SlideShare une entreprise Scribd logo
1  sur  44
Fixed Business Law Groupwork EMBA11 – Group 2 Stanelle, Tari, Estep, Nguyen, Mildren
[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object]
[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object]
[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object]
[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object]
[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],Map Illustrating Global existence of Antitrust laws – Source Anti trust blog
[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object]
[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object]
[object Object],[object Object],[object Object]
[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object]
[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object]
[object Object],[object Object],[object Object]
[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object]
[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object]
[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object]
[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object]
[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object]
[object Object],[object Object],[object Object]
[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object]
[object Object]
[object Object],facilities for an amount that grossly exceeds the average price for that commodity during the 30 days before the declaration of the state of emergency, unless the seller can justify the price by showing increases in its prices or market trends
[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object]
[object Object],[object Object],[object Object]
[object Object],[object Object],[object Object]
[object Object],[object Object],determine significantly the terms on which other individuals shall have access to it
[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object]
[object Object],[object Object],conspiracies that unreasonably restrain interstate and foreign trade. This includes cartel violations, such as price fixing, bid rigging and customer allocation.
[object Object],[object Object],[object Object]
[object Object],[object Object]
[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object]
[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object]
[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object]
[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object]
[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object]
[object Object],[object Object]
[object Object],[object Object],[object Object]
[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object]
[object Object],[object Object]
[object Object],[object Object],[object Object]
[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object]
[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object]
[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object]
[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object]
[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object],[object Object]

Contenu connexe

Tendances

Kotler: Chapter 21
Kotler: Chapter 21Kotler: Chapter 21
Kotler: Chapter 21
Grace
 
Marketing environment
Marketing environmentMarketing environment
Marketing environment
Shameem Ali
 
personal selling and direct marketing
personal selling and direct marketingpersonal selling and direct marketing
personal selling and direct marketing
Darwin Granadozin
 
Distribution Management
Distribution ManagementDistribution Management
Distribution Management
Ravi Lakhani
 
Chapter 1 Defining Marketing For The 21st Century
Chapter 1 Defining Marketing For The 21st CenturyChapter 1 Defining Marketing For The 21st Century
Chapter 1 Defining Marketing For The 21st Century
Diarta
 
Chapter 1 P P T
Chapter 1  P P TChapter 1  P P T
Chapter 1 P P T
intro
 

Tendances (20)

Marketing Environment
Marketing EnvironmentMarketing Environment
Marketing Environment
 
Trade barriers
Trade barriersTrade barriers
Trade barriers
 
Kotler: Chapter 21
Kotler: Chapter 21Kotler: Chapter 21
Kotler: Chapter 21
 
Laws Affecting International Business and Travel Chapter 12
Laws Affecting International Business and Travel Chapter 12Laws Affecting International Business and Travel Chapter 12
Laws Affecting International Business and Travel Chapter 12
 
Sustainable marketing
Sustainable marketingSustainable marketing
Sustainable marketing
 
Marketing environment
Marketing environmentMarketing environment
Marketing environment
 
personal selling and direct marketing
personal selling and direct marketingpersonal selling and direct marketing
personal selling and direct marketing
 
Distribution Management
Distribution ManagementDistribution Management
Distribution Management
 
International Marketing Management - Introduction
International Marketing Management - IntroductionInternational Marketing Management - Introduction
International Marketing Management - Introduction
 
Direct and online marketing
Direct and online marketing Direct and online marketing
Direct and online marketing
 
Marketing management orientation
Marketing management orientationMarketing management orientation
Marketing management orientation
 
Chapter 1 Defining Marketing For The 21st Century
Chapter 1 Defining Marketing For The 21st CenturyChapter 1 Defining Marketing For The 21st Century
Chapter 1 Defining Marketing For The 21st Century
 
Global Marketing
Global MarketingGlobal Marketing
Global Marketing
 
Managing Marketing Information
Managing Marketing InformationManaging Marketing Information
Managing Marketing Information
 
Consumer Market and Business Market
Consumer Market and Business MarketConsumer Market and Business Market
Consumer Market and Business Market
 
Chap 14 Developing Pricing Strategies & Programs
Chap 14 Developing Pricing Strategies & ProgramsChap 14 Developing Pricing Strategies & Programs
Chap 14 Developing Pricing Strategies & Programs
 
World bank group international trade
World bank group international tradeWorld bank group international trade
World bank group international trade
 
Designing and Managing Integrated Marketing Communications
Designing and Managing Integrated Marketing CommunicationsDesigning and Managing Integrated Marketing Communications
Designing and Managing Integrated Marketing Communications
 
Chapter 1 P P T
Chapter 1  P P TChapter 1  P P T
Chapter 1 P P T
 
Telemarketing ppt-1
Telemarketing ppt-1Telemarketing ppt-1
Telemarketing ppt-1
 

Similaire à Law pricing presentation final 08152010

Jeopardy commercial law
Jeopardy commercial lawJeopardy commercial law
Jeopardy commercial law
Donna Kesot
 
Jeopardy commercial law
Jeopardy commercial lawJeopardy commercial law
Jeopardy commercial law
Donna Kesot
 
Critical Analysis Topic The Impact of Antitrust on Business P.docx
Critical Analysis Topic The Impact of Antitrust on Business   P.docxCritical Analysis Topic The Impact of Antitrust on Business   P.docx
Critical Analysis Topic The Impact of Antitrust on Business P.docx
faithxdunce63732
 

Similaire à Law pricing presentation final 08152010 (20)

Chapter 22
Chapter 22Chapter 22
Chapter 22
 
What do Trade Creditors need to know about Antitrust Laws
What do Trade Creditors need to know about Antitrust LawsWhat do Trade Creditors need to know about Antitrust Laws
What do Trade Creditors need to know about Antitrust Laws
 
What do Trade Creditors Need to Know
What do Trade Creditors Need to KnowWhat do Trade Creditors Need to Know
What do Trade Creditors Need to Know
 
