SlideShare une entreprise Scribd logo
1  sur  28
AN INTRODUCTION TO THE DODD-FRANK ACT:
      Congress Addresses Systemic Risk
                John C. Coffee, Jr.
          Adolf A. Berle Professor of Law
              Columbia Law School
                   June 7, 2012
         Second Circuit Judicial Conference




             The Boom/Bust Cycle              Slide 1
I. Unlike Most Securities Reform Legislation (Which
   Principally Addresses Investor Protection and Disclosure
   Issues), the Dodd-Frank Act chiefly addresses systemic
   risk. Thus, the inevitable question is: What Do We Mean
   By Systemic Risk?
II. Although There Is No Universally Accepted Definition, the
    Core Idea Is That Because of Interconnections A Local
    Crisis Can Become a Global Crisis, Causing In Effect A
    Cascade of Falling Financial Dominoes
III. We Saw Systemic Risk Produce a World-Wide Crisis in
     2008 When a Localized Problem In the U.S. Subprime
     Mortgage Market Paralyzed the World’s Financial Markets
     Because Asset-Backed Securitizations and Derivatives
     Had Knitted Together the World’s Financial Institutions In
     a Web of Interdependency
                                                           Slide 2
Systemic Risk Has Three Faces:
(1) A Financial Institution Can Be Too Big to Fail (Lehman
    Wasn’t, But Citigroup Probably Is).
(2) A Financial Institution Can Be Too Interconnected to Fail
    Because Many Institutions Are Its Counterparties (AIG is
    the paradigm as it tied together many institutions through
    credit default swaps)
(3) Financial Institutions Can Be Too Risk Correlated to Fail
    (Because the Prospective Failure of One Causes Prices to
    Fall In a Market In Which Many Have Invested) For
    example, if Bear Stearns desperately needs to liquidate its
    portfolio of CDOs to avoid insolvency, its sales drive down
    prices in a thin market and forces larger TBTF institutions to
    mark down or liquidate similar investments. Market
    pressures and globalization have probably increased the
    level of risk correlation over the last decade.
                                                              Slide 3
I.    WHAT CAUSED THE 2008 CRISIS?
      Why did all major financial institutions seemingly become insolvent at once?
II.   FOUR CREDIBLE SCENARIOS EXIST:
      A.   The Moral Hazard Story: “Executive Compensation Caused the Crash.” Here, the
           claim is that a rapid shift toward incentive-based compensation at financial
           institutions focused senior managers on short-term results. For example, if you can
           make $100 million in Year 1 if a sufficient number of securitization deals close,
           why worry about what happens to those deals in Year 5?
      B.   The Perverse Subsidy Story: Because Creditors Believed that “Too Big to Fail
           Banks” (“TBTF”) Would Always Be Bailed Out, They Advanced Too Much Credit
           and Too Cheaply. Because of this perception, TBTF banks received an implicit
           subsidy, as investors lent too cheaply. Exploiting this subsidy, financial institutions
           took on excessive leverage (often under shareholder pressure to do so).
      C.   Bounded Rationality: The Industry and Regulators Are Subject to The Same
           Cognitive Limitations. For example, no one truly understood the risk potential in
           Credit Default Swaps. Both in the case of AIG (and more recently in the case of
           MF Global), the potential for a “run on the bank” through margin calls was not
           adequately recognized.
      D.   “Shadow Banking” Was Exempt From The Regulatory Scrutiny That Applied to
           Traditional Banks. This disparity caused the crisis to begin at investment banks.


                                                                                             Slide 4
What Prescriptions Follow From These Diagnoses?
A.   If “Excessive” or “Short-Term” Executive Compensation is the Problem,
     Then the Following Responses Seem Relevant:
              1) Regulatory Controls on Compensation at Large Financial
                 Institutions
              2) Mandatory Deferral of Bonuses
              3) Clawbacks
              4) Corporate Governance Reforms Giving Shareholders
                 Greater Power (“Say on Pay” Votes and “Access to the
                 Proxy Statement”).
B.   If an Implicit Subsidy Based on Expectations of a Bailout is the Problem,
     Then The Following Reforms Seem Responsive:
              1) Restrict Banking Regulators from Making Bailouts
              2) Resolution Authority (an expedited procedure for liquidating
                  failing TBTF institutions prior to insolvency without the use
                            of bankruptcy)
              3) Higher Capital Adequacy Standards
              4) Mandatory or Permissive Use of Contingent Capital


                                                                         Slide 5
C. If Panic and Cognitive Failures Are the Key Problem (as in AIG),
   Then Policymakers Might Consider:
            1) Mandating the Use of Clearinghouses and Exchanges in
               the OTC Derivatives Market
            2) Restrict Risk-Taking by TBTF Banks by Proscribing
               Certain Higher Risk Activities (i.e. the “Volcker Rule”)

D. To the Extent “Shadow Banking” Was Exempt from Prudential
   Oversight, Then Appropriate Reforms Would Include:
          1) A Centralized Systemic Risk Oversight Body
          2) Ending the Exemptions for OTC Derivatives
          3) Subjecting Hedge Funds to Regulation
          4) Closer Regulation of Credit Rating Agencies

As Will Next Be Seen Dodd-Frank Attempts All of the Above —
Incompletely and In Broad Brushstrokes




                                                                      Slide 6
The New Financial Architecture

1. Although the U.S. has the most fragmented system of financial regulation in the
   developed world, with a different regulator for each class of investments,
   Dodd-Frank did little to change this:
     1. The SEC and CFTC were not merged.
     2. Only the unlamented Office of Thrift Supervision was terminated.
     3. But new agencies were created (e.g., Consumer Protection).
2. The major new player is the Financial Stability Oversight Council (“FSOC”), which is
   intended to monitor systemic risk. (See Sections 111 to 121 of Dodd-Frank). It has
   ten voting members (consisting primarily of the chairs of the major financial
   regulators), is chaired by the Secretary of the Treasury, and five non-voting members
   (e.g., the Director of the Office of Financial Research, the Director of the Federal
   Insurance Office, and several representatives of state financial regulators).
3. The FSOC’s purposes are (1) “to identify risks to the financial stability of the United
   States that could arise from the material financial distress or failure or ongoing
   activities of large, inter-connected” financial institutions; (2) “to provide market
   discipline, by eliminating expectations . . . that the Government will shield [institutions
   and creditors] from losses in the event of failure”; and (3) “to respond to emerging
   threats to the stability of the U.S. financial system” (Section 111(a) ).

                                                                                   Slide 7
1. In overview, the FSOC is a beefed-up successor to the President’s Working Group,
   with a significantly enhanced research capacity, but only limited powers. Its powers
   are largely advisory or limited to information gathering, except that it may determine
   by a 2/3’s vote (which majority must include the Secretary of the Treasury) that a
   U.S. nonbank financial company (or a foreign nonbank financial company) is to be
   supervised by the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve and subjected to the
   latter’s prudential standards if the FSOC finds that the institution’s activities “could
   pose a threat to the financial stability of the United States” (Section 113(a)).
2. This means that the FSOC could determine that certain insurance companies, broker
   dealers, mutual fund managers (e.g., Fidelity), hedge funds (e.g., Citadel), or
   industrial companies (e.g., GE) should be subject to the same standards of capital
   adequacy, leverage and risk-taking as a major bank holding company is.
3. The FSOC has recently specified the criteria (and some of the procedures) that it will
   use in determining which nonbank financial institutions are systemically significant,
   but has not yet acted to designate any institution as systemically significant.
4. When it does, there will predictably be appeals that will reach the courts.
5. Evaluation: The FSOC emerged from Dodd-Frank a slightly weaker body than
   originally intended. Had it been given an independent chair, it would have been led
   by an independent and politically accountable figure with exclusive responsibility for
   systemic risk. Instead, the Secretary of the Treasury has multiple responsibilities and
   must balance financial stability against economic growth and political consensus.

                                                                                  Slide 8
The End of the Central Bank As Lender of Last Resort?

     1. Dodd-Frank Restricts the Power of the Federal Reserve to advance funds to a failing TBTF
        bank.
     2. Specifically, Section 1101(a)(6) of Dodd-Frank eliminates the Federal Reserve Board’s
        former authority under Section 13(3) of the Federal Reserve Act to make emergency loans
        to a failing bank. Now, the FRB can no longer lend to a single firm but can only make
        emergency loans “for the purpose of providing liquidity to the financial system, and not to a
        failing financial company.” Such lending must be pursuant to a “program or facility with
        broad-based eligibility” and must be adequately collateralized in a manner that “is sufficient
        to protect taxpayers from losses.”
     3. Clearly, neither Lehman nor AIG could have met this standard. Indeed, Section 1101(a)(6)
        expressly denies the FRB the power to make loans under its emergency lending authority
        “for the purpose of assisting a single and specific company to avoid bankruptcy [or]
        resolution authority under Title II” of the Dodd-Frank Act.
     4. Similarly, Section 212 (“No Other Funding”) bars the FDIC from lending to TBTF banks
        outside of a Title II receivership. The language is clear that the FDIC can lend to, or
        guarantee debts of, the institution only once the financial institution has entered liquidation
        and is being wound down.

Bottom Line: The intent of Dodd-Frank is to end the Central Bank As Lender of Last Resort to
Failing TBTF Banks because bailouts have become politically unacceptable. The FRB may
find ways to avoid this proscription, but its hands are significantly tied and it will have to face
Congress, and maybe the courts, if it seeks to outflank these provisions.

                                                                                            Slide 9
Resolution Authority
1. In place of Central Bank lending to avert a banking crisis, Dodd-Frank intends to
   substitute “resolution authority,” which is largely modelled after the procedures the
   FDIC has used to liquidate smaller banks outside of bankruptcy.
2. Although expeditious liquidation of a systemically significant financial institution is
   clearly desirable (and the Lehman bankruptcy shows that liquidation under the
   Bankruptcy Code is interminable), the problem with Title II (“Orderly Liquidation
   Authority”) of Dodd-Frank is that it requires a very high level of consensus among
   financial regulators to begin the process and then subjects their determination to a
   uniquely truncated form of judicial review.
3. To illustrate, let’s suppose that a major bank is in trouble (the procedures are
   different for a broker-dealer or insurance company). What happens? Sections 203
   and 202 of Dodd-Frank outline the following procedures:
          Step One. On their own initiative (or at the request of the Secretary of the Treasury),
          the FDIC and the FRB determine to request the Secretary to appoint the FDIC as
          receiver for this financial institution — by not less than a two-thirds vote of each of
          the FRB Governors and the FDIC board of directors. (If the troubled institution is a
          broker, 2/3s of the SEC’s five Commissioners must also approve — i.e., four
          Commissioners).
          Step Two. The FRB and the FDIC submit an elaborate report to the Secretary,
          containing the findings specified in Section 203(a)(2) of Dodd-Frank, which must
          describe the effect of the default upon the financial stability of the U.S. and the
          likelihood of any “private sector alternative.”
                                                                                      Slide 10
Step Three. The Secretary, in consultation with the President, must determine
         that the financial company is in “danger of default,” which term is elaborately
         defined in Section 203(c)(4). Under Section 203(b), the Secretary must make a
         total of seven overlapping findings, including the “danger of default” finding.
         Step Four. The Secretary notifies the “covered financial company” that it
         intends to appoint the FDIC as receiver. If the company does not consent, the
         Secretary must petition the United States District Court for the District of
         Columbia for an order authorizing the Secretary to so appoint the FDIC as
         receiver. The Court must determine if the Secretary’s decision is “arbitrary and
         capricious” after a hearing, but under Section 202(a)(1)(v), if “the Court does
         not make a determination within 24 hours of receipt of the petition, . . . the
         petition shall be granted by operation of law.”
         Step Five. An appeal may be taken to the D.C. Circuit within 30 days, and the
         D.C. Circuit “shall consider any appeal . . . on an expedited basis.” A petition
         for a writ of certiorari to the Supreme Court is also authorized, and the Court is
         instructed to “consider any petition on an expedited basis.” However, the scope
         of the Court’s review “shall be limited to whether the determination of the
         Secretary that the covered financial company is in default or in danger of
         default (and is within the statute’s coverage) . . . is arbitrary and capricious.”
         (Section 202(a)(2)(iv). (This seems to eliminate judicial review of five of the
         seven findings that the Secretary must make).
1. Some law professors have already suggested that this procedure is constitutionally
   suspect.
                                                                                Slide 11
1. More importantly, these are determinations that no Secretary of the Treasury (or President) will
   want to make as liquidation will suggest a failure of adequate supervision on their watch. An
   immediate report must also be provided to Congress, where the opposition party will eagerly
   second guess the Secretary. A possibility exists that any such liquidation may trigger a financial
   panic (as Lehman’s bankruptcy did).
2. Bottom Line: Although “resolution authority” contemplates an early intervention and early
   liquidation of a TBTF institution, this is unrealistic, and the odds are high that financial regulators
   will prefer to “kick the can down the road” and hope for the best — until actual insolvency
   occurs.
3. As a result, if (1) the FRB and FDIC cannot advance funds to a major financial institution facing
   a liquidity crisis and (2) the Government will be reluctant to liquidate early,
   Dodd-Frank may have painted the U.S. financial system into the proverbial corner where
   nothing can or will be done.
4. If “orderly liquidation” under Title II is in fact ordered, Section 204(a) of Dodd-Frank mandates
   that (1) “creditors and shareholders will bear the losses,” (2) “management will not be retained,”
   and (3) all parties “having responsibility for the condition of the financial company will bear
   losses consistent with their responsibility.” This sounds retributive, and Section 210(f) authorizes
   the FDIC, as receiver, to sue officers and directors of a failed financial company for gross
   negligence. (It is unclear whether corporate charter provisions eliminating monetary liability for
   breach of the duty of care will be respected — See Delaware §102(b)(7)).
5. A Final Irony. The FDIC is authorized to makes loans to, and purchase debt obligations of, a
   covered financial company placed in Title II liquidation. As a result, creditors may still be spared.
   (See Section 204(d)). The most likely procedure will involve the FDIC creating a “bridge
   company” to buy the assets of the failed company by paying off the creditors. If the FDIC
   decides to pay off debt holders in full, the same expectation of a bailout may persist, and the
   perverse subsidy may survive. But the FDIC’s funds are limited, and it probably cannot bailout
   an AIG alone.
                                                                                              Slide 12
EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION

1. Given the strong perception that incentive compensation can produce “short termism”
   and moral hazard, Dodd-Frank takes two divergent and possibly contradictory routes
   to cure this problem:

         A. It federalizes some aspects of corporate governance in order to give
            shareholders greater power; and
         B. In Section 956, it authorizes regulators to prohibit excessive incentive-band
            compensation at “covered financial institutions” that “could lead to material
            financial loss.”

1. Overview: There is much evidence that the more closely the incentives of senior
   executives were aligned with those of shareholders, the worse the financial institution
   did in 2008! Banks with “shareholder friendly” corporate governance performed more
   poorly than banks with “unfriendly” corporate governance.
2. Bottom Line: Empowering shareholders may not be the answer, but instead may be
   part of the problem, in terms of systemic risk. Shareholders appear to push managers
   to accept higher risk.



                                                                                Slide 13
The Corporate Governance Prong

1. Section 971 authorized, but did not mandate, the SEC to adopt “proxy access” — a
   corporate governance reform that it had previously proposed, but never adopted.
   Other provisions mandated advisory shareholder votes on executive compensation
   (Section 951), required additional disclosures on CEO compensation (Section 953),
   required compensation committee independence (Section 952), and eliminated
   “broker votes” in director elections (Section 957).
2. Pursuant to this authority, the SEC adopted Rule 14a-11 (the proxy access rule)
   permitting low cost proxy contests to elect 1, 2, or at most 3 directors by investors
   holding 3% if they were not seeking control.
3. The Business Roundtable and the Chamber of Commerce sued to invalidate the rule
   on the grounds that the SEC had not done an adequate cost/benefit analysis – and
   won (Business Roundtable v. SEC, 647 F.3d 1144 (D.C. Cir. 2011)). The D.C. Circuit
   found that the lack of an adequate cost/benefit study made the rule arbitrary and
   capricious; it particularly emphasized the SEC’s failure to consider the costs that
   corporations would incur in resisting “proxy access” in its cost/benefit calculus.




                                                                                 Slide 14
IMPACT

1. Far more than earlier statutes (such as SOX), Dodd-Frank relies on administrative
   implementation through risk-making.
2. That process is seriously behind.
3. As of June 1, 2012, a total of 221 Dodd-Frank rulemaking deadlines have passed,
   and 148 (or 67.0%) have been missed, while only 73 (33.0%) have been met with
   finalized rules (Source: DavisPolk Progress Report 6/1/2012).
4. Multiple factors may explain this slowness, but the Business Roundtable decision
   appears to have traumatized the SEC, which may lack the resources or capacity to
   engage in cost/benefit analysis that will satisfy the D.C. Circuit
5. Highly Debatable Policy Issue: Can Cost/Benefit Analysis Be Used to Return Us to a
   Lochner-like era in which regulation is presumptively disfavored?




                                                                             Slide 15
The Paternalistic Prong

1. Section 956 (“Enhanced Compensation Structure Reporting”) instructs Federal
   regulators to jointly prescribe regulations requiring “covered financial institutions” to
   disclose “the structure of all incentive-based compensation arrangements offered by
   such covered financial institutions sufficient to determine whether the compensation
   structure —

          A. provides an executive officer, employee, director, or principal shareholder
             with excessive compensation, fees, or benefits, or
          B. could lead to material financial loss to the covered financial institution . . .”


1. Section 956(b) then authorizes federal regulators to bar “any type of incentive-based
   payment arrangement that . . . encourages inappropriate risks by covered financial
   institutions. . . .”
2. The initial issue was how broadly to read this disclosure obligation. Although it was
   clear that individual identities were not to be disclosed, this language could have
   been read to require disclosure of aggregate incentive compensation paid to
   executives and its distribution.



                                                                                     Slide 16
1.   This is exactly what then New York Attorney General Cuomo required in 2009 when he published the
         following chart:

                      2008 Bonus Compensation at Selected Financial Institutions of
                                                              No. of          No.
                                                                              Employees        Employees
                                                                              Receiving        Receiving
                                                                              Bonus ≥ $3       Bonus ≥ $1
    Institution                    Earnings / (Losses)   Bonus Pool           million          million
    Bank of America                $4 billion            $3.3 billion                28             172

    Citigroup, Inc.                $(27.7 billion)       $5.33 billion              124             738

    Goldman Sachs Group            $2.322 billion        $4.823 billion             212             953

    J.P. Morgan Chase & Co.        $5.6 billion          $8.693 billion            >200             1,626

    Merrill Lynch                  $(27.6 billion)       $3.6 billion               149             696

    Morgan Stanley                 $1.707 billion        $4.475 billion             101             428

    1.   As the above chart makes clear, even when financial institutions lost billions, they still paid out bonuses
         totaling in the billions to hundreds of employees (see Citigroup and Merrill Lynch in the above chart).
    2.   When the firm did profit, the bonus pool was often a multiple of earnings (see Goldman, J.P. Morgan,
         and Morgan Stanley’s in the above chart).
    3.   Practices varied, thus making firm-specific disclosure more important. At Merrill Lynch, 14 employees
         received over $10 million in bonuses in 2008; 10 at J.P. Morgan Chase; but only 3 at Citigroup.
BOTTOM LINE: THE BONUS CULTURE HAS DEEP ROOTS.

                                                                                                       Slide 17
What Happened to Section 956?

1.   Section 956 will not produce anything like the foregoing disclosures. This is
     because, notwithstanding its broad statutory language, the industry has already
     won this battle — and on several levels.
2.   First, rather than requiring quantitative disclosures relating to executive
     compensation, federal regulators have required only an annual report that
     “describes the structure of the covered financial institution’s incentive-based
     compensation arrangements . . . that is sufficient to allow an assessment” of
     whether those arrangements could lead to “excessive compensation.” This
     compromise means no numbers need be disclosed, and boilerplate will suffice.
3.   Second, although more was required in the case of very large TBTF banks with
     $50 billion in assets or more, it was left to the board of each such TBTF
     institution to decide who (other than its executive officers) had the ability to
     expose the institution to substantial losses. In short, regulators decided to let
     each firm determine for itself who could expose the firm to substantial loss.




                                                                             Slide 18
What Is Going On Here?
 2.   Under this rule, a TBTF bank could employ a 100 or more persons, each
      receiving a bonus of well over $1 million, and still disclose nothing – so long
      as the employees were not executives and did not occupy a position that the
      board detrmined could cause it a substantial loss.
 3.   Third, although the rules require a deferral of at least 50% of the annual
      incentive-based compensation paid to senior executives for a period of at
      least three years, they require no deferral even in the case of those other
      persons that the board does identify as being able to cause substantial loss to
      the firm.

Bottom line:
(2) No quantitative aggregate disclosures are required.
(3) Each institution decides for itself who could cause it a substantial loss and discloses
    only its general arrangements in those cases.
(4) No deferral for even those persons (other than executives) who a TBTF institution
    acknowledges could cause it loss.
What Explains This?

                                                                                 Slide 19
1.   The most plausible answer is that the industry did not want the executive
     compensation rules to apply to its “star” traders.
2.   If the rules required disclosure and deferral of bonus compensation in their
     case, the industry likely feared a migration of these traders from TBTF banks
     to hedge funds or offshore institutions.
3.   But “star” traders are exactly the persons who can cause substantial losses to
     financial institutions: Witness Nicholas Leeson at Barings in 1995 and
     Jerome Kerveil at Societe Generale.
4.   Bottom Line: The executive compensation rules have been hollowed out by
     the regulators to protect TBTF banks from competitive injury.



Irony:    A General Counsel at such a bank will have to
defer his incentive compensation for 3 years (although he
is innocuous in terms of the bank’s solvency), but the star
trader betting billions each week will not.




                                                                             Slide 20
CLAWBACKS


1. Section 954 of Dodd-Frank vastly expands the scope of mandatory clawbacks
   beyond that originally provided in Sarbanes-Oxley (“SOX”).
2. While SOX required recovery of incentive-based bonuses from the CEO and
   CFO, Dodd-Frank specifies that the “issuer will recover from any current or
   former executive officer of the issuer who received incentive-based
   compensation (including stock options awarded as compensation) during the 3-
   year period preceding the date on which the issuer is required to prepare an
   accounting restatement based on the erroneous data in excess of what would
   have been paid to the executive office under the accounting restatement.”
3. Still, there must be “an accounting restatement due to the material
   noncompliance of the issuer with any financial reporting requirement under the
   securities laws.” Thus, a bonus paid to the “London Whale” would not be
   recoverable if no restatement were necessary.
4. No enforcement mechanism is provided. To date, clawbacks have been
   primarily enforced by the SEC (although a derivative action is possible if
   demand can be excused).



                                                                           Slide 21
Restricting Risk-Taking

1. If some financial institutions are “too big to fail,” it follows that they need to be
   regulated so that they do not fail.
2. The leading attempt made by Dodd-Frank toward this end is Section 619
   (“Prohibitions on Proprietary Trading And Certain Relationships With Hedge Funds
   and Private Equity Funds”). Known as the “Volcker Rule,” this provision has touched
   off the largest lobbying campaign in modern financial history.
3. Section 619 (which amends the Bank Holding Company Act) starts with broad
   prohibitions:
               “Unless otherwise provided in this section, a banking entity shall not —
                        A. engage in proprietary trading, or
                        B. acquire or retain any equity, partnership, or other
                           ownership interest in or sponsor a hedge fund or a
                           private equity fund.”




                                                                                      Slide 22
Exemptions

    1. Some ambiguous exemptions, however, may undercut the scope of § 619. Section
       13(d)(1)(C) of the amended Bank Holding Company Act (“BHCA”) permits:
                  “Risk-mitigating hedging activities in connection with and related to
                  individual or aggregated positions, contracts, or other holdings of a
                  banking entity that are designed to reduce the specific risks to the banking
                  entity in connection with and related to such positions, contracts or other
                  holdings.”

Does this authorize the type of “portfolio hedging” engaged in by JPMorgan’s “London
Whale”? Although the above statutory language seems narrow, the proposed rules are
broader, and the answer will lie in the final rules.

    1. Another important exemption is in Section 13(d)(1)(B) of the BHCA for “underwriting
       or market-making activities to the extent that any such activities . . . are designed not
       to exceed the reasonably expected near term demands of dealers, customers or
       counterparties.”




                                                                                      Slide 23
The Lobbying Battle

1. The banking industry wants broad permission to trade sovereign debt. After Greece,
   the failure of MF Global, and JPMorgan’s problems, such trading is no longer self-
   evidently safe, but other European countries, Japan, and Canada have all asked the
   U.S. to permit such trading by U.S. banks.
2. A legal battle will likely arise regarding the extraterritorial scope of Dodd-Frank’s
   Section 619. Can, for example, federal regulators prohibit the London office of U.S.
   banks from engaging in proprietary trading (as in the case of the London Whale)? Or
   does this overlook the presumption against extraterritoriality in Morrison v. Nat’l.
   Australia Bank Ltd., 130 Sup. Ct. 2860?
3. If regulators cannot restrict overseas operations, Section 619 may simply produce a
   migration of traders to offshore offices.
4. The lobbying imbalance is reaching record proportions. A study by Duke Law
   Professor Kimberly Krawiec finds that between July 2010 and October 2011,
   representatives of financial institutions met with federal agencies to discuss the
   Volcker Rule some 351 times, while public interest groups met with regulators some
   19 times over the same period — a better than 18 to 1 ratio.




                                                                              Slide 24
Regulating Over-The-Counter Derivatives
1. AIG’s failure showed the dangers of opacity in a major market.
2. Had counterparties understood the degree to which AIG was serving as the counterparty
   to the entire market of Credit Default Swap users and was thus insuring the entire market
   against financial risk, counterparties might have required that greater collateral and margin
   be posted (or might simply have sought other counterparties).
3. To prevent the default of a single counterparty creating a wave of falling financial
   dominoes, Section 723 of Dodd-Frank mandates the use of clearinghouses (which means
   that each party’s transaction is with a clearinghouse backed by the market) and the use of
   exchanges and “swap execution facilities” (to create greater transparency).
4. But there are numerous exceptions. The most important is the “end user exemption” that is
   now set forth in Section 2(h)(7) of the Commodity Exchange Act, which applies to non-
   financial entities using swaps “to hedge or mitigate commercial risk.” Under it, a United
   Airlines is, for example, exempt so long as it is hedging its own fuel costs. But if it is
   exempt, so also is its counterparty, and thus much trading will remain off market and
   opaque.
5. Additionally, customized swaps need not be cleared through clearinghouses or traded on
   exchanges, and here the definitions in the rules will be critical. How little does it take to
   make a swap “customized” and thus exempt?
6.    New Division of Jurisdiction: Swaps are Covered; SEC has “Security-Based” Swaps
     (defined in Section 761); CFTC, the rest. Registration is required of “swap execution
     facilities,” major dealers and “swap participants.”

                                                                                       Slide 25
Credit Rating Agencies
1. SEC administrative oversight of the credit rating agencies has been tightened,
   but the “issuer pays” model for credit ratings seems likely to persist.
2. The one area where courts will encounter a potentially significant legal change
   is the revised pleading standard in Section 933 (“State of mind in private
   actions”). It provides both that (i) credit ratings shall not qualify for the PSLRA’s
   “safe harbor for forward-looking information” and (ii) the PSLRA’s “strong
   inference of fraud” pleading standard shall not apply to credit ratings. Instead,
          “[I]t shall be sufficient for purposes of pleading any required state of mind
          in relation to such actions that the complaint state with particularity facts
          giving rise to a strong inference that the credit rating agency knowingly or
          recklessly failed —
                  (i) to conduct a reasonable investigation of the rated security with
                      respect to the factual elements relied upon by its own
                      methodology for evaluating credit risk; or
                  (ii) to obtain reasonable verification of such factual elements
                       (which verification may be based on a sampling technique that
                       does not amount to an audit) from other sources that the credit
                       rating agency considered to be competent and that were
                       independent of the issuer and underwriter.”


                                                                               Slide 26
Meaning and Impact

1. Does this language replace the normal scienter standard of Rule 10b-5 with a
   negligence standard? Answer: NO!
2. Instead, it is simply providing a substitute pleading standard for the motion to
   dismiss, which requires plaintiffs to plead a lack of adequate due diligence.
3. The plaintiff who survives the motion to dismiss because of this softened standard
   can obtain discovery, but, by trial or summary judgment, plaintiffs must show
   scienter.
4. For the future, in light of this Circuit’s decision in Fait v. Regions Fin. Corp., 655 F.3d
   105 (2d Cir. 2011), it will likely be necessary for plaintiffs to show not only that a
   rating was inflated but that defendants did not subjectively believe the rating was
   accurate at the time it was published.
5. Credit Rating Agencies commonly assert a First Amendment Defense. In Section
   951, Congress states a finding that “the activities of credit rating agencies are
   fundamentally commercial in character and should be subject to the same standards
   of liability and oversight as apply to auditors, securities analysts, and investment
   bankers.” Will this have any impact?




                                                                                    Slide 27
Summary


1. This tour has not covered many topics, including:
         1. Whistleblowers and bounties;
         2. Asset-Backed Securitizations and mandatory risk retention;
         3. New SEC and SIPC powers;
         4. the Bureau of Consumer Protection (Sections 1011 to 1051);
         5. Hedge fund registration;
         6. “Predatory” Mortgage lending; and
         7. Conflict Minerals.
2. But, more than other “reform” statutes, Dodd-Frank depends on administrative
   implementation. To date, that implementation has been slow and equivocal, and
   early steps have been judicially contested. Nothing suggests that this will change.




                                                                               Slide 28

Contenu connexe

Tendances

Financial regulation
Financial regulationFinancial regulation
Financial regulationNaresh Gautam
 
Summary of Dodd Frank Act from mofo
Summary of Dodd Frank Act from mofoSummary of Dodd Frank Act from mofo
Summary of Dodd Frank Act from mofoSerge Milman
 
Soa chicago2011 10-12-dodd-frank-frings
Soa chicago2011 10-12-dodd-frank-fringsSoa chicago2011 10-12-dodd-frank-frings
Soa chicago2011 10-12-dodd-frank-fringsmfrings
 
Contracts and Systemic Risk in Europe
Contracts and Systemic Risk in EuropeContracts and Systemic Risk in Europe
Contracts and Systemic Risk in EuropeLuca Amorello
 
Dodd frank wall_street_reform_comprehensive_summary_final
Dodd frank wall_street_reform_comprehensive_summary_finalDodd frank wall_street_reform_comprehensive_summary_final
Dodd frank wall_street_reform_comprehensive_summary_finalmberre
 
Banking regulations post-crisis and their effect on SME lending. Robert Carpe...
Banking regulations post-crisis and their effect on SME lending. Robert Carpe...Banking regulations post-crisis and their effect on SME lending. Robert Carpe...
Banking regulations post-crisis and their effect on SME lending. Robert Carpe...EOI Escuela de Organización Industrial
 
Financial Crisis
Financial CrisisFinancial Crisis
Financial Crisisguest530220
 
Basel committee & basel norms
Basel committee & basel normsBasel committee & basel norms
Basel committee & basel normsYasha Singh
 
CLE COURS BANKING LAW FOR GENERAL PRACTITIONER
CLE COURS BANKING LAW FOR GENERAL PRACTITIONERCLE COURS BANKING LAW FOR GENERAL PRACTITIONER
CLE COURS BANKING LAW FOR GENERAL PRACTITIONERMissy Cruz
 
Insolvency law in uae amrita roy chowdhury
Insolvency law in uae amrita roy chowdhuryInsolvency law in uae amrita roy chowdhury
Insolvency law in uae amrita roy chowdhuryamrita roy chowdhury
 
The dodd frank effect on information management
The dodd frank effect on information managementThe dodd frank effect on information management
The dodd frank effect on information managementExterro
 
The dodd frank effect on information management
The dodd frank effect on information managementThe dodd frank effect on information management
The dodd frank effect on information managementExterro
 
The operational & liquidity implications of CCPs
The operational & liquidity implications of CCPsThe operational & liquidity implications of CCPs
The operational & liquidity implications of CCPsJohn Wilson
 
Us banks regulation
Us banks regulation Us banks regulation
Us banks regulation Brenda
 
James Okarimia - The New Margin Requirements For Non Centrally Cleared Deriv...
James Okarimia - The  New Margin Requirements For Non Centrally Cleared Deriv...James Okarimia - The  New Margin Requirements For Non Centrally Cleared Deriv...
James Okarimia - The New Margin Requirements For Non Centrally Cleared Deriv...JAMES OKARIMIA
 
Euromoney - Global Insolvency & Restructuring Review 2013-14
Euromoney - Global Insolvency & Restructuring Review 2013-14Euromoney - Global Insolvency & Restructuring Review 2013-14
Euromoney - Global Insolvency & Restructuring Review 2013-14Anindya Roychowdhury
 

Tendances (19)

Exam i review
Exam i reviewExam i review
Exam i review
 
Financial regulation
Financial regulationFinancial regulation
Financial regulation
 
Summary of Dodd Frank Act from mofo
Summary of Dodd Frank Act from mofoSummary of Dodd Frank Act from mofo
Summary of Dodd Frank Act from mofo
 
Soa chicago2011 10-12-dodd-frank-frings
Soa chicago2011 10-12-dodd-frank-fringsSoa chicago2011 10-12-dodd-frank-frings
Soa chicago2011 10-12-dodd-frank-frings
 
Contracts and Systemic Risk in Europe
Contracts and Systemic Risk in EuropeContracts and Systemic Risk in Europe
Contracts and Systemic Risk in Europe
 
Dodd frank wall_street_reform_comprehensive_summary_final
Dodd frank wall_street_reform_comprehensive_summary_finalDodd frank wall_street_reform_comprehensive_summary_final
Dodd frank wall_street_reform_comprehensive_summary_final
 
Banking regulations post-crisis and their effect on SME lending. Robert Carpe...
Banking regulations post-crisis and their effect on SME lending. Robert Carpe...Banking regulations post-crisis and their effect on SME lending. Robert Carpe...
Banking regulations post-crisis and their effect on SME lending. Robert Carpe...
 
Financial Crisis
Financial CrisisFinancial Crisis
Financial Crisis
 
Basel committee & basel norms
Basel committee & basel normsBasel committee & basel norms
Basel committee & basel norms
 
CLE COURS BANKING LAW FOR GENERAL PRACTITIONER
CLE COURS BANKING LAW FOR GENERAL PRACTITIONERCLE COURS BANKING LAW FOR GENERAL PRACTITIONER
CLE COURS BANKING LAW FOR GENERAL PRACTITIONER
 
"Challenges of financial regulation in the post crisis world"- "Những thách t...
"Challenges of financial regulation in the post crisis world"- "Những thách t..."Challenges of financial regulation in the post crisis world"- "Những thách t...
"Challenges of financial regulation in the post crisis world"- "Những thách t...
 
Insolvency law in uae amrita roy chowdhury
Insolvency law in uae amrita roy chowdhuryInsolvency law in uae amrita roy chowdhury
Insolvency law in uae amrita roy chowdhury
 
The dodd frank effect on information management
The dodd frank effect on information managementThe dodd frank effect on information management
The dodd frank effect on information management
 
The dodd frank effect on information management
The dodd frank effect on information managementThe dodd frank effect on information management
The dodd frank effect on information management
 
The operational & liquidity implications of CCPs
The operational & liquidity implications of CCPsThe operational & liquidity implications of CCPs
The operational & liquidity implications of CCPs
 
Financial inter
Financial interFinancial inter
Financial inter
 
Us banks regulation
Us banks regulation Us banks regulation
Us banks regulation
 
James Okarimia - The New Margin Requirements For Non Centrally Cleared Deriv...
James Okarimia - The  New Margin Requirements For Non Centrally Cleared Deriv...James Okarimia - The  New Margin Requirements For Non Centrally Cleared Deriv...
James Okarimia - The New Margin Requirements For Non Centrally Cleared Deriv...
 
Euromoney - Global Insolvency & Restructuring Review 2013-14
Euromoney - Global Insolvency & Restructuring Review 2013-14Euromoney - Global Insolvency & Restructuring Review 2013-14
Euromoney - Global Insolvency & Restructuring Review 2013-14
 

En vedette

The Real Impact of Say on Pay and a Brief Update from the Dodd-Frank Bill
The Real Impact of Say on Pay and a Brief Update from the Dodd-Frank BillThe Real Impact of Say on Pay and a Brief Update from the Dodd-Frank Bill
The Real Impact of Say on Pay and a Brief Update from the Dodd-Frank BillEdward Hauder
 
Sibos 2012 sessions - Transparency in cross-border payments & the impact of D...
Sibos 2012 sessions - Transparency in cross-border payments & the impact of D...Sibos 2012 sessions - Transparency in cross-border payments & the impact of D...
Sibos 2012 sessions - Transparency in cross-border payments & the impact of D...Earthport
 
Wall Street Reform Act Summary
Wall Street Reform Act SummaryWall Street Reform Act Summary
Wall Street Reform Act SummaryKaren Kay
 
Big Data Analytics for Dodd-Frank
Big Data Analytics for Dodd-FrankBig Data Analytics for Dodd-Frank
Big Data Analytics for Dodd-FrankDataWorks Summit
 
Overview of Dodd Frank Recovery and Resolution Planning
Overview of Dodd Frank Recovery and Resolution PlanningOverview of Dodd Frank Recovery and Resolution Planning
Overview of Dodd Frank Recovery and Resolution PlanningLewis Adams
 
How to adapt to changing regulations in the financial markets worldwide?
How to adapt to changing regulations in the financial markets worldwide? How to adapt to changing regulations in the financial markets worldwide?
How to adapt to changing regulations in the financial markets worldwide? Projectivebiz
 
Orderly Liquidation Authority under Dodd-Frank
Orderly Liquidation Authority under Dodd-FrankOrderly Liquidation Authority under Dodd-Frank
Orderly Liquidation Authority under Dodd-FrankSimon Lacey
 
Dodd frank Uncleared Margin Rules
Dodd frank Uncleared Margin RulesDodd frank Uncleared Margin Rules
Dodd frank Uncleared Margin RulesBilly Gopeesingh
 
Wall Street Reform: Action Items for Compensation (Dodd Frank Act)
Wall Street Reform: Action Items for Compensation (Dodd Frank Act)Wall Street Reform: Action Items for Compensation (Dodd Frank Act)
Wall Street Reform: Action Items for Compensation (Dodd Frank Act)PERFORMENSATION
 
Dodd Frank
Dodd FrankDodd Frank
Dodd Frankgcable
 

En vedette (12)

The Real Impact of Say on Pay and a Brief Update from the Dodd-Frank Bill
The Real Impact of Say on Pay and a Brief Update from the Dodd-Frank BillThe Real Impact of Say on Pay and a Brief Update from the Dodd-Frank Bill
The Real Impact of Say on Pay and a Brief Update from the Dodd-Frank Bill
 
Dodd-Frank Compliance
Dodd-Frank ComplianceDodd-Frank Compliance
Dodd-Frank Compliance
 
Sibos 2012 sessions - Transparency in cross-border payments & the impact of D...
Sibos 2012 sessions - Transparency in cross-border payments & the impact of D...Sibos 2012 sessions - Transparency in cross-border payments & the impact of D...
Sibos 2012 sessions - Transparency in cross-border payments & the impact of D...
 
MHM's Guide to the Dodd-Frank Act
MHM's Guide to the Dodd-Frank ActMHM's Guide to the Dodd-Frank Act
MHM's Guide to the Dodd-Frank Act
 
Wall Street Reform Act Summary
Wall Street Reform Act SummaryWall Street Reform Act Summary
Wall Street Reform Act Summary
 
Big Data Analytics for Dodd-Frank
Big Data Analytics for Dodd-FrankBig Data Analytics for Dodd-Frank
Big Data Analytics for Dodd-Frank
 
Overview of Dodd Frank Recovery and Resolution Planning
Overview of Dodd Frank Recovery and Resolution PlanningOverview of Dodd Frank Recovery and Resolution Planning
Overview of Dodd Frank Recovery and Resolution Planning
 
How to adapt to changing regulations in the financial markets worldwide?
How to adapt to changing regulations in the financial markets worldwide? How to adapt to changing regulations in the financial markets worldwide?
How to adapt to changing regulations in the financial markets worldwide?
 
Orderly Liquidation Authority under Dodd-Frank
Orderly Liquidation Authority under Dodd-FrankOrderly Liquidation Authority under Dodd-Frank
Orderly Liquidation Authority under Dodd-Frank
 
Dodd frank Uncleared Margin Rules
Dodd frank Uncleared Margin RulesDodd frank Uncleared Margin Rules
Dodd frank Uncleared Margin Rules
 
Wall Street Reform: Action Items for Compensation (Dodd Frank Act)
Wall Street Reform: Action Items for Compensation (Dodd Frank Act)Wall Street Reform: Action Items for Compensation (Dodd Frank Act)
Wall Street Reform: Action Items for Compensation (Dodd Frank Act)
 
Dodd Frank
Dodd FrankDodd Frank
Dodd Frank
 

Similaire à Coffee dodd-frank-systemic-risk-cs

Jacobs Dofdd Frank&Basel3 Risk Nov11 11 8 11 V1
Jacobs Dofdd Frank&Basel3 Risk Nov11 11 8 11 V1Jacobs Dofdd Frank&Basel3 Risk Nov11 11 8 11 V1
Jacobs Dofdd Frank&Basel3 Risk Nov11 11 8 11 V1Michael Jacobs, Jr.
 
The Future of Finance
The Future of FinanceThe Future of Finance
The Future of FinanceGaetan Lion
 
The Legal Foundations of Financial Collapse
The Legal Foundations of Financial CollapseThe Legal Foundations of Financial Collapse
The Legal Foundations of Financial CollapseCarolyn Sissoko
 
CAPITAL MARKETS ALERT: How Dodd-Frank and Other New U.S. Laws May Affect Non-...
CAPITAL MARKETS ALERT: How Dodd-Frank and Other New U.S. Laws May Affect Non-...CAPITAL MARKETS ALERT: How Dodd-Frank and Other New U.S. Laws May Affect Non-...
CAPITAL MARKETS ALERT: How Dodd-Frank and Other New U.S. Laws May Affect Non-...Patton Boggs LLP
 
DeFi's dependency on the U.S. banking system
DeFi's dependency on the U.S. banking systemDeFi's dependency on the U.S. banking system
DeFi's dependency on the U.S. banking systemTim Swanson
 
Glossary financial-crisis-terms
Glossary financial-crisis-termsGlossary financial-crisis-terms
Glossary financial-crisis-termsJaspreet2411
 
Loic sarton cds travail
Loic sarton   cds travailLoic sarton   cds travail
Loic sarton cds travailLoic Sarton
 
Patton Boggs Dodd-Frank Reform Analysis
Patton Boggs Dodd-Frank Reform AnalysisPatton Boggs Dodd-Frank Reform Analysis
Patton Boggs Dodd-Frank Reform AnalysisPatton Boggs LLP
 
Final term paper emerging market finance (1)
Final term paper   emerging market finance (1)Final term paper   emerging market finance (1)
Final term paper emerging market finance (1)Lehana Singh
 
Jon terracciano: Hedging the Global Market - Introduction
Jon terracciano: Hedging the Global Market - IntroductionJon terracciano: Hedging the Global Market - Introduction
Jon terracciano: Hedging the Global Market - IntroductionJon Terracciano
 
Risk Trends - Parkview Newsletter September 2010
Risk Trends - Parkview Newsletter September 2010Risk Trends - Parkview Newsletter September 2010
Risk Trends - Parkview Newsletter September 2010ugulvadi
 
Essay-G.J.Smid-IFC-UEK
Essay-G.J.Smid-IFC-UEKEssay-G.J.Smid-IFC-UEK
Essay-G.J.Smid-IFC-UEKGido Smid
 

Similaire à Coffee dodd-frank-systemic-risk-cs (20)

Jacobs Dofdd Frank&Basel3 Risk Nov11 11 8 11 V1
Jacobs Dofdd Frank&Basel3 Risk Nov11 11 8 11 V1Jacobs Dofdd Frank&Basel3 Risk Nov11 11 8 11 V1
Jacobs Dofdd Frank&Basel3 Risk Nov11 11 8 11 V1
 
The Future of Finance
The Future of FinanceThe Future of Finance
The Future of Finance
 
(292) failure can be good
(292)   failure can be good(292)   failure can be good
(292) failure can be good
 
Too Big to Fail
Too Big to FailToo Big to Fail
Too Big to Fail
 
The Legal Foundations of Financial Collapse
The Legal Foundations of Financial CollapseThe Legal Foundations of Financial Collapse
The Legal Foundations of Financial Collapse
 
2009 cd omeltdown
2009 cd omeltdown2009 cd omeltdown
2009 cd omeltdown
 
CAPITAL MARKETS ALERT: How Dodd-Frank and Other New U.S. Laws May Affect Non-...
CAPITAL MARKETS ALERT: How Dodd-Frank and Other New U.S. Laws May Affect Non-...CAPITAL MARKETS ALERT: How Dodd-Frank and Other New U.S. Laws May Affect Non-...
CAPITAL MARKETS ALERT: How Dodd-Frank and Other New U.S. Laws May Affect Non-...
 
DeFi's dependency on the U.S. banking system
DeFi's dependency on the U.S. banking systemDeFi's dependency on the U.S. banking system
DeFi's dependency on the U.S. banking system
 
Glossary financial-crisis-terms
Glossary financial-crisis-termsGlossary financial-crisis-terms
Glossary financial-crisis-terms
 
Loic sarton cds travail
Loic sarton   cds travailLoic sarton   cds travail
Loic sarton cds travail
 
Patton Boggs Dodd-Frank Reform Analysis
Patton Boggs Dodd-Frank Reform AnalysisPatton Boggs Dodd-Frank Reform Analysis
Patton Boggs Dodd-Frank Reform Analysis
 
Reg Reform Fact Sheet
Reg Reform Fact SheetReg Reform Fact Sheet
Reg Reform Fact Sheet
 
Reg Reform Fact Sheet
Reg Reform Fact SheetReg Reform Fact Sheet
Reg Reform Fact Sheet
 
Reg Reform Fact Sheet
Reg Reform Fact SheetReg Reform Fact Sheet
Reg Reform Fact Sheet
 
Choking the recovery
Choking the recoveryChoking the recovery
Choking the recovery
 
Final term paper emerging market finance (1)
Final term paper   emerging market finance (1)Final term paper   emerging market finance (1)
Final term paper emerging market finance (1)
 
Market Risk Management
Market Risk ManagementMarket Risk Management
Market Risk Management
 
Jon terracciano: Hedging the Global Market - Introduction
Jon terracciano: Hedging the Global Market - IntroductionJon terracciano: Hedging the Global Market - Introduction
Jon terracciano: Hedging the Global Market - Introduction
 
Risk Trends - Parkview Newsletter September 2010
Risk Trends - Parkview Newsletter September 2010Risk Trends - Parkview Newsletter September 2010
Risk Trends - Parkview Newsletter September 2010
 
Essay-G.J.Smid-IFC-UEK
Essay-G.J.Smid-IFC-UEKEssay-G.J.Smid-IFC-UEK
Essay-G.J.Smid-IFC-UEK
 

Dernier

Call Girls Service Pune ₹7.5k Pick Up & Drop With Cash Payment 9352852248 Cal...
Call Girls Service Pune ₹7.5k Pick Up & Drop With Cash Payment 9352852248 Cal...Call Girls Service Pune ₹7.5k Pick Up & Drop With Cash Payment 9352852248 Cal...
Call Girls Service Pune ₹7.5k Pick Up & Drop With Cash Payment 9352852248 Cal...roshnidevijkn ( Why You Choose Us? ) Escorts
 
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Wadgaon Sheri 6297143586 Call Hot Ind...
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Wadgaon Sheri  6297143586 Call Hot Ind...Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Wadgaon Sheri  6297143586 Call Hot Ind...
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Wadgaon Sheri 6297143586 Call Hot Ind...Call Girls in Nagpur High Profile
 
VIP Independent Call Girls in Bandra West 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Esc...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Bandra West 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Esc...VIP Independent Call Girls in Bandra West 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Esc...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Bandra West 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Esc...dipikadinghjn ( Why You Choose Us? ) Escorts
 
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Shivane 6297143586 Call Hot Indian Gi...
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Shivane  6297143586 Call Hot Indian Gi...Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Shivane  6297143586 Call Hot Indian Gi...
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Shivane 6297143586 Call Hot Indian Gi...Call Girls in Nagpur High Profile
 
7 tips trading Deriv Accumulator Options
7 tips trading Deriv Accumulator Options7 tips trading Deriv Accumulator Options
7 tips trading Deriv Accumulator OptionsVince Stanzione
 
Call Girls Banaswadi Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Service Ban...
Call Girls Banaswadi Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Service Ban...Call Girls Banaswadi Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Service Ban...
Call Girls Banaswadi Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Service Ban...amitlee9823
 
VIP Independent Call Girls in Taloja 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts ...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Taloja 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts ...VIP Independent Call Girls in Taloja 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts ...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Taloja 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts ...dipikadinghjn ( Why You Choose Us? ) Escorts
 
8377087607, Door Step Call Girls In Kalkaji (Locanto) 24/7 Available
8377087607, Door Step Call Girls In Kalkaji (Locanto) 24/7 Available8377087607, Door Step Call Girls In Kalkaji (Locanto) 24/7 Available
8377087607, Door Step Call Girls In Kalkaji (Locanto) 24/7 Availabledollysharma2066
 
Top Rated Pune Call Girls Sinhagad Road ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine S...
Top Rated  Pune Call Girls Sinhagad Road ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine S...Top Rated  Pune Call Girls Sinhagad Road ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine S...
Top Rated Pune Call Girls Sinhagad Road ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine S...Call Girls in Nagpur High Profile
 
Call Girls Rajgurunagar Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance Booking
Call Girls Rajgurunagar Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance BookingCall Girls Rajgurunagar Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance Booking
Call Girls Rajgurunagar Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance Bookingroncy bisnoi
 
Top Rated Pune Call Girls Viman Nagar ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex...
Top Rated  Pune Call Girls Viman Nagar ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex...Top Rated  Pune Call Girls Viman Nagar ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex...
Top Rated Pune Call Girls Viman Nagar ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex...Call Girls in Nagpur High Profile
 
Vasai-Virar Fantastic Call Girls-9833754194-Call Girls MUmbai
Vasai-Virar Fantastic Call Girls-9833754194-Call Girls MUmbaiVasai-Virar Fantastic Call Girls-9833754194-Call Girls MUmbai
Vasai-Virar Fantastic Call Girls-9833754194-Call Girls MUmbaipriyasharma62062
 
VIP Independent Call Girls in Andheri 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Andheri 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts...VIP Independent Call Girls in Andheri 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Andheri 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts...dipikadinghjn ( Why You Choose Us? ) Escorts
 
Business Principles, Tools, and Techniques in Participating in Various Types...
Business Principles, Tools, and Techniques  in Participating in Various Types...Business Principles, Tools, and Techniques  in Participating in Various Types...
Business Principles, Tools, and Techniques in Participating in Various Types...jeffreytingson
 
falcon-invoice-discounting-unlocking-prime-investment-opportunities
falcon-invoice-discounting-unlocking-prime-investment-opportunitiesfalcon-invoice-discounting-unlocking-prime-investment-opportunities
falcon-invoice-discounting-unlocking-prime-investment-opportunitiesFalcon Invoice Discounting
 
Diva-Thane European Call Girls Number-9833754194-Diva Busty Professional Call...
Diva-Thane European Call Girls Number-9833754194-Diva Busty Professional Call...Diva-Thane European Call Girls Number-9833754194-Diva Busty Professional Call...
Diva-Thane European Call Girls Number-9833754194-Diva Busty Professional Call...priyasharma62062
 
Stock Market Brief Deck (Under Pressure).pdf
Stock Market Brief Deck (Under Pressure).pdfStock Market Brief Deck (Under Pressure).pdf
Stock Market Brief Deck (Under Pressure).pdfMichael Silva
 
VIP Call Girl in Mumbai 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday Wit...
VIP Call Girl in Mumbai 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday Wit...VIP Call Girl in Mumbai 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday Wit...
VIP Call Girl in Mumbai 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday Wit...dipikadinghjn ( Why You Choose Us? ) Escorts
 

Dernier (20)

Call Girls Service Pune ₹7.5k Pick Up & Drop With Cash Payment 9352852248 Cal...
Call Girls Service Pune ₹7.5k Pick Up & Drop With Cash Payment 9352852248 Cal...Call Girls Service Pune ₹7.5k Pick Up & Drop With Cash Payment 9352852248 Cal...
Call Girls Service Pune ₹7.5k Pick Up & Drop With Cash Payment 9352852248 Cal...
 
(INDIRA) Call Girl Mumbai Call Now 8250077686 Mumbai Escorts 24x7
(INDIRA) Call Girl Mumbai Call Now 8250077686 Mumbai Escorts 24x7(INDIRA) Call Girl Mumbai Call Now 8250077686 Mumbai Escorts 24x7
(INDIRA) Call Girl Mumbai Call Now 8250077686 Mumbai Escorts 24x7
 
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Wadgaon Sheri 6297143586 Call Hot Ind...
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Wadgaon Sheri  6297143586 Call Hot Ind...Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Wadgaon Sheri  6297143586 Call Hot Ind...
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Wadgaon Sheri 6297143586 Call Hot Ind...
 
VIP Independent Call Girls in Bandra West 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Esc...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Bandra West 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Esc...VIP Independent Call Girls in Bandra West 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Esc...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Bandra West 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Esc...
 
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Shivane 6297143586 Call Hot Indian Gi...
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Shivane  6297143586 Call Hot Indian Gi...Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Shivane  6297143586 Call Hot Indian Gi...
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Shivane 6297143586 Call Hot Indian Gi...
 
7 tips trading Deriv Accumulator Options
7 tips trading Deriv Accumulator Options7 tips trading Deriv Accumulator Options
7 tips trading Deriv Accumulator Options
 
Call Girls Banaswadi Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Service Ban...
Call Girls Banaswadi Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Service Ban...Call Girls Banaswadi Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Service Ban...
Call Girls Banaswadi Just Call 👗 7737669865 👗 Top Class Call Girl Service Ban...
 
VIP Independent Call Girls in Taloja 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts ...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Taloja 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts ...VIP Independent Call Girls in Taloja 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts ...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Taloja 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts ...
 
8377087607, Door Step Call Girls In Kalkaji (Locanto) 24/7 Available
8377087607, Door Step Call Girls In Kalkaji (Locanto) 24/7 Available8377087607, Door Step Call Girls In Kalkaji (Locanto) 24/7 Available
8377087607, Door Step Call Girls In Kalkaji (Locanto) 24/7 Available
 
Top Rated Pune Call Girls Sinhagad Road ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine S...
Top Rated  Pune Call Girls Sinhagad Road ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine S...Top Rated  Pune Call Girls Sinhagad Road ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine S...
Top Rated Pune Call Girls Sinhagad Road ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine S...
 
Call Girls Rajgurunagar Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance Booking
Call Girls Rajgurunagar Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance BookingCall Girls Rajgurunagar Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance Booking
Call Girls Rajgurunagar Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance Booking
 
Top Rated Pune Call Girls Viman Nagar ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex...
Top Rated  Pune Call Girls Viman Nagar ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex...Top Rated  Pune Call Girls Viman Nagar ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex...
Top Rated Pune Call Girls Viman Nagar ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex...
 
Vasai-Virar Fantastic Call Girls-9833754194-Call Girls MUmbai
Vasai-Virar Fantastic Call Girls-9833754194-Call Girls MUmbaiVasai-Virar Fantastic Call Girls-9833754194-Call Girls MUmbai
Vasai-Virar Fantastic Call Girls-9833754194-Call Girls MUmbai
 
VIP Independent Call Girls in Andheri 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Andheri 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts...VIP Independent Call Girls in Andheri 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Andheri 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts...
 
Business Principles, Tools, and Techniques in Participating in Various Types...
Business Principles, Tools, and Techniques  in Participating in Various Types...Business Principles, Tools, and Techniques  in Participating in Various Types...
Business Principles, Tools, and Techniques in Participating in Various Types...
 
falcon-invoice-discounting-unlocking-prime-investment-opportunities
falcon-invoice-discounting-unlocking-prime-investment-opportunitiesfalcon-invoice-discounting-unlocking-prime-investment-opportunities
falcon-invoice-discounting-unlocking-prime-investment-opportunities
 
W.D. Gann Theory Complete Information.pdf
W.D. Gann Theory Complete Information.pdfW.D. Gann Theory Complete Information.pdf
W.D. Gann Theory Complete Information.pdf
 
Diva-Thane European Call Girls Number-9833754194-Diva Busty Professional Call...
Diva-Thane European Call Girls Number-9833754194-Diva Busty Professional Call...Diva-Thane European Call Girls Number-9833754194-Diva Busty Professional Call...
Diva-Thane European Call Girls Number-9833754194-Diva Busty Professional Call...
 
Stock Market Brief Deck (Under Pressure).pdf
Stock Market Brief Deck (Under Pressure).pdfStock Market Brief Deck (Under Pressure).pdf
Stock Market Brief Deck (Under Pressure).pdf
 
VIP Call Girl in Mumbai 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday Wit...
VIP Call Girl in Mumbai 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday Wit...VIP Call Girl in Mumbai 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday Wit...
VIP Call Girl in Mumbai 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday Wit...
 

Coffee dodd-frank-systemic-risk-cs

  • 1. AN INTRODUCTION TO THE DODD-FRANK ACT: Congress Addresses Systemic Risk John C. Coffee, Jr. Adolf A. Berle Professor of Law Columbia Law School June 7, 2012 Second Circuit Judicial Conference The Boom/Bust Cycle Slide 1
  • 2. I. Unlike Most Securities Reform Legislation (Which Principally Addresses Investor Protection and Disclosure Issues), the Dodd-Frank Act chiefly addresses systemic risk. Thus, the inevitable question is: What Do We Mean By Systemic Risk? II. Although There Is No Universally Accepted Definition, the Core Idea Is That Because of Interconnections A Local Crisis Can Become a Global Crisis, Causing In Effect A Cascade of Falling Financial Dominoes III. We Saw Systemic Risk Produce a World-Wide Crisis in 2008 When a Localized Problem In the U.S. Subprime Mortgage Market Paralyzed the World’s Financial Markets Because Asset-Backed Securitizations and Derivatives Had Knitted Together the World’s Financial Institutions In a Web of Interdependency Slide 2
  • 3. Systemic Risk Has Three Faces: (1) A Financial Institution Can Be Too Big to Fail (Lehman Wasn’t, But Citigroup Probably Is). (2) A Financial Institution Can Be Too Interconnected to Fail Because Many Institutions Are Its Counterparties (AIG is the paradigm as it tied together many institutions through credit default swaps) (3) Financial Institutions Can Be Too Risk Correlated to Fail (Because the Prospective Failure of One Causes Prices to Fall In a Market In Which Many Have Invested) For example, if Bear Stearns desperately needs to liquidate its portfolio of CDOs to avoid insolvency, its sales drive down prices in a thin market and forces larger TBTF institutions to mark down or liquidate similar investments. Market pressures and globalization have probably increased the level of risk correlation over the last decade. Slide 3
  • 4. I. WHAT CAUSED THE 2008 CRISIS? Why did all major financial institutions seemingly become insolvent at once? II. FOUR CREDIBLE SCENARIOS EXIST: A. The Moral Hazard Story: “Executive Compensation Caused the Crash.” Here, the claim is that a rapid shift toward incentive-based compensation at financial institutions focused senior managers on short-term results. For example, if you can make $100 million in Year 1 if a sufficient number of securitization deals close, why worry about what happens to those deals in Year 5? B. The Perverse Subsidy Story: Because Creditors Believed that “Too Big to Fail Banks” (“TBTF”) Would Always Be Bailed Out, They Advanced Too Much Credit and Too Cheaply. Because of this perception, TBTF banks received an implicit subsidy, as investors lent too cheaply. Exploiting this subsidy, financial institutions took on excessive leverage (often under shareholder pressure to do so). C. Bounded Rationality: The Industry and Regulators Are Subject to The Same Cognitive Limitations. For example, no one truly understood the risk potential in Credit Default Swaps. Both in the case of AIG (and more recently in the case of MF Global), the potential for a “run on the bank” through margin calls was not adequately recognized. D. “Shadow Banking” Was Exempt From The Regulatory Scrutiny That Applied to Traditional Banks. This disparity caused the crisis to begin at investment banks. Slide 4
  • 5. What Prescriptions Follow From These Diagnoses? A. If “Excessive” or “Short-Term” Executive Compensation is the Problem, Then the Following Responses Seem Relevant: 1) Regulatory Controls on Compensation at Large Financial Institutions 2) Mandatory Deferral of Bonuses 3) Clawbacks 4) Corporate Governance Reforms Giving Shareholders Greater Power (“Say on Pay” Votes and “Access to the Proxy Statement”). B. If an Implicit Subsidy Based on Expectations of a Bailout is the Problem, Then The Following Reforms Seem Responsive: 1) Restrict Banking Regulators from Making Bailouts 2) Resolution Authority (an expedited procedure for liquidating failing TBTF institutions prior to insolvency without the use of bankruptcy) 3) Higher Capital Adequacy Standards 4) Mandatory or Permissive Use of Contingent Capital Slide 5
  • 6. C. If Panic and Cognitive Failures Are the Key Problem (as in AIG), Then Policymakers Might Consider: 1) Mandating the Use of Clearinghouses and Exchanges in the OTC Derivatives Market 2) Restrict Risk-Taking by TBTF Banks by Proscribing Certain Higher Risk Activities (i.e. the “Volcker Rule”) D. To the Extent “Shadow Banking” Was Exempt from Prudential Oversight, Then Appropriate Reforms Would Include: 1) A Centralized Systemic Risk Oversight Body 2) Ending the Exemptions for OTC Derivatives 3) Subjecting Hedge Funds to Regulation 4) Closer Regulation of Credit Rating Agencies As Will Next Be Seen Dodd-Frank Attempts All of the Above — Incompletely and In Broad Brushstrokes Slide 6
  • 7. The New Financial Architecture 1. Although the U.S. has the most fragmented system of financial regulation in the developed world, with a different regulator for each class of investments, Dodd-Frank did little to change this: 1. The SEC and CFTC were not merged. 2. Only the unlamented Office of Thrift Supervision was terminated. 3. But new agencies were created (e.g., Consumer Protection). 2. The major new player is the Financial Stability Oversight Council (“FSOC”), which is intended to monitor systemic risk. (See Sections 111 to 121 of Dodd-Frank). It has ten voting members (consisting primarily of the chairs of the major financial regulators), is chaired by the Secretary of the Treasury, and five non-voting members (e.g., the Director of the Office of Financial Research, the Director of the Federal Insurance Office, and several representatives of state financial regulators). 3. The FSOC’s purposes are (1) “to identify risks to the financial stability of the United States that could arise from the material financial distress or failure or ongoing activities of large, inter-connected” financial institutions; (2) “to provide market discipline, by eliminating expectations . . . that the Government will shield [institutions and creditors] from losses in the event of failure”; and (3) “to respond to emerging threats to the stability of the U.S. financial system” (Section 111(a) ). Slide 7
  • 8. 1. In overview, the FSOC is a beefed-up successor to the President’s Working Group, with a significantly enhanced research capacity, but only limited powers. Its powers are largely advisory or limited to information gathering, except that it may determine by a 2/3’s vote (which majority must include the Secretary of the Treasury) that a U.S. nonbank financial company (or a foreign nonbank financial company) is to be supervised by the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve and subjected to the latter’s prudential standards if the FSOC finds that the institution’s activities “could pose a threat to the financial stability of the United States” (Section 113(a)). 2. This means that the FSOC could determine that certain insurance companies, broker dealers, mutual fund managers (e.g., Fidelity), hedge funds (e.g., Citadel), or industrial companies (e.g., GE) should be subject to the same standards of capital adequacy, leverage and risk-taking as a major bank holding company is. 3. The FSOC has recently specified the criteria (and some of the procedures) that it will use in determining which nonbank financial institutions are systemically significant, but has not yet acted to designate any institution as systemically significant. 4. When it does, there will predictably be appeals that will reach the courts. 5. Evaluation: The FSOC emerged from Dodd-Frank a slightly weaker body than originally intended. Had it been given an independent chair, it would have been led by an independent and politically accountable figure with exclusive responsibility for systemic risk. Instead, the Secretary of the Treasury has multiple responsibilities and must balance financial stability against economic growth and political consensus. Slide 8
  • 9. The End of the Central Bank As Lender of Last Resort? 1. Dodd-Frank Restricts the Power of the Federal Reserve to advance funds to a failing TBTF bank. 2. Specifically, Section 1101(a)(6) of Dodd-Frank eliminates the Federal Reserve Board’s former authority under Section 13(3) of the Federal Reserve Act to make emergency loans to a failing bank. Now, the FRB can no longer lend to a single firm but can only make emergency loans “for the purpose of providing liquidity to the financial system, and not to a failing financial company.” Such lending must be pursuant to a “program or facility with broad-based eligibility” and must be adequately collateralized in a manner that “is sufficient to protect taxpayers from losses.” 3. Clearly, neither Lehman nor AIG could have met this standard. Indeed, Section 1101(a)(6) expressly denies the FRB the power to make loans under its emergency lending authority “for the purpose of assisting a single and specific company to avoid bankruptcy [or] resolution authority under Title II” of the Dodd-Frank Act. 4. Similarly, Section 212 (“No Other Funding”) bars the FDIC from lending to TBTF banks outside of a Title II receivership. The language is clear that the FDIC can lend to, or guarantee debts of, the institution only once the financial institution has entered liquidation and is being wound down. Bottom Line: The intent of Dodd-Frank is to end the Central Bank As Lender of Last Resort to Failing TBTF Banks because bailouts have become politically unacceptable. The FRB may find ways to avoid this proscription, but its hands are significantly tied and it will have to face Congress, and maybe the courts, if it seeks to outflank these provisions. Slide 9
  • 10. Resolution Authority 1. In place of Central Bank lending to avert a banking crisis, Dodd-Frank intends to substitute “resolution authority,” which is largely modelled after the procedures the FDIC has used to liquidate smaller banks outside of bankruptcy. 2. Although expeditious liquidation of a systemically significant financial institution is clearly desirable (and the Lehman bankruptcy shows that liquidation under the Bankruptcy Code is interminable), the problem with Title II (“Orderly Liquidation Authority”) of Dodd-Frank is that it requires a very high level of consensus among financial regulators to begin the process and then subjects their determination to a uniquely truncated form of judicial review. 3. To illustrate, let’s suppose that a major bank is in trouble (the procedures are different for a broker-dealer or insurance company). What happens? Sections 203 and 202 of Dodd-Frank outline the following procedures: Step One. On their own initiative (or at the request of the Secretary of the Treasury), the FDIC and the FRB determine to request the Secretary to appoint the FDIC as receiver for this financial institution — by not less than a two-thirds vote of each of the FRB Governors and the FDIC board of directors. (If the troubled institution is a broker, 2/3s of the SEC’s five Commissioners must also approve — i.e., four Commissioners). Step Two. The FRB and the FDIC submit an elaborate report to the Secretary, containing the findings specified in Section 203(a)(2) of Dodd-Frank, which must describe the effect of the default upon the financial stability of the U.S. and the likelihood of any “private sector alternative.” Slide 10
  • 11. Step Three. The Secretary, in consultation with the President, must determine that the financial company is in “danger of default,” which term is elaborately defined in Section 203(c)(4). Under Section 203(b), the Secretary must make a total of seven overlapping findings, including the “danger of default” finding. Step Four. The Secretary notifies the “covered financial company” that it intends to appoint the FDIC as receiver. If the company does not consent, the Secretary must petition the United States District Court for the District of Columbia for an order authorizing the Secretary to so appoint the FDIC as receiver. The Court must determine if the Secretary’s decision is “arbitrary and capricious” after a hearing, but under Section 202(a)(1)(v), if “the Court does not make a determination within 24 hours of receipt of the petition, . . . the petition shall be granted by operation of law.” Step Five. An appeal may be taken to the D.C. Circuit within 30 days, and the D.C. Circuit “shall consider any appeal . . . on an expedited basis.” A petition for a writ of certiorari to the Supreme Court is also authorized, and the Court is instructed to “consider any petition on an expedited basis.” However, the scope of the Court’s review “shall be limited to whether the determination of the Secretary that the covered financial company is in default or in danger of default (and is within the statute’s coverage) . . . is arbitrary and capricious.” (Section 202(a)(2)(iv). (This seems to eliminate judicial review of five of the seven findings that the Secretary must make). 1. Some law professors have already suggested that this procedure is constitutionally suspect. Slide 11
  • 12. 1. More importantly, these are determinations that no Secretary of the Treasury (or President) will want to make as liquidation will suggest a failure of adequate supervision on their watch. An immediate report must also be provided to Congress, where the opposition party will eagerly second guess the Secretary. A possibility exists that any such liquidation may trigger a financial panic (as Lehman’s bankruptcy did). 2. Bottom Line: Although “resolution authority” contemplates an early intervention and early liquidation of a TBTF institution, this is unrealistic, and the odds are high that financial regulators will prefer to “kick the can down the road” and hope for the best — until actual insolvency occurs. 3. As a result, if (1) the FRB and FDIC cannot advance funds to a major financial institution facing a liquidity crisis and (2) the Government will be reluctant to liquidate early, Dodd-Frank may have painted the U.S. financial system into the proverbial corner where nothing can or will be done. 4. If “orderly liquidation” under Title II is in fact ordered, Section 204(a) of Dodd-Frank mandates that (1) “creditors and shareholders will bear the losses,” (2) “management will not be retained,” and (3) all parties “having responsibility for the condition of the financial company will bear losses consistent with their responsibility.” This sounds retributive, and Section 210(f) authorizes the FDIC, as receiver, to sue officers and directors of a failed financial company for gross negligence. (It is unclear whether corporate charter provisions eliminating monetary liability for breach of the duty of care will be respected — See Delaware §102(b)(7)). 5. A Final Irony. The FDIC is authorized to makes loans to, and purchase debt obligations of, a covered financial company placed in Title II liquidation. As a result, creditors may still be spared. (See Section 204(d)). The most likely procedure will involve the FDIC creating a “bridge company” to buy the assets of the failed company by paying off the creditors. If the FDIC decides to pay off debt holders in full, the same expectation of a bailout may persist, and the perverse subsidy may survive. But the FDIC’s funds are limited, and it probably cannot bailout an AIG alone. Slide 12
  • 13. EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION 1. Given the strong perception that incentive compensation can produce “short termism” and moral hazard, Dodd-Frank takes two divergent and possibly contradictory routes to cure this problem: A. It federalizes some aspects of corporate governance in order to give shareholders greater power; and B. In Section 956, it authorizes regulators to prohibit excessive incentive-band compensation at “covered financial institutions” that “could lead to material financial loss.” 1. Overview: There is much evidence that the more closely the incentives of senior executives were aligned with those of shareholders, the worse the financial institution did in 2008! Banks with “shareholder friendly” corporate governance performed more poorly than banks with “unfriendly” corporate governance. 2. Bottom Line: Empowering shareholders may not be the answer, but instead may be part of the problem, in terms of systemic risk. Shareholders appear to push managers to accept higher risk. Slide 13
  • 14. The Corporate Governance Prong 1. Section 971 authorized, but did not mandate, the SEC to adopt “proxy access” — a corporate governance reform that it had previously proposed, but never adopted. Other provisions mandated advisory shareholder votes on executive compensation (Section 951), required additional disclosures on CEO compensation (Section 953), required compensation committee independence (Section 952), and eliminated “broker votes” in director elections (Section 957). 2. Pursuant to this authority, the SEC adopted Rule 14a-11 (the proxy access rule) permitting low cost proxy contests to elect 1, 2, or at most 3 directors by investors holding 3% if they were not seeking control. 3. The Business Roundtable and the Chamber of Commerce sued to invalidate the rule on the grounds that the SEC had not done an adequate cost/benefit analysis – and won (Business Roundtable v. SEC, 647 F.3d 1144 (D.C. Cir. 2011)). The D.C. Circuit found that the lack of an adequate cost/benefit study made the rule arbitrary and capricious; it particularly emphasized the SEC’s failure to consider the costs that corporations would incur in resisting “proxy access” in its cost/benefit calculus. Slide 14
  • 15. IMPACT 1. Far more than earlier statutes (such as SOX), Dodd-Frank relies on administrative implementation through risk-making. 2. That process is seriously behind. 3. As of June 1, 2012, a total of 221 Dodd-Frank rulemaking deadlines have passed, and 148 (or 67.0%) have been missed, while only 73 (33.0%) have been met with finalized rules (Source: DavisPolk Progress Report 6/1/2012). 4. Multiple factors may explain this slowness, but the Business Roundtable decision appears to have traumatized the SEC, which may lack the resources or capacity to engage in cost/benefit analysis that will satisfy the D.C. Circuit 5. Highly Debatable Policy Issue: Can Cost/Benefit Analysis Be Used to Return Us to a Lochner-like era in which regulation is presumptively disfavored? Slide 15
  • 16. The Paternalistic Prong 1. Section 956 (“Enhanced Compensation Structure Reporting”) instructs Federal regulators to jointly prescribe regulations requiring “covered financial institutions” to disclose “the structure of all incentive-based compensation arrangements offered by such covered financial institutions sufficient to determine whether the compensation structure — A. provides an executive officer, employee, director, or principal shareholder with excessive compensation, fees, or benefits, or B. could lead to material financial loss to the covered financial institution . . .” 1. Section 956(b) then authorizes federal regulators to bar “any type of incentive-based payment arrangement that . . . encourages inappropriate risks by covered financial institutions. . . .” 2. The initial issue was how broadly to read this disclosure obligation. Although it was clear that individual identities were not to be disclosed, this language could have been read to require disclosure of aggregate incentive compensation paid to executives and its distribution. Slide 16
  • 17. 1. This is exactly what then New York Attorney General Cuomo required in 2009 when he published the following chart: 2008 Bonus Compensation at Selected Financial Institutions of No. of No. Employees Employees Receiving Receiving Bonus ≥ $3 Bonus ≥ $1 Institution Earnings / (Losses) Bonus Pool million million Bank of America $4 billion $3.3 billion 28 172 Citigroup, Inc. $(27.7 billion) $5.33 billion 124 738 Goldman Sachs Group $2.322 billion $4.823 billion 212 953 J.P. Morgan Chase & Co. $5.6 billion $8.693 billion >200 1,626 Merrill Lynch $(27.6 billion) $3.6 billion 149 696 Morgan Stanley $1.707 billion $4.475 billion 101 428 1. As the above chart makes clear, even when financial institutions lost billions, they still paid out bonuses totaling in the billions to hundreds of employees (see Citigroup and Merrill Lynch in the above chart). 2. When the firm did profit, the bonus pool was often a multiple of earnings (see Goldman, J.P. Morgan, and Morgan Stanley’s in the above chart). 3. Practices varied, thus making firm-specific disclosure more important. At Merrill Lynch, 14 employees received over $10 million in bonuses in 2008; 10 at J.P. Morgan Chase; but only 3 at Citigroup. BOTTOM LINE: THE BONUS CULTURE HAS DEEP ROOTS. Slide 17
  • 18. What Happened to Section 956? 1. Section 956 will not produce anything like the foregoing disclosures. This is because, notwithstanding its broad statutory language, the industry has already won this battle — and on several levels. 2. First, rather than requiring quantitative disclosures relating to executive compensation, federal regulators have required only an annual report that “describes the structure of the covered financial institution’s incentive-based compensation arrangements . . . that is sufficient to allow an assessment” of whether those arrangements could lead to “excessive compensation.” This compromise means no numbers need be disclosed, and boilerplate will suffice. 3. Second, although more was required in the case of very large TBTF banks with $50 billion in assets or more, it was left to the board of each such TBTF institution to decide who (other than its executive officers) had the ability to expose the institution to substantial losses. In short, regulators decided to let each firm determine for itself who could expose the firm to substantial loss. Slide 18
  • 19. What Is Going On Here? 2. Under this rule, a TBTF bank could employ a 100 or more persons, each receiving a bonus of well over $1 million, and still disclose nothing – so long as the employees were not executives and did not occupy a position that the board detrmined could cause it a substantial loss. 3. Third, although the rules require a deferral of at least 50% of the annual incentive-based compensation paid to senior executives for a period of at least three years, they require no deferral even in the case of those other persons that the board does identify as being able to cause substantial loss to the firm. Bottom line: (2) No quantitative aggregate disclosures are required. (3) Each institution decides for itself who could cause it a substantial loss and discloses only its general arrangements in those cases. (4) No deferral for even those persons (other than executives) who a TBTF institution acknowledges could cause it loss. What Explains This? Slide 19
  • 20. 1. The most plausible answer is that the industry did not want the executive compensation rules to apply to its “star” traders. 2. If the rules required disclosure and deferral of bonus compensation in their case, the industry likely feared a migration of these traders from TBTF banks to hedge funds or offshore institutions. 3. But “star” traders are exactly the persons who can cause substantial losses to financial institutions: Witness Nicholas Leeson at Barings in 1995 and Jerome Kerveil at Societe Generale. 4. Bottom Line: The executive compensation rules have been hollowed out by the regulators to protect TBTF banks from competitive injury. Irony: A General Counsel at such a bank will have to defer his incentive compensation for 3 years (although he is innocuous in terms of the bank’s solvency), but the star trader betting billions each week will not. Slide 20
  • 21. CLAWBACKS 1. Section 954 of Dodd-Frank vastly expands the scope of mandatory clawbacks beyond that originally provided in Sarbanes-Oxley (“SOX”). 2. While SOX required recovery of incentive-based bonuses from the CEO and CFO, Dodd-Frank specifies that the “issuer will recover from any current or former executive officer of the issuer who received incentive-based compensation (including stock options awarded as compensation) during the 3- year period preceding the date on which the issuer is required to prepare an accounting restatement based on the erroneous data in excess of what would have been paid to the executive office under the accounting restatement.” 3. Still, there must be “an accounting restatement due to the material noncompliance of the issuer with any financial reporting requirement under the securities laws.” Thus, a bonus paid to the “London Whale” would not be recoverable if no restatement were necessary. 4. No enforcement mechanism is provided. To date, clawbacks have been primarily enforced by the SEC (although a derivative action is possible if demand can be excused). Slide 21
  • 22. Restricting Risk-Taking 1. If some financial institutions are “too big to fail,” it follows that they need to be regulated so that they do not fail. 2. The leading attempt made by Dodd-Frank toward this end is Section 619 (“Prohibitions on Proprietary Trading And Certain Relationships With Hedge Funds and Private Equity Funds”). Known as the “Volcker Rule,” this provision has touched off the largest lobbying campaign in modern financial history. 3. Section 619 (which amends the Bank Holding Company Act) starts with broad prohibitions: “Unless otherwise provided in this section, a banking entity shall not — A. engage in proprietary trading, or B. acquire or retain any equity, partnership, or other ownership interest in or sponsor a hedge fund or a private equity fund.” Slide 22
  • 23. Exemptions 1. Some ambiguous exemptions, however, may undercut the scope of § 619. Section 13(d)(1)(C) of the amended Bank Holding Company Act (“BHCA”) permits: “Risk-mitigating hedging activities in connection with and related to individual or aggregated positions, contracts, or other holdings of a banking entity that are designed to reduce the specific risks to the banking entity in connection with and related to such positions, contracts or other holdings.” Does this authorize the type of “portfolio hedging” engaged in by JPMorgan’s “London Whale”? Although the above statutory language seems narrow, the proposed rules are broader, and the answer will lie in the final rules. 1. Another important exemption is in Section 13(d)(1)(B) of the BHCA for “underwriting or market-making activities to the extent that any such activities . . . are designed not to exceed the reasonably expected near term demands of dealers, customers or counterparties.” Slide 23
  • 24. The Lobbying Battle 1. The banking industry wants broad permission to trade sovereign debt. After Greece, the failure of MF Global, and JPMorgan’s problems, such trading is no longer self- evidently safe, but other European countries, Japan, and Canada have all asked the U.S. to permit such trading by U.S. banks. 2. A legal battle will likely arise regarding the extraterritorial scope of Dodd-Frank’s Section 619. Can, for example, federal regulators prohibit the London office of U.S. banks from engaging in proprietary trading (as in the case of the London Whale)? Or does this overlook the presumption against extraterritoriality in Morrison v. Nat’l. Australia Bank Ltd., 130 Sup. Ct. 2860? 3. If regulators cannot restrict overseas operations, Section 619 may simply produce a migration of traders to offshore offices. 4. The lobbying imbalance is reaching record proportions. A study by Duke Law Professor Kimberly Krawiec finds that between July 2010 and October 2011, representatives of financial institutions met with federal agencies to discuss the Volcker Rule some 351 times, while public interest groups met with regulators some 19 times over the same period — a better than 18 to 1 ratio. Slide 24
  • 25. Regulating Over-The-Counter Derivatives 1. AIG’s failure showed the dangers of opacity in a major market. 2. Had counterparties understood the degree to which AIG was serving as the counterparty to the entire market of Credit Default Swap users and was thus insuring the entire market against financial risk, counterparties might have required that greater collateral and margin be posted (or might simply have sought other counterparties). 3. To prevent the default of a single counterparty creating a wave of falling financial dominoes, Section 723 of Dodd-Frank mandates the use of clearinghouses (which means that each party’s transaction is with a clearinghouse backed by the market) and the use of exchanges and “swap execution facilities” (to create greater transparency). 4. But there are numerous exceptions. The most important is the “end user exemption” that is now set forth in Section 2(h)(7) of the Commodity Exchange Act, which applies to non- financial entities using swaps “to hedge or mitigate commercial risk.” Under it, a United Airlines is, for example, exempt so long as it is hedging its own fuel costs. But if it is exempt, so also is its counterparty, and thus much trading will remain off market and opaque. 5. Additionally, customized swaps need not be cleared through clearinghouses or traded on exchanges, and here the definitions in the rules will be critical. How little does it take to make a swap “customized” and thus exempt? 6. New Division of Jurisdiction: Swaps are Covered; SEC has “Security-Based” Swaps (defined in Section 761); CFTC, the rest. Registration is required of “swap execution facilities,” major dealers and “swap participants.” Slide 25
  • 26. Credit Rating Agencies 1. SEC administrative oversight of the credit rating agencies has been tightened, but the “issuer pays” model for credit ratings seems likely to persist. 2. The one area where courts will encounter a potentially significant legal change is the revised pleading standard in Section 933 (“State of mind in private actions”). It provides both that (i) credit ratings shall not qualify for the PSLRA’s “safe harbor for forward-looking information” and (ii) the PSLRA’s “strong inference of fraud” pleading standard shall not apply to credit ratings. Instead, “[I]t shall be sufficient for purposes of pleading any required state of mind in relation to such actions that the complaint state with particularity facts giving rise to a strong inference that the credit rating agency knowingly or recklessly failed — (i) to conduct a reasonable investigation of the rated security with respect to the factual elements relied upon by its own methodology for evaluating credit risk; or (ii) to obtain reasonable verification of such factual elements (which verification may be based on a sampling technique that does not amount to an audit) from other sources that the credit rating agency considered to be competent and that were independent of the issuer and underwriter.” Slide 26
  • 27. Meaning and Impact 1. Does this language replace the normal scienter standard of Rule 10b-5 with a negligence standard? Answer: NO! 2. Instead, it is simply providing a substitute pleading standard for the motion to dismiss, which requires plaintiffs to plead a lack of adequate due diligence. 3. The plaintiff who survives the motion to dismiss because of this softened standard can obtain discovery, but, by trial or summary judgment, plaintiffs must show scienter. 4. For the future, in light of this Circuit’s decision in Fait v. Regions Fin. Corp., 655 F.3d 105 (2d Cir. 2011), it will likely be necessary for plaintiffs to show not only that a rating was inflated but that defendants did not subjectively believe the rating was accurate at the time it was published. 5. Credit Rating Agencies commonly assert a First Amendment Defense. In Section 951, Congress states a finding that “the activities of credit rating agencies are fundamentally commercial in character and should be subject to the same standards of liability and oversight as apply to auditors, securities analysts, and investment bankers.” Will this have any impact? Slide 27
  • 28. Summary 1. This tour has not covered many topics, including: 1. Whistleblowers and bounties; 2. Asset-Backed Securitizations and mandatory risk retention; 3. New SEC and SIPC powers; 4. the Bureau of Consumer Protection (Sections 1011 to 1051); 5. Hedge fund registration; 6. “Predatory” Mortgage lending; and 7. Conflict Minerals. 2. But, more than other “reform” statutes, Dodd-Frank depends on administrative implementation. To date, that implementation has been slow and equivocal, and early steps have been judicially contested. Nothing suggests that this will change. Slide 28