
with the main difference being that the developing country can spend the received money
anywhere it wants (Untied aid, n.d.). The present paper, however, will focus neither on the tied
food aid nor on the untied food aid. Instead, it will focus on the direct, free transfer of food
produced in Canada, to the countries in need. And it will argue that such food aid is highly
beneficial to Canadian economy in various ways.
Most experts agree that surplus disposal and addition of value to Canadian food products
are the two key potential benefits of Canadian food aid policy to Canadian economy (Charlton,
1992). Surplus disposal involves reducing excess inventories of locally produced food products
by sending them off as foreign aid (Charlton, 1992). The surplus food produce, of course, does
not get shipped off without any compensation to its producers; otherwise there would be no
benefit to the Canadian economy. Instead, a federal government agency, such as the Canadian
International Development Agency (CIDA), purchases the surplus food produce from its
producers at a mutually agreed upon price, which is seldom equal to the lowest one on the world
market (Charlton, 1992).
Interdisciplinary, unpaid research opportunities are available. Various academic specialties are required. If interested, email me at
dr.freedom@hotmail.ca.
Canadian economy can benefit from surplus disposal in at least two ways. First, the
handling and storage of excess inventories carries considerable costs, which are significantly
reduced by early disposal of the surplus (Charlton, 1992). In fact, there are many unnecessary
costs, which are incurred by the carrying of excess inventory. Every item kept in stock must be
financed by its interest or opportunity cost, which amounts to between 10% and 15% of the
item’s value. Moving items in and out of facilities incurs its own costs; as does storing them in a
rented space (Sahin & Robinson, 2007). And even if the storage space is owned rather than
rented, a considerable opportunity cost may be incurred by using this space to store excess
inventory, if the same space can be used for another, more productive activity (Sahin &
Robinson, 2007). Also, taxes must be paid on all inventory assets. While insurance is also
usually paid for all types of stock. Finally, inventory shrinkage also has its costs. Shrinkage
occurs due to pilferage, obsolescence, or deterioration (Sahin & Robinson, 2007). In the case of
food produce, deterioration is doubtlessly a major cause of inventory shrinkage.
Second, large surpluses have a depressive effect on the markets of food products. Surplus
disposal, not surprisingly, greatly reduces this depressive effect (Charlton, 1992). In fact, a
surplus of food produce on the Canadian market means that the supplied quantity of food
produce is greater than optimal, i.e. above that required to achieve the equilibrium price.
Moreover, the increase in the quantity of any commodity on the market means a decrease in the
quantity of it demanded by the customers (McConnell et al., 2002). Since, the equilibrium point
is the only point at which the quantity supplied is equal to the quantity demanded, under surplus
conditions the quantity supplied at a price acceptable to the producer, is considerably greater
than the quantity demanded, at that price, by the consumers. Consequently, under surplus
conditions, the producers cannot sell a large quantity of their produce at a price acceptable to
Interdisciplinary, unpaid research opportunities are available. Various academic specialties are required. If interested, email me at
dr.freedom@hotmail.ca.
them (McConnell et al., 2002). On the other hand, if they are determined to sell all of their
produce (because, for example, it will simply rot and become worthless if they don’t), they have
to considerably lower the prices in order to cause the quantity demanded to increase. Thus, the
existence of the surplus in the food market, while having no effect on the consumers (as they
always get as much or as little as they want depending on the price), greatly harms the food
producers (McConnell et al., 2002). This is why surpluses are said to ‘depress’ the markets and
harm the economy.
In order to be effective, however, the disposal of surplus food products should be
correctly matched with eternally changing market conditions. During the late sixties, for
example, the disposal of surplus wheat was a primary objective of Canadian food aid policy
(Charlton, 1992). On the other hand, during the boom years of the seventies the shipping of
surplus wheat as foreign aid became uneconomic, because during those years the Canadian
farmers had no trouble selling all of their surplus wheat to other countries. Consequently, the
boom years of the seventies saw a shift in Canadian food aid exports from wheat to products like
fish, dried eggs, canned meat, and milk powder (Charlton, 1992).
The value added to Canadian food produce by processing it, is another economic benefit
of Canadian food aid policy (Charlton, 1992). Value added is the market value of the product
sold by a firm minus the value of the inputs that the firm has purchased and used to produce that
product. Value added to every product is paid out as wages, rent, interest, and profit by the firm
that produced it (McConnell et al., 2002). Consequently, the shipping of flour instead of wheat,
for example, causes an addition of value to wheat through its processing into flour and a
resulting input of wages, rents, interests, and profits into the Canadian economy. Moreover, the
Interdisciplinary, unpaid research opportunities are available. Various academic specialties are required. If interested, email me at
dr.freedom@hotmail.ca.
processing of various food products leads to an increase in the utilization of the existing
productive capacity of the industry that processes these products (Charlton, 1992).
In its most basic conception, “capacity” is an aspect of output, which is directly
proportional to the changes in capital stock over the long-run. Capacity is measured in various
ways, and it is useful to split it into two categories of “engineering” and “economic” capacity.
Engineering capacity is the maximum production level which can be sustained over a certain
interval of time. While economic capacity is the desired production level (Shaikh & Moudud,
2004). For example, it may be possible, for a certain flour-milling plant, to mill three thousand
tons into flour in one week. But it may turn out that the higher costs of milling the second and
third ton, due to extra maintenance requirements, higher wages for night workers, etc., make the
milling of only one ton per week, most profitable. Hence, economic capacity constitutes an
optimal level of output (Shaikh & Moudud, 2004). A persistent production below economic
capacity indicates the need to slowdown the planned capacity growth, while that persistently
above it indicates that the planned capacity growth can be accelerated (Kurz, 1986). Thus, an
increase in demand for processed foods, leads to increased output of the food processing plants,
and an increase in their capacity growth. Moreover, over the short-run, changes in output are
thought to correlate with changes in employment. Thus, in the short-run, an increase in capacity
utilization rate (the ratio of output to capacity) will likely see a collateral increase in the
employment rate (the ratio of employment to labour supply), which is unquestionably beneficial
to the economy of any country (Shaikh & Moudud, 2004). The increase in demand on canola oil
and wheat flour, caused by using them as food aid, has greatly benefited the flour-milling and
canola oilseed crushing industries, which previously experienced chronically low levels of
capacity utilization in their facilities (Charlton, 1992).
Interdisciplinary, unpaid research opportunities are available. Various academic specialties are required. If interested, email me at
dr.freedom@hotmail.ca.
Aside from surplus disposal and the addition of value to Canadian food products, there
are other, though lesser, benefits of Canadian food aid policy to the Canadian economy. The
foremost among them is market development. Market development with respect to food aid
generally works through the shipping as food aid of a certain type of Canadian food produce to
recipient countries unfamiliar with this type of food (Charlton, 1992). The result is that the
recipients get thoroughly familiarized with the quality of these Canadian food products and end
up developing a taste for them. Once that happens and once the short-term famines, in the
recipient countries, are over, the former food aid recipients start to be treated as full paying
customers (Charlton, 1992).
Food aid has also been used by Canadian political leaders to obtain and/or seal trade
agreements with other countries, once again to the benefit of the Canadian economy. For
example, in 1977 Colombia signed an important trade agreement with Canada, which may not
have taken place if Canada had not also offered to sign another agreement with Colombia which
stated that Canada will donate to Colombia 1800 tons of skim milk powder (Charlton, 1992).
Interdisciplinary, unpaid research opportunities are available. Various academic specialties are required. If interested, email me at
dr.freedom@hotmail.ca.
References
Charlton, M. W. (1992). The making of Canadian food aid policy. Montreal: McGill-Queen’s
University Press.
Kurz, H. (1986). Normal positions and capital utilization. Political Economy: Studies in the
Surplus Approach, 2(1), 37-54.
McConnell, C. R., Brue, S. L., & Barbiero, T. P. (2002). Macroeconomics. Toronto: McGraw-
Hill Ryerson.
Sahin, F., & Robinson, E. P. Jr. (2007). Inventory management. In J. T. Mentzer, M. B. Myers,
& T. P. Stank (Eds.), Handbook of global supply chain management (pp. 185-201).
Thousand Oaks, California: Sage Publications, Inc.
Shaikh, A. M., & Moudud, J. K. (2004). Measuring capacity utilization in OECD countries: A
cointegration method. The Levy Economics Institute Working Paper Collection, 415.
Retrieved from http://homepage.newschool.edu/~AShaikh/measuring%20capacity.pdf
Tied aid. (n.d.). Retrieved November 30, 2011 from Wikipedia:
http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Tied_aid
Untied aid. (n.d.). Retrieved November 30, 2011 from Wikipedia:
http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Untied_aid

Contenu connexe

Plus de Oleg Nekrassovski

Details and Implementation Plan of a Code of Ethics for a Proposed Lunar Colony
Details and Implementation Plan of a Code of Ethics for a Proposed Lunar ColonyDetails and Implementation Plan of a Code of Ethics for a Proposed Lunar Colony
Details and Implementation Plan of a Code of Ethics for a Proposed Lunar ColonyOleg Nekrassovski
 
The Politics of Gender, Sexual Orientation, and the Canadian Forces, between ...
The Politics of Gender, Sexual Orientation, and the Canadian Forces, between ...The Politics of Gender, Sexual Orientation, and the Canadian Forces, between ...
The Politics of Gender, Sexual Orientation, and the Canadian Forces, between ...Oleg Nekrassovski
 
Learning, Insight, and Innovation in Animals in the Context of Evolution
Learning, Insight, and Innovation in Animals in the Context of EvolutionLearning, Insight, and Innovation in Animals in the Context of Evolution
Learning, Insight, and Innovation in Animals in the Context of EvolutionOleg Nekrassovski
 
Corporate Psychopaths: The Good, the Evil, and Organizational Differences
Corporate Psychopaths: The Good, the Evil, and Organizational DifferencesCorporate Psychopaths: The Good, the Evil, and Organizational Differences
Corporate Psychopaths: The Good, the Evil, and Organizational DifferencesOleg Nekrassovski
 
Transformational Leadership, Servant Leadership, and Psychological Needs
Transformational Leadership, Servant Leadership, and Psychological NeedsTransformational Leadership, Servant Leadership, and Psychological Needs
Transformational Leadership, Servant Leadership, and Psychological NeedsOleg Nekrassovski
 
Leadership and Organizational Function
Leadership and Organizational FunctionLeadership and Organizational Function
Leadership and Organizational FunctionOleg Nekrassovski
 
Review of Andrew J. Bacevich's The New American Militarism - How Americans ar...
Review of Andrew J. Bacevich's The New American Militarism - How Americans ar...Review of Andrew J. Bacevich's The New American Militarism - How Americans ar...
Review of Andrew J. Bacevich's The New American Militarism - How Americans ar...Oleg Nekrassovski
 
Review of 2 Journal Articles on Psychological Factors Influencing Capital Pun...
Review of 2 Journal Articles on Psychological Factors Influencing Capital Pun...Review of 2 Journal Articles on Psychological Factors Influencing Capital Pun...
Review of 2 Journal Articles on Psychological Factors Influencing Capital Pun...Oleg Nekrassovski
 
NASA and the Space Shuttle Program
NASA and the Space Shuttle ProgramNASA and the Space Shuttle Program
NASA and the Space Shuttle ProgramOleg Nekrassovski
 
NASA - The Quest for the Moon
NASA - The Quest for the MoonNASA - The Quest for the Moon
NASA - The Quest for the MoonOleg Nekrassovski
 
Canada, and the US Ballistic Missile Defence Program
Canada, and the US Ballistic Missile Defence ProgramCanada, and the US Ballistic Missile Defence Program
Canada, and the US Ballistic Missile Defence ProgramOleg Nekrassovski
 
Barriers to International Cooperation
Barriers to International CooperationBarriers to International Cooperation
Barriers to International CooperationOleg Nekrassovski
 
Econometric Military Production Function
Econometric Military Production FunctionEconometric Military Production Function
Econometric Military Production FunctionOleg Nekrassovski
 
Canada’s Commitment to Tolerance, Democracy, and the Rule of Law
Canada’s Commitment to Tolerance, Democracy, and the Rule of LawCanada’s Commitment to Tolerance, Democracy, and the Rule of Law
Canada’s Commitment to Tolerance, Democracy, and the Rule of LawOleg Nekrassovski
 
Transnational Terrorism vs Local Terrorism
Transnational Terrorism vs Local TerrorismTransnational Terrorism vs Local Terrorism
Transnational Terrorism vs Local TerrorismOleg Nekrassovski
 
The Relationship between the USA and China/North Vietnam/USSR, in light of th...
The Relationship between the USA and China/North Vietnam/USSR, in light of th...The Relationship between the USA and China/North Vietnam/USSR, in light of th...
The Relationship between the USA and China/North Vietnam/USSR, in light of th...Oleg Nekrassovski
 
Military Robots and Canadian Defence and Foreign Policy
Military Robots and Canadian Defence and Foreign PolicyMilitary Robots and Canadian Defence and Foreign Policy
Military Robots and Canadian Defence and Foreign PolicyOleg Nekrassovski
 
Political Economy of UAVs, and Cost-Benefit Analysis and Optimization of UAV ...
Political Economy of UAVs, and Cost-Benefit Analysis and Optimization of UAV ...Political Economy of UAVs, and Cost-Benefit Analysis and Optimization of UAV ...
Political Economy of UAVs, and Cost-Benefit Analysis and Optimization of UAV ...Oleg Nekrassovski
 

Plus de Oleg Nekrassovski (20)

Details and Implementation Plan of a Code of Ethics for a Proposed Lunar Colony
Details and Implementation Plan of a Code of Ethics for a Proposed Lunar ColonyDetails and Implementation Plan of a Code of Ethics for a Proposed Lunar Colony
Details and Implementation Plan of a Code of Ethics for a Proposed Lunar Colony
 
The Politics of Gender, Sexual Orientation, and the Canadian Forces, between ...
The Politics of Gender, Sexual Orientation, and the Canadian Forces, between ...The Politics of Gender, Sexual Orientation, and the Canadian Forces, between ...
The Politics of Gender, Sexual Orientation, and the Canadian Forces, between ...
 
Learning, Insight, and Innovation in Animals in the Context of Evolution
Learning, Insight, and Innovation in Animals in the Context of EvolutionLearning, Insight, and Innovation in Animals in the Context of Evolution
Learning, Insight, and Innovation in Animals in the Context of Evolution
 
Corporate Psychopaths: The Good, the Evil, and Organizational Differences
Corporate Psychopaths: The Good, the Evil, and Organizational DifferencesCorporate Psychopaths: The Good, the Evil, and Organizational Differences
Corporate Psychopaths: The Good, the Evil, and Organizational Differences
 
Transformational Leadership, Servant Leadership, and Psychological Needs
Transformational Leadership, Servant Leadership, and Psychological NeedsTransformational Leadership, Servant Leadership, and Psychological Needs
Transformational Leadership, Servant Leadership, and Psychological Needs
 
Leadership and Organizational Function
Leadership and Organizational FunctionLeadership and Organizational Function
Leadership and Organizational Function
 
Review of Andrew J. Bacevich's The New American Militarism - How Americans ar...
Review of Andrew J. Bacevich's The New American Militarism - How Americans ar...Review of Andrew J. Bacevich's The New American Militarism - How Americans ar...
Review of Andrew J. Bacevich's The New American Militarism - How Americans ar...
 
Review of 2 Journal Articles on Psychological Factors Influencing Capital Pun...
Review of 2 Journal Articles on Psychological Factors Influencing Capital Pun...Review of 2 Journal Articles on Psychological Factors Influencing Capital Pun...
Review of 2 Journal Articles on Psychological Factors Influencing Capital Pun...
 
Premenstrual Syndrome (PMS)
Premenstrual Syndrome (PMS)Premenstrual Syndrome (PMS)
Premenstrual Syndrome (PMS)
 
NASA and the Space Shuttle Program
NASA and the Space Shuttle ProgramNASA and the Space Shuttle Program
NASA and the Space Shuttle Program
 
NASA - The Quest for the Moon
NASA - The Quest for the MoonNASA - The Quest for the Moon
NASA - The Quest for the Moon
 
Canada, and the US Ballistic Missile Defence Program
Canada, and the US Ballistic Missile Defence ProgramCanada, and the US Ballistic Missile Defence Program
Canada, and the US Ballistic Missile Defence Program
 
Barriers to International Cooperation
Barriers to International CooperationBarriers to International Cooperation
Barriers to International Cooperation
 
Econometric Military Production Function
Econometric Military Production FunctionEconometric Military Production Function
Econometric Military Production Function
 
Separatism in Quebec
Separatism in QuebecSeparatism in Quebec
Separatism in Quebec
 
Canada’s Commitment to Tolerance, Democracy, and the Rule of Law
Canada’s Commitment to Tolerance, Democracy, and the Rule of LawCanada’s Commitment to Tolerance, Democracy, and the Rule of Law
Canada’s Commitment to Tolerance, Democracy, and the Rule of Law
 
Transnational Terrorism vs Local Terrorism
Transnational Terrorism vs Local TerrorismTransnational Terrorism vs Local Terrorism
Transnational Terrorism vs Local Terrorism
 
The Relationship between the USA and China/North Vietnam/USSR, in light of th...
The Relationship between the USA and China/North Vietnam/USSR, in light of th...The Relationship between the USA and China/North Vietnam/USSR, in light of th...
The Relationship between the USA and China/North Vietnam/USSR, in light of th...
 
Military Robots and Canadian Defence and Foreign Policy
Military Robots and Canadian Defence and Foreign PolicyMilitary Robots and Canadian Defence and Foreign Policy
Military Robots and Canadian Defence and Foreign Policy
 
Political Economy of UAVs, and Cost-Benefit Analysis and Optimization of UAV ...
Political Economy of UAVs, and Cost-Benefit Analysis and Optimization of UAV ...Political Economy of UAVs, and Cost-Benefit Analysis and Optimization of UAV ...
Political Economy of UAVs, and Cost-Benefit Analysis and Optimization of UAV ...
 

The Benefits of Canadian Food Aid Policy to the Canadian Economy

  • 1. Interdisciplinary, unpaid research opportunities are available. Various academic specialties are required. If interested, email me at dr.freedom@hotmail.ca. The Benefits of Canadian Food Aid Policy to the Canadian Economy By Oleg Nekrassovski Tied aid involves a developed country giving a loan or a grant to a developing country while dictating where in the world they should buy what they need with that money. This generally amounts to the recipient country being told to spend the given money in the donor country (i.e. on the goods and services produced by that country) (Tied aid, n.d.). Untied aid, on the other hand, involves a similar transaction between a developed and a developing country, with the main difference being that the developing country can spend the received money anywhere it wants (Untied aid, n.d.). The present paper, however, will focus neither on the tied food aid nor on the untied food aid. Instead, it will focus on the direct, free transfer of food produced in Canada, to the countries in need. And it will argue that such food aid is highly beneficial to Canadian economy in various ways. Most experts agree that surplus disposal and addition of value to Canadian food products are the two key potential benefits of Canadian food aid policy to Canadian economy (Charlton, 1992). Surplus disposal involves reducing excess inventories of locally produced food products by sending them off as foreign aid (Charlton, 1992). The surplus food produce, of course, does not get shipped off without any compensation to its producers; otherwise there would be no benefit to the Canadian economy. Instead, a federal government agency, such as the Canadian International Development Agency (CIDA), purchases the surplus food produce from its producers at a mutually agreed upon price, which is seldom equal to the lowest one on the world market (Charlton, 1992).
  • 2. Interdisciplinary, unpaid research opportunities are available. Various academic specialties are required. If interested, email me at dr.freedom@hotmail.ca. Canadian economy can benefit from surplus disposal in at least two ways. First, the handling and storage of excess inventories carries considerable costs, which are significantly reduced by early disposal of the surplus (Charlton, 1992). In fact, there are many unnecessary costs, which are incurred by the carrying of excess inventory. Every item kept in stock must be financed by its interest or opportunity cost, which amounts to between 10% and 15% of the item’s value. Moving items in and out of facilities incurs its own costs; as does storing them in a rented space (Sahin & Robinson, 2007). And even if the storage space is owned rather than rented, a considerable opportunity cost may be incurred by using this space to store excess inventory, if the same space can be used for another, more productive activity (Sahin & Robinson, 2007). Also, taxes must be paid on all inventory assets. While insurance is also usually paid for all types of stock. Finally, inventory shrinkage also has its costs. Shrinkage occurs due to pilferage, obsolescence, or deterioration (Sahin & Robinson, 2007). In the case of food produce, deterioration is doubtlessly a major cause of inventory shrinkage. Second, large surpluses have a depressive effect on the markets of food products. Surplus disposal, not surprisingly, greatly reduces this depressive effect (Charlton, 1992). In fact, a surplus of food produce on the Canadian market means that the supplied quantity of food produce is greater than optimal, i.e. above that required to achieve the equilibrium price. Moreover, the increase in the quantity of any commodity on the market means a decrease in the quantity of it demanded by the customers (McConnell et al., 2002). Since, the equilibrium point is the only point at which the quantity supplied is equal to the quantity demanded, under surplus conditions the quantity supplied at a price acceptable to the producer, is considerably greater than the quantity demanded, at that price, by the consumers. Consequently, under surplus conditions, the producers cannot sell a large quantity of their produce at a price acceptable to
  • 3. Interdisciplinary, unpaid research opportunities are available. Various academic specialties are required. If interested, email me at dr.freedom@hotmail.ca. them (McConnell et al., 2002). On the other hand, if they are determined to sell all of their produce (because, for example, it will simply rot and become worthless if they don’t), they have to considerably lower the prices in order to cause the quantity demanded to increase. Thus, the existence of the surplus in the food market, while having no effect on the consumers (as they always get as much or as little as they want depending on the price), greatly harms the food producers (McConnell et al., 2002). This is why surpluses are said to ‘depress’ the markets and harm the economy. In order to be effective, however, the disposal of surplus food products should be correctly matched with eternally changing market conditions. During the late sixties, for example, the disposal of surplus wheat was a primary objective of Canadian food aid policy (Charlton, 1992). On the other hand, during the boom years of the seventies the shipping of surplus wheat as foreign aid became uneconomic, because during those years the Canadian farmers had no trouble selling all of their surplus wheat to other countries. Consequently, the boom years of the seventies saw a shift in Canadian food aid exports from wheat to products like fish, dried eggs, canned meat, and milk powder (Charlton, 1992). The value added to Canadian food produce by processing it, is another economic benefit of Canadian food aid policy (Charlton, 1992). Value added is the market value of the product sold by a firm minus the value of the inputs that the firm has purchased and used to produce that product. Value added to every product is paid out as wages, rent, interest, and profit by the firm that produced it (McConnell et al., 2002). Consequently, the shipping of flour instead of wheat, for example, causes an addition of value to wheat through its processing into flour and a resulting input of wages, rents, interests, and profits into the Canadian economy. Moreover, the
  • 4. Interdisciplinary, unpaid research opportunities are available. Various academic specialties are required. If interested, email me at dr.freedom@hotmail.ca. processing of various food products leads to an increase in the utilization of the existing productive capacity of the industry that processes these products (Charlton, 1992). In its most basic conception, “capacity” is an aspect of output, which is directly proportional to the changes in capital stock over the long-run. Capacity is measured in various ways, and it is useful to split it into two categories of “engineering” and “economic” capacity. Engineering capacity is the maximum production level which can be sustained over a certain interval of time. While economic capacity is the desired production level (Shaikh & Moudud, 2004). For example, it may be possible, for a certain flour-milling plant, to mill three thousand tons into flour in one week. But it may turn out that the higher costs of milling the second and third ton, due to extra maintenance requirements, higher wages for night workers, etc., make the milling of only one ton per week, most profitable. Hence, economic capacity constitutes an optimal level of output (Shaikh & Moudud, 2004). A persistent production below economic capacity indicates the need to slowdown the planned capacity growth, while that persistently above it indicates that the planned capacity growth can be accelerated (Kurz, 1986). Thus, an increase in demand for processed foods, leads to increased output of the food processing plants, and an increase in their capacity growth. Moreover, over the short-run, changes in output are thought to correlate with changes in employment. Thus, in the short-run, an increase in capacity utilization rate (the ratio of output to capacity) will likely see a collateral increase in the employment rate (the ratio of employment to labour supply), which is unquestionably beneficial to the economy of any country (Shaikh & Moudud, 2004). The increase in demand on canola oil and wheat flour, caused by using them as food aid, has greatly benefited the flour-milling and canola oilseed crushing industries, which previously experienced chronically low levels of capacity utilization in their facilities (Charlton, 1992).
  • 5. Interdisciplinary, unpaid research opportunities are available. Various academic specialties are required. If interested, email me at dr.freedom@hotmail.ca. Aside from surplus disposal and the addition of value to Canadian food products, there are other, though lesser, benefits of Canadian food aid policy to the Canadian economy. The foremost among them is market development. Market development with respect to food aid generally works through the shipping as food aid of a certain type of Canadian food produce to recipient countries unfamiliar with this type of food (Charlton, 1992). The result is that the recipients get thoroughly familiarized with the quality of these Canadian food products and end up developing a taste for them. Once that happens and once the short-term famines, in the recipient countries, are over, the former food aid recipients start to be treated as full paying customers (Charlton, 1992). Food aid has also been used by Canadian political leaders to obtain and/or seal trade agreements with other countries, once again to the benefit of the Canadian economy. For example, in 1977 Colombia signed an important trade agreement with Canada, which may not have taken place if Canada had not also offered to sign another agreement with Colombia which stated that Canada will donate to Colombia 1800 tons of skim milk powder (Charlton, 1992).
  • 6. Interdisciplinary, unpaid research opportunities are available. Various academic specialties are required. If interested, email me at dr.freedom@hotmail.ca. References Charlton, M. W. (1992). The making of Canadian food aid policy. Montreal: McGill-Queen’s University Press. Kurz, H. (1986). Normal positions and capital utilization. Political Economy: Studies in the Surplus Approach, 2(1), 37-54. McConnell, C. R., Brue, S. L., & Barbiero, T. P. (2002). Macroeconomics. Toronto: McGraw- Hill Ryerson. Sahin, F., & Robinson, E. P. Jr. (2007). Inventory management. In J. T. Mentzer, M. B. Myers, & T. P. Stank (Eds.), Handbook of global supply chain management (pp. 185-201). Thousand Oaks, California: Sage Publications, Inc. Shaikh, A. M., & Moudud, J. K. (2004). Measuring capacity utilization in OECD countries: A cointegration method. The Levy Economics Institute Working Paper Collection, 415. Retrieved from http://homepage.newschool.edu/~AShaikh/measuring%20capacity.pdf Tied aid. (n.d.). Retrieved November 30, 2011 from Wikipedia: http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Tied_aid Untied aid. (n.d.). Retrieved November 30, 2011 from Wikipedia: http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Untied_aid