6XZ1799
6XZ17996XZ1799
6XZ1799
 
Playmobil.Ver2
Playmobil.Ver2Playmobil.Ver2
Playmobil.Ver2
 
Comprtition law
Comprtition law Comprtition law
Comprtition law
 
Information Sharing.ppt
Information Sharing.pptInformation Sharing.ppt
Information Sharing.ppt
 
Jeopardy commercial law
Jeopardy commercial lawJeopardy commercial law
Jeopardy commercial law
 
Antitrust and real estate
Antitrust and real estateAntitrust and real estate
Antitrust and real estate
 
Jeopardy commercial law
Jeopardy commercial lawJeopardy commercial law
Jeopardy commercial law
 
Transatlantic business brief march 2014
Transatlantic business brief march 2014Transatlantic business brief march 2014
Transatlantic business brief march 2014
 
Critical Analysis Topic The Impact of Antitrust on Business P.docx
Critical Analysis Topic The Impact of Antitrust on Business   P.docxCritical Analysis Topic The Impact of Antitrust on Business   P.docx
Critical Analysis Topic The Impact of Antitrust on Business P.docx
 
Ch12
Ch12 Ch12
Ch12
 
Ch12
Ch12Ch12
Ch12
 
Monopoly
MonopolyMonopoly
Monopoly
 
Chapter7.ppt
Chapter7.pptChapter7.ppt
Chapter7.ppt
 
Antitrust laws
Antitrust lawsAntitrust laws
Antitrust laws
 
Monopoly
MonopolyMonopoly
Monopoly
 
Antitrust Policy: A Century of Economic and Legal Thinking
Antitrust Policy: A Century of Economic and Legal ThinkingAntitrust Policy: A Century of Economic and Legal Thinking
Antitrust Policy: A Century of Economic and Legal Thinking
 
Case Econ08 Ppt 13
Case Econ08 Ppt 13Case Econ08 Ppt 13
Case Econ08 Ppt 13
 

Law pricing presentation final 08152010

  • 1. Fixed Business Law Groupwork EMBA11 – Group 2 Stanelle, Tari, Estep, Nguyen, Mildren
  • 2.
  • 3.
  • 4.
  • 5.
  • 6.
  • 7.
  • 8.
  • 9.
  • 10.
  • 11.
  • 12.
  • 13.
  • 14.
  • 15.
  • 16.
  • 17.
  • 18.
  • 19.
  • 20.
  • 21.
  • 22.
  • 23.
  • 24.
  • 25.
  • 26.
  • 27.
  • 28.
  • 29.
  • 30.
  • 31.
  • 32.
  • 33.
  • 34.
  • 35.
  • 36.
  • 37.
  • 38.
  • 39.
  • 40.
  • 41.
  • 42.
  • 43.
  • 44.

Notes de l'éditeur

  1. In the Bizarre world of Anti Trust Pricing, any price a company charges for its good or services could be considered illegal. If your price is lower than your competitors’, you could be charged with being a “predator” for anti-competitive “predatory pricing.” If your price is “too high”, you could be charged with anti-competitive monopoly pricing, or “price gouging”. And if your price is the same as your competitors, you could be charged with collusion and anti-competitive price-fixing.
  2. Our team investigated a broad area of unfair pricing practices. We were able to identify seven different areas of potentially illegal pricing. We have tried to illustrate the principles with cartoons, drama and references to court rulings Managers and the legal environment – Bagley & Savage Source - http://library.findlaw.com/1999/Jan/1/241454.html - Executive Summary Of The Antitrust Laws - By Richard M. Steuer of Mayer Brown LLP http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Competition_law
  3. Http://iris.nyit.edu/~shartman/mba0101/trust.htm
  4. Source - http://library.findlaw.com/1999/Jan/1/241454.html - Executive Summary Of The Antitrust Laws - By Richard M. Steuer of Mayer Brown LLP Managers and the legal environment – Bagley & Savage FTC Guide to the Antitrust Laws - http://www.ftc.gov/bc/antitrust/manufacturer_requirements.shtm The Sherman Act of 1890, which prohibits contracts, combinations, and conspiracies in restraint of trade, and monopolization, includes criminal penalties when enforced by the government. Violation can result in substantial fines and, for individual transgressors, prison terms. In addition, court orders restraining future violations are also available. These provisions are enforced primarily by the Antitrust Division of the Justice Department. The Clayton Act was first enacted in 1914 and significantly amended in 1936 by the Robinson-Patman Act and in 1950 by the Celler-Kefauver Antimerger Act. The Clayton Act, which deals with specific types of restraints including exclusive dealing arrangements, tie-in sales, price discrimination, mergers and acquisitions, and interlocking directorates, carries only civil penalties and is enforced jointly by both the Antitrust Division and the Federal Trade Commission (FTC), but with the FTC in practice assuming almost total responsibility for the Robinson-Patman Act's strictures against anticompetitive price discrimination. The Federal Trade Commission Act, administered solely by that agency, is a catch-all enactment which has been construed to include all the prohibitions of the other antitrust laws and, in addition, may be utilized to fill what may appear to be loopholes in the more explicit regulatory statutes. Both the Antitrust Division and the FTC have broad investigatory powers to uncover antitrust violations. Yet, despite the breadth of this authority, they are subject to constitutional and statutory limitations. It is therefore essential, when contacted by an enforcement agency, to consult counsel at once. Over and above this awesome panoply of governmental enforcement, the Clayton Act arms a person who can establish that he or she has been injured by virtue of any antitrust violation with the substantial weapons of a private suit in the federal courts for treble the damages sustained plus reasonable attorneys' fees and a court order restraining future violations. In many instances, the specter of substantial liability for treble damages, not to mention the cost of defending such suits, is a far more significant deterrent to antitrust infraction than the threat of criminal sanctions. Source: FindLaw.com Executive Summary Of The Antitrust Laws
  5. Information on all other national competition laws can be found at http://www.justice.gov/atr/contact/otheratr.htm OECD Guidelines on predatory pricing - http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/7/54/2375661.pdf
  6. Horizontal price fixing is an agreement between competitors or businesses at the same level of competition arranging to set a common price. It is the most direct way to reduce competition [1]. Includes: Setting prices (including maximum prices) Setting the terms of sale Setting quantity/quality of goods to be manufactured or made available for sale Rigging bids [2] In their Wisconsin Law Review Article, Robert Hande and Howard Marvel also categorize collusion as Type I and Type II collusion. Type I, or Classic, collusion involves parties colluding to directly raise prices. Type II collusion occurs when parties collude to disadvantage another rival, eventually enabling the colluding parties to raise prices. They also propose a Type III collusion, where competition is indirectly affected (for example by the parties agreeing to ban advertising and limit information to consumers or raise consumers’ search costs [3] Emerson, R. Business Law , pg. 518 Bagley, C. and Savage, D. Managers and the Legal Environment, 6 th Edition , pg. 650 Hande, Robert H. and Marvel, Howard P., “The Tree Types of Collusion: Fixing Prices, Rivals, and Rules,” Wisconsin Law Review , 2000:941, p. 941, 951, 964
  7. Courts broadly define price fixing. Credit terms and discounts cannot be fixed since inextricably related to price [4] The reason why collusion is treated as a paramount offense is it could lead to monopoly-like outcomes, including monopoly profits shared by colluding parties [5] But it is permitted in some markets; where allowed, referred to as resale or retail price maintenance [6] 4. Emerson, pg. 518 5. Hande, R. and Marvel, H., p. 941 http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Price_fixingf For example, a manufacturer and distributor may agree that the distributor will sell the product at a specified price (resale price maintenance). In Leegan Creative Leather Products, Inc. v. PSKS, Inc. held that vertical price restraints are not per se unlawful, but must be judged under the rule of reason.
  8. Table - Criminal penalties for price fixing 1890-1990 [7] 2 more examples: In the mid-1990’s - Archer Daniels Midland executives were caught on FBI surveillance tapes fixing the price of lysine, a feed additive, with competitors 2005 – Samsung pleads guilty in conspiring with other DRAM (dynamic random access memory) makers to fix prices of DRAM sold to computer and server manufacturers 7. Connor, J. “The Food and Agricultural Global Cartels of the 1990s: Overview and Update” 2002, pg. 22
  9. In the EU, rare exceptions are made when they benefit consumers from technological innovation [10] Before 1995, less than 1% of firms accused of price fixing were foreign firms; after 1997, foreign firms account for over 50%. In 1999, nearly four fifths of fines for price fixing imposed by US Antitrust Division were against foreign firms ($900 million). [11] 10. Connor, pg. 3 11. Connor, pg. 20.
  10. Businesspeople with advanced degrees, such as MBAs, should expect more severe penalties, such as longer prison sentences, as they "should know better.” [12] 12. Gift, Paul “Price Fixing and Minimum Resale Price Restrictions Are Two Different Animals,” Graziadio Business Report , Pepperdine University: Graziadio School of Business and Management, 2009, Vol. 12, Issue 2
  11. U.S. Justice Dept. views horizontal price-fixing as a “hard crime” punishable by prison sentences. In most cases, first time offenders serve a minimum sentence of 6-12 months [13] Liability for antitrust violations is joint and several, i.e. each conspirator could be liable for the losses caused by all of the violators [14] Table - Fines/Prison Sentences Imposed in U.S. DOJ Price Fixing Cases [15] 13, 14. Bagley, C. and Savage, D. pg. 650. 15. Connor, pg. 23
  12. Eastman Kodak Co. v. ITS: The Downfall of the Chicago School - By Ronald S. Katz of Coudert Brothers LLP - http://library.findlaw.com/1992/Jul/1/128101.html
  13. Refers to price fixing in the vertical direction or supply chain. Vertical pricing refers to price controls in the vertical direction. This can also be referred to as resale price maintenance. When a manufacturer sells directly to an end customer, the company clearly controls the customer price and this is not anti competitive. However, when the supply chain involves a distributor or retailer, the manufacturer can no longer control the actual retail price charged. Manufacturers can establish an MSRP or manufacturer’s suggested retail price. A manufacturer can establish an MSRP or manufacturers suggested retail price, but it would be anti-competitive and hence illegal for a manufacturer to dictate that retailers sell at this price. The fact that the suggested price is followed is not enough to show the presence of conspiracy. Maximum Retail Pricing however can be established by a manufacturer. In 1997 State Oil Co. v. Khan the Supreme Court unanimously overturned previous law in establishing manufacturers establishing price ceilings. The Supreme Court stated that from now on price ceilings will be subject to the "rule of reason" and should be lawful in the vast majority of cases. The Court was concerned monopolist dealers in exclusive territories would have complete control over pricing and that there might not be enough local competition to prevent price gouging.   By enforcing a maximum retail price, manufacturers can prevent dealers from charging more than list price for new or scarce products, like the latest iPhone. This will prevent long-term loss of brand goodwill by opportunistic dealers.   http://www.mayerbrown.com/publications/article.asp?id=786&nid=6 http://edition.cnn.com/US/9711/04/scotus.antitrust/index.html Minimum Retail Pricing RPM must be decided on a case by case basis. In 2007 Leegin Creative Leather Products, Inc. v. PSKS, Inc. the Supreme Court overturned previous ruling on minimum price fixing. The law now requires that courts use the “rule of reason” to decide on a case by case basis if manufacturers demanding minimum prices for their goods are violating federal antitrust laws.   This new law is untested and might conflict with prior contracts, franchise laws and even state law.   Establishment of a minimum retail price addresses problems a manufacturer faces when dealers take a free ride by offering heavily discounted prices yet do not offer aftermarket or marketing support for the brand.   Horizontal price fixing remains illegal and manufacturers must be careful to avoid minimum price requests from groups of dealers as this could lead to the manufacturer becoming embroiled in the dealer groups’ horizontal pricing conspiracy. http://www.fredlaw.com/articles/marketing/mark_0707_rjw.html "Rule of reason" determines illegality on a case-by-case basis, whereby "the factfinder weighs all of the circumstances of a case in deciding whether a restrictive practice should be prohibited as imposing an unreasonable restraint on competition.” This rule not only examines circumstances, but also weighs likely harm as well as legitimate business justifications and consumer benefits, i.e. pro-competitive justifications. Thus, minimum RPM is not always legal or illegal, but each case will be analyzed on an individual basis, taking all relevant factors into consideration. It is worth noting that a significant amount of U.S. state law and legislation conforms to the new federal standard, but not all do.
  14. Reference – Peperdine University – Grazadio School of Business - Price Fixing and Minimum Resale Price Restrictions Are Two Different Animals – Dr Paul Gift – http://www.google.com/imgres?imgurl=http://gbr.pepperdine.edu/images/092/rpm1.jpg&imgrefurl=http://gbr.pepperdine.edu/092/rpm.html&usg=__IJJZxeUVUKOMnAP8cHAFEGcGG8o=&h=150&w=200&sz=5&hl=en&start=83&itbs=1&tbnid=XRuoPjURHprfrM:&tbnh=78&tbnw=104&prev=/images%3Fq%3Dantitrust%2Bpricing%26start%3D80%26hl%3Den%26sa%3DN%26gbv%3D2%26ndsp%3D20%26tbs%3Disch:1
  15. United States v Colgate Co. - http://supreme.justia.com/us/250/300/case.html Leegin Creative Leather Products, Inc v PSKS, Inc - http://www.law.cornell.edu/supct/html/06-480.ZS.html 2009 Discount Pricing Consumer Protection Act - http://www.govtrack.us/congress/bill.xpd?bill=s111-148
  16. Links regarding the UK’s net book agreement http://www.independent.co.uk/news/uk/collapse-of-net-book-agreement-within-months-collapse-1388530.html Note that a recent article in the UK’s Guardian newspaper mourns the Net Book Agreement claiming that the large booksellers now have too much control on what books sell, how they are presented and which writers should be bestsellers. http://www.guardian.co.uk/books/booksblog/2010/jun/17/net-book-agreement-publishing
  17. Minimum Retail Pricing RPM must be decided on a case by case basis: In 2007 Leegin Creative Leather Products, Inc. v. PSKS, Inc. the supreme court overturned previous ruling on minimum price fixing. The law now requires that courts use the “rule of reason” to decide on a case by case basis if manufacturers demanding minimum prices for their goods are violating federal antitrust laws. This new law is untested and might conflict with prior contracts, franchise laws and even state law Establishment of a minimum retail price addresses problems a manufacturer faces when dealers take a free ride by offering heavily discounted prices yet do not offer aftermarket or marketing support for the brand Horizontal price fixing remains illegal and manufacturers must be careful to avoid minimum price requests from groups of dealers as this could lead to the manufacturer becoming embroiled in the dealer groups’ horizontal pricing conspiracy http://www.fredlaw.com/articles/marketing/mark_0707_rjw.html "Rule of reason" determines illegality on a case-by-case basis, whereby "the factfinder weighs all of the circumstances of a case in deciding whether a restrictive practice should be prohibited as imposing an unreasonable restraint on competition”. This rule not only examines circumstances, but also weighs likely harm as well as legitimate business justifications and consumer benefits (i.e., procompetitive justifications). Thus, minimum RPM is not always legal or illegal, but each case will be analyzed on an individual basis, taking all relevant factors into consideration. It is worth noting that a significant amount of U.S. state law and legislation conforms to the new federal standard, but not all do.
  18. The other definition of price gouging is the raising of prices above the market rate that would prevail in a competitive environment, by a monopoly.
  19. Additionally, it is a violation of §501.204 of the Florida Unfair and Deceptive Trade Practices Act (FDUTPA) for a person, his or her agent, or employee, during a declared state of emergency, to rent or sell or offer to rent or sell at an unconscionable price within the state of emergency area, any essential commodity including, but not limited to, supplies, services, provisions, or equipment that is necessary for consumption or use as a result of a declared state of emergency. This prohibition remains in effect until the declaration of emergency expires or is terminated. The Price Gouging Statute covers only essential commodities. A “commodity” means any good, service, material, merchandise, supplies, equipment, resources, or other article of commerce, and includes, without limitation, food, water, ice, chemicals, petroleum products, and lumber necessary for consumption or use as a direct result of the emergency. The law also requires those selling goods and services to possess an occupational license. Examples of non-essential items luxury items are alcoholic beverages and cigarettes. The price gouging law does not define “unconscionable," "gross disparity," or "grossly exceeds.“ Price gougers are subject to hefty civil and criminal penalties. In addition to all other remedies FDUTPA provides, a court may impose a civil penalty of not more than $1,000 per violation, with the aggregate not to exceed $25,000 for any 24-hour period against the price gouging law violators. Additionally, it is a second degree misdemeanor for any person to offer goods and services for sale to the public during a state of emergency without an occupational license. The Department of Agriculture and Consumer Services, the office of the state attorney, or the Department of Legal Affairs may enforce Florida's price gouging law.
  20. On August 14, 2004, Attorney General Christ announced the creation of the Attorney General's Hurricane Task Force, which mobilized criminal and civil investigators statewide to investigate price gouging complaints. Based on their investigations, the attorney general filed numerous civil complaints against several individuals and businesses. Such as, 1.Days Inn Airport, West Palm Beach (State of Florida v. Janus Hotels and Resorts, Inc., Complaint, available at myfloridalegal.com/daysinncomplaint.pdf; myfloridalegal.com/JanusAVC.pdf) A billboard in close proximity to the Days Inn Airport advertised rooms for less than $50 per night. After Hurricane Charley, the hotel charged more than double that amount to three consumers. Two were forced to pay $109 per night, while the hotel charged $119 for the third. The hotel told the consumers that it had "only two rooms left," thereby creating a sense of urgency to pay the inflated price. The hotel settled the lawsuit for $70,000 with $10,000 of the settlement for consumer restitution and the remainder went to the costs of the investigation and to the Florida Hurricane Relief Fund. 2. Payless Inn & Suites, Ocala (State of Florida v. Ocala Inn Management, Inc., Complaint, available at myfloridalegal.com/paylesscomplaint.pdf) A 77-year old woman, with her husband and disabled daughter, fled their Tampa home because it was in a designated evacuation zone. The family checked into the Payless Inn after seeing a highway billboard advertising a 50 percent discount for senior citizens. The next day, the hotel charged the family $160.49 for a one-night stay. Later that day, the family found a booklet advertising rates for only $29.99 a night, with a $10-per-person charge for additional guests. Two days later, the inn quoted a rate of $59.99 over the phone. The hotel told another consumer that only two rooms were available at a rate of $129.90. The hotel told the consumer that the high price stemmed from the room being a suite. In fact, the room was not a suite, but a regular room. Soon after, the consumer called the hotel to learn that a regular room was $79 a night. 3. Baymont Inns & Suites, Naples (State of Florida v. Baymont Inns Hospitality, LLC, Complaint, available at myfloridalegal.com/baymontcomplaint.pdf) The Baymont Inns & Suites charged three consumers more at check-out than the price quoted to them when they made their reservations. The first consumer received a quote of $53.99 per night. During check-out three days later, the hotel charged her 33 percent more, $71.99 for the first two days, and $89.10 for the third day, or 65 percent above the quote. After she protested, the hotel reduced the rate for the third day charges to $71.99, but refused to honor the $53.00 quote for the first two days. The hotel charged a second consumer $93.60 after receiving a 10 percent AAA discount. The hotel, however, quoted a rate between $49 and $64 per night. A third consumer reserved a room for herself, a friend, and a dog at a quoted rate of $55 per night. The hotel tried to charge her $99 per night, but upon her objection, the hotel reduced the rate to $79 per night, still 44 percent higher than the originally quoted price. 4. ABC Restoration, Inc. d/b/a Dr. Dry (State of Florida v. ABC Restoration, Inc., Complaint, available at myfloridalegal.com/DrDryComplaint.pdf) Dr. Dry sent an employee on August 16, 2004, to assess water damage at a consumer's home. Dr. Dry's employee quoted a price of $6,500 to $7,500 to repair the couple's porch ceiling and upstairs screens and to remove the carpet from a room adjacent to the porch. The business removed the carpet, left it on the front lawn, moved furniture from an upstairs room to the porch, and then demanded $12,000 to complete the remaining work. Dr. Dry also provided a quote of $5,000 to remove furniture and wet carpeting from another home. The consumer in that home authorized Dr. Dry to charge her credit card $5,000 upon completion of the work. The workers placed 10 large fans and three dehumidifiers in the woman's home and made large holes in her ceilings to allow for drainage. Dr. Dry then demanded an additional $6,500 to complete the work. Later, the woman discovered that Dr. Dry had charged her credit card even though Dr. Dry never completed the agreed-upon work. The business then refused to give her a refund. Also, on August 17, Dr. Dry removed 24 square yards of wet carpet from a Ft. Myers home. The removal took one hour to complete, for which Dr. Dry charged a fee of $22 per square yard. The standard industry price for the service should have been $3 to $8 per square yard. 5. Sun State Trees & Property Maintenance, Inc. (State of Florida v. Sun State Trees & Property Maintenance, Inc., Complaint, available at myfloridalegal.com/sunstatecomplaint.pdf) Two Winter Park neighbors obtained an estimate from Sun State, after three trees in one man's yard fell onto another house, damaging the roof. Sun State provided an estimate of $30,000 for tree removal services and gave invoices for $15,000 to each of the neighbors. Sun State removed one tree on August 15, 2004, two days after Hurricane Charley hit Florida, and arranged to return the next day to remove the remaining trees. The next day, the neighbors complained about the high cost of the tree removal service, and Sun State offered to complete the job for a total cost of $11,000. The average price in Central Florida for the removal of three trees during the 30-day period preceding the declaration of a state of emergency was approximately $3,359.14. 6. John Charles Mikell and John Tate Mikell (State of Florida v. John Charles Mikell et al., Complaint, available at myfloridalegal. com/MikellComplaint.pdf) A man and his son traveled to Santa Rosa County and sold generators from a pickup truck and horse trailer parked on a roadside. They sold 22 generators for $650 each. The investigators determined that the manufacturer's suggested retail price for that model generator was $299.99, meaning the price offered for the generators was more than double the retail price.
  21. Laws against price gouging In the United States, laws against price gouging have been held constitutional as a valid exercise of the police power to preserve order during an emergency, and may be combined with anti-hoarding measures. Exceptions are prescribed for price increases that can be justified in terms of increased cost of supply, transportation or storage. Statutes generally give wide discretion not to prosecute: in 2004, Florida determined that one-third of complaints were unfounded, and a large fraction of the remainder were handled by consent decrees, rather than prosecution. Proponents of laws against price gouging assert that it can create an unrealistic psychological demand that can drive a non-replenishable item into extinction. Opposition to laws against price gouging Some support the ability to raise prices under such circumstances, asserting that government prohibition of the practice is a violation of individual rights or that the ability to raise prices has beneficial effects or both. Libertarians are among those who think firms should be allowed to charge what they want regardless of the circumstances. Free market economists Thomas Sowell and Walter E. Williams, among others, argue against laws that interfere with large price changes. According to this view, high prices can be viewed as information for use in determining the best allocation of scarce resources for which there are multiple uses. For example, after a storm has felled numerous trees in a locality, a rise in the price of chain saws will discourage their purchase by people with only a minor need for them, making them more available for those with the strongest need. Problems during the 1870 Siege of Paris, which critics attribute to price restrictions, are often held up as another example. Free market economists, in effect, reject the term "price gouging," and argue that laws against price increases serve only to restrict supplies of a good or service by reducing the incentive suppliers have to undertake any additional costs, hazards or inconvenience that may be required. They argue further saying that these price increases force consumers to ration goods thus increasing the longevity of certain resources in an emergency. Moral arguments Both proponents and opponents of laws outlawing price gouging make moral arguments. Proponents of the laws state that when some people are priced out of a market in an emergency, they can be severely hurt (and in the case of food and water price gouging, could even lose their lives). Thus those with limited financial resources are at a disadvantage relative to those who are wealthier. Further, proponents of the laws assert that it is simply unfair for a supplier of goods to receive an unearned windfall at the expense of other people. Opponents of the laws state that, when an emergency combined with anti-gouging laws causes important goods to disappear from the shelves on a first-come first-served basis, the people who need them most may not get them; but with price rises, people whose need for the goods is not strong will refrain from buying them, making them available for the people with the strongest need. In this view, people who most need the goods but don't get them, because of shortages due to non-market-clearing prices, could be severely hurt (or again, in the case of food and water shortages, could even lose their lives).
  22. Cartels Cartels usually occur in an oligopolistic industry, where there is a small number of sellers and usually involve homogeneous products. The most famous, or infamous, example is the Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC). Cartel members may agree on such matters as price fixing, total industry output, market shares, allocation of customers, allocation of territories, bid rigging, establishment of common sales agencies, and the division of profits or combination of these. The aim of such collusion (also called the cartel agreement) is to increase individual members’ profits by reducing competition. One can distinguish private cartels from public cartels. In the public cartel a government is involved to enforce the cartel agreement, and the government's sovereignty shields such cartels from legal actions. Contrariwise, private cartels are subject to legal liability under the antitrust laws now found in nearly every nation of the world. Competition laws often forbid private cartels. Identifying and breaking up cartels is an important part of the competition policy in most countries, although proving the existence of a cartel is rarely easy, as firms are usually not so careless as to put agreements to collude on paper. Monopoly Monopolies are characterized by a lack of economic competition for the good or service they provide and a lack of viable substitute goods.
  23. The protection of international competition is governed by international competition agreements. In 1945, during the negotiations preceding the adoption of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) in 1947, limited international competition obligations were proposed within the Charter for an International Trade Organization. These obligations were not included in GATT, but in 1994, with the conclusion of the Uruguay Round of GATT Multilateral Negotiations, the World Trade Organization (WTO) was created. The Agreement Establishing the WTO included a range of limited provisions on various cross-border competition issues on a sector specific basis.
  24. Violations of the Sherman Act involving agreements between competitors are usually punishable as criminal felonies.
  25. Copyright, patents and trademarks are examples of government-granted monopolies.
  26. American Bar Association – Predatory Pricing – Google Books http://books.google.co.uk/books?id=K7OLLYMRdv4C&printsec=frontcover&dq=predatory+pricing&source=bl&ots=ZgXMAk3JnL&sig=E_P7aBB9XbYbM7NmQJ88lT6DquA&hl=en&ei=sPMXTPaHOMWblgfD6OXSCw&sa=X&oi=book_result&ct=result&resnum=6&ved=0CDMQ6AEwBQ#v=onepage&q&f=false Judge Easterbrook Quote - Stopping Above-Cost Predatory Pricing - Yale Law Journal - http://www.yalelawjournal.org/the-yale-law-journal/content-pages/stopping-above%11cost-predatory-pricing/
  27. Predatory Pricing lecture by Kerry Tan - http://web.econ.ohio-state.edu/~tan/E367/lecture3_predatorypricing.pdf
  28. Predatory Pricing lecture by Kerry Tan - http://web.econ.ohio-state.edu/~tan/E367/lecture3_predatorypricing.pdf Managers and the legal environment – Bagley & Savage 1970 Matsushita Electronic Industrial Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp. http://caselaw.lp.findlaw.com/cgi-bin/getcase.pl?friend=nytimes&court=US&vol=475&invol=574&pageno=588 Brooke Group v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco http://www.law.cornell.edu/supct/html/92-466.ZS.html
  29. The Herbert Dow story from The politically incorrect guide to American history   By Thomas E. Woods And http://www.thefreemanonline.org/featured/herbert-dow-and-predatory-pricing/# Wal-Mart Germany Story – NY Times 2000 Edmund L Andrews
  30. Predatory Pricing lecture by Kerry Tan - http://web.econ.ohio-state.edu/~tan/E367/lecture3_predatorypricing.pdf
  31. Price Discrimination in Anti-Trust pricing is defined as the illegal charging of different prices to different purchasers of goods that are of “like grade and quality”, when the price differences are not justified by cost differences. Note that the purchasers must be of the same distribution level. The Robinson-Patman (RP) Act was established in 1936. Historically, it was referred as the "anti-chain store act“. RP Act was intended to prohibit monopolization by curbing the power of large retail chains, thus enabling smaller independent retailers to compete with the retail chains. However, as seen in the next slide, the RP Act contains many elements, making it very difficult to prove illegal price discrimination. References Bagley, C.E. and Savage, D.W. (2010) Price Discrimination: The Robinson-Patman Act. In: Managers and the Legal Environment: Strategies for the 21 st Century, 6e, pages 665-667. Emerson, R.W. (2009) Robinson-Patman Act. In: Barrons’ Business Law, 5e, pages 525-526. Steuer, R.M. (1999) http://library.findlaw.com/1999/Jan/1/241454.html SPG Insights (2006) http://www.imakenews.com/strategicpricing/e_article000649775.cfm?x=b11,0,w Dukes, A.J. (2003) http://findarticles.com/p/articles/mi_qa4026/is_200307/ai_n9292644/
  32. Illegal price discrimination occurs if the different prices charged result in substantial injury to: (1) buyers' competition (injury in the secondary line) - buyers must compete geographically, and on the same functional level. If both purchasers are ultimate consumers and do not compete in resale of the product, no violation can be found. (2) sellers' competition (injury in the primary line) – lower discriminatory (predatory) price damages the seller’s competitors by making them lose business. This is essentially the same as the Predatory pricing section (Section 5) discussed previously. Assuming that the supplier sells in interstate commerce, each of the following five elements must be present in order to prove illegal price discrimination under the RP Act. Discrimination - This standard is met simply by charging different prices to different customers. Sales to Two or More Purchasers - The different prices must be charged on reasonably contemporaneous sales to two or more purchasers - a rule that permits price fluctuations. In other words, it is inappropriate under the statute to compare two widely separated sales in a highly volatile market. Yet if prices typically change annually or semiannually, a sale made in January may be compared with one made in March. In addition, offering different prices is not enough. Actual sales or agreements to sell at different prices must exist. Goods – RP Act applies to the sale of goods only; services, such as telecommunications, banking, and transportation, are not covered. Like Grade and Quality - The goods involved must be physically or essentially the same. Brand preferences are irrelevant, but functional variations can differentiate products. Reasonable Probability of Competitive Injury - The law generally focuses on injury at one of two levels: “primary line” or “secondary line”. The primary line injury had been discussed in the Predatory Pricing section. Far more common is “secondary line” injury, where a supplier’s disfavored reseller or end-user customer may sue the supplier for price discrimination. However, the law is clear that only competing customers must be treated alike. To the extent that customers do not compete due to their locations or the markets they serve, different prices are appropriate under the RP Act. Defenses to Price Discrimination Even if all five price-discrimination elements are present, there are three defenses that may be used to avoid what otherwise is unlawful discrimination. Cost Justification - This defense permits a price disparity if it is based on legitimate cost differences. Meeting Competition - Under this defense, discrimination is permissible if it is based on a good-faith belief that a discriminatory price is necessary to meet the price of a competitive supplier to the favored customer or to maintain a traditional price disparity. Changing Conditions - Special prices may be provided to sell perishable, seasonal, obsolete, or distressed merchandise, even though the full price had been charged up to the point of offering the special prices. References Bagley, C.E. and Savage, D.W. (2010) Price Discrimination: The Robinson-Patman Act. In: Managers and the Legal Environment: Strategies for the 21 st Century, 6e, pages 665-667. Emerson, R.W. (2009) Robinson-Patman Act. In: Barrons’ Business Law, 5e, pages 525-526. Steuer, R.M. (1999) http://library.findlaw.com/1999/Jan/1/241454.html SPG Insights (2006) http://www.imakenews.com/strategicpricing/e_article000649775.cfm?x=b11,0,w Dukes, A.J. (2003) http://findarticles.com/p/articles/mi_qa4026/is_200307/ai_n9292644/
  33. U.S. law had focused on prohibiting price discrimination as a means to preserve market competition by maintaining the viability of numerous sellers. While price discrimination has been unlawful since 1914, the RP Act amended existing legislation in 1936, so this entire area is commonly referred to by the name of the amendment. In the early twentieth century, a chain store could bargain with suppliers for cheaper prices because it bought large quantities of goods. Because the traditional local retailers, so-called mom-and-pop shops, were not entitled to these bargain prices, chain stores' discounts were generally viewed as unfair. The RP Act was a result of this public outcry against the chain store. The act prohibits sellers from charging different prices to different buyers for identical products when the effect might be injurious to competition. The act was intended to eradicate the competitive advantage of the chain store. But since 1936, the economic benefit of the RP Act has been debated. On the one hand, RP Act is one way to ensure that competitors will be protected from those whose only advantage is size. Thus, RP is seen as preserving market competition. On the other hand, many anti-trust economists disagree with this reasoning and argue that the act rewards less-efficient competitors, imposes higher prices and lower sales, and provides less economic benefit overall. Since passage of RP Act, many cases involving alleged violations of the act have been examined by the courts. Courts have generally ruled in favor of the defendant. Examples In Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp. , 509 U.S. 209, 220 (1993), the U.S. Supreme Court held that the RP Act does not "ban all price differences charged to different purchasers of commodities of like grade and quality". Instead, the Act proscribes "price discrimination only to the extent that it threatens to injure competition”. Therefore, the plaintiff must prove that the defendant’s practice of price discrimination has caused injury to his/her business. On January 10, 2006, the U.S. Supreme Court issued its decision in Volvo Trucks North America, Inc. v. Reeder-Simco GMC, Inc . Reeder-Simco GMC, Inc. (Reeder), an authorized dealer of heavy-duty trucks manufactured by Volvo Trucks North America, Inc. (Volvo), generally sold those trucks through a competitive bidding process, whereby the retail customer describes its specific product requirements and invites bids from dealers. Once a Volvo dealer receives the customer’s specifications, it requests a discount or "concession" from Volvo off the normal wholesale prices. Volvo decides on a case-by-case whether to offer a concession. The dealer then uses its Volvo discount in preparing its bid; it purchases trucks from Volvo only if and when the retail customer accepts its bid. Retail customers normally solicited bids from only one Volvo dealer. In the atypical cases in which a retail customer solicited bids from more than one Volvo dealer (so-called "head-to-head" situations), it was Volvo’s stated policy to offer the same price concession to each dealer. In 1997 after Volvo had announced plans to streamline its dealer network, Reeder learned that Volvo had given another dealer a price concession greater than the discounts Reeder typically received. Suspecting it would not be retained as a Volvo dealer, Reeder filed suit against Volvo, claiming Volvo’s pricing practices constituted unlawful price discrimination under section 2(a) of the RPA. Following a jury trial, Reeder was awarded $4 million in damages on its RPA claim. In a 2-1 decision, the U.S. Court of Appeals for the Eighth Circuit affirmed the jury’s verdict. The Supreme Court granted certiorari on March 7, 2005 and the case was argued on October 31, 2005. On January 10, 2006, in a 7-2 decision (Justice Stevens, joined by Justice Thomas, dissenting), the Supreme Court reversed the Eighth Circuit because the Court held that Reeder’s evidence failed to establish the competitive injury required under the RP Act. With this case, the Court once again emphasized that it is the plaintiff’s burden to meet the RP Act’s "competitive injury" requirement. Because of the 2006 ruling of the U.S. Supreme Court, the Third Circuit Court reversed price discrimination judgment in Feesers v. Michael Foods and Sodexho earlier this year. In June 2009, a federal judge in Pennsylvania issued a rare plaintiff's judgment in a RP Act. The court found that local Harrisburg food distributor Feesers had proved its claim that Michael Foods, the largest producer of liquid eggs in the United States, had discriminated against it in the pricing of egg and potato products sold to both Feesers and the multi-national food service management firm, Sodexo. The Third Circuit Court did not contest that Feesers had shown that—on average and over time—Michael Foods sold egg products to Sodexo at lower prices. However, the appellate court focused on the statute's requirement of competitive injury from price discrimination, and in particular on the requirement that two purchasers of products from a single manufacturer be in competition with each other for "the same dollar." The Third Circuit found that food service management firms, such as Sodexo, and food distributors, such as Feesers, are not competing purchasers because they do not compete in the same bid markets. Therefore, Feesers cannot satisfy the competitive injury requirement of price discrimination of the RP Act. References SPG Insights (2006) http://www.imakenews.com/strategicpricing/e_article000649775.cfm?x=b11,0,w Dukes, A.J. (2003) http://findarticles.com/p/articles/mi_qa4026/is_200307/ai_n9292644/http://www.law.cornell.edu/supct/html/92-466.ZS.html (1993) http://www.law.cornell.edu/supct/html/92-466.ZS.html McDermott Newsletters (2006) http://www.mwe.com/index.cfm/fuseaction/publications.nldetail/object_id/6851e0cb-31b3-4c31-b06c-4bede6eeb8a4.cfm Duncan, R.A. and Williams, M.K. (2010) http://www.faegre.com/showarticle.aspx?Show=10778
  34. EU Perspective Under EU law, for example, article 82 prohibits companies with a dominant position from applying dissimilar conditions to equivalent transactions with other trading parties, thereby placing the trading parties at a competitive disadvantage. Accordingly, not just any price discrimination is actionable under article 82; the price discrimination must be imposed by a company with a dominant position. Note that “dominant market power” is not a requirement under U. S. law. There are few EU cases dealing with pure price discrimination, without some other form of competitive abuse. One such case involves EU airlines. In December 2003, the European Commission launched a probe into claims that E.U. airlines have engaged in illegal price discrimination to charge different fares for the same flight according to the national residence of the passenger buying the ticket. Initial evidence had suggested that a fare booked on an airline Web site varied by as much as 300 percent, depending on which country the booker entered as their place of residence. One example was a Frankfurt-Berlin flight, which cost €88 if booked in Germany but €268 if booked in Belgium. The Commission cracked down on airline Web site price discrimination by writing to 18 leading E.U.-based airlines. All but two, Alitialia and Olympic Airways, responded that while they may have indulged in discriminatory practices in the past, they had now desisted. Tests by the Commission verified these claims. A statement from the Commission said: "In rare cases some restrictions may still exist for certain paper-based tickets, but all electronic tickets are now available throughout the E.U. without discrimination, except, in some cases, for differences in handling fees. As a result, price levels are now similar for all E.U. residents.” References Miller, W.T. and Shaw, K.N. (2010) http://www.globalcompetitionreview.com/reviews/20/sections/71/chapters/787/eu-us-comparison-pricing/ Business Travel News (2004) http://www.allbusiness.com/transportation-communications/transportation-services/4136942-1.html
  35. Managers need to make sure that similar pricing is used when selling goods to different customers of the same geographical area and functional level. For example, if a company has a volume discount program, it could end up discriminating in price among the different purchasers depending on the purchasers’ volumes. But if the company has made the discount program reasonably available to all purchasers, even if some purchasers currently lack sufficient sales to qualify for higher volume discounts, the company is not liable. Managers need to be aware that, despite it is very difficult to prove illegal price discrimination, lagging or resentful rivals may use the RP Act as a misguided and wasteful way to battle a leading competitor. References Dukes, A.J. (2003) http://findarticles.com/p/articles/mi_qa4026/is_200307/ai_n9292644/
  36. It’s important to understand the differences between BUNDLING and TYING of products. Bundling is a marketing decision, a packaging strategy. It is a legal commercial practice where a company offers several products or services together in a combined offering. Typically, this strategy is used to configure margin-rich solutions, to offer desired complimentary products or services in a convenient and affordable way, and to further differentiate from competition who may only offer a partial or incomplete solution. Tying is an often illegal use of market power to limit consumer choice or competitive forces by making the sale of product or service conditional upon the sale of another product or service. Oftentimes the tied products or services are unrelated or not desired by the purchaser. This practice has historically been seen as an unfair, unethical, or anti-competitive use of economic power.
  37. Tying of products can be broken down into two different categories. Horizontal tying deals with the conditional sale of unrelated goods. Vertical tying is the conditional sale of related goods. While vertical tying could be defended as characterized as bundling, Horizontal tying is much harder to defend or justify. The key concept with tying is that of economic power. If a conditional sale is made possible because of the seller’s dominant market position or market influence, it could be seen as anticompetitive. This is particularly true when the tied item is not desired by consumers or is of a sub-standard or poor quality relative to competitive products. Typically, there are four conditions that must be met in order to establish unlawful tying. Just because a situation meets these four criteria does not mean that the practice is unlawful. However, these four conditions must be met (at a minimum) if unlawful tying is to be argued.
  38. Most states have laws against Tying of products. There are key provisions within the Sherman AntiTrust Act and the Clayton Act that relate to tying of products. Other significant legislation and policy that extends or further clarifies the notion of Tying. The Bank Holding Company Act Amendments clarify the practice of bundling and tying within the financial services industry. The Magnuson-Moss Warranty Act clarifies a seller’s rights and responsibilities as it relates to service and warranties primarily for consumer goods. Perhaps the most notable court case related to bundling and tying of products is the United States v. Microsoft. The controversy over Internet Explorer and Windows Media Player is a highly visible and well known consideration of market power and the impact on competition and consumer choice. Some recent court cases has suggested that the presence or exercise of market power is not necessarily anti-competitive or illegal. Jefferson Parish Hospital District v. Hyde and Illinois Tools Works v Independent Ink are two rulings that have raised the burden of proof for demonstrating that a company’s exercise of market power is bad for consumers or illegally restricts competition.
  39. In the European Union, there are also laws against unlawful tying of products. Tying in European law is summarized as unconnected supplementary obligations. As in the United States, the intent behind this legislation is to promote competition and to ensure market power is not used to unduly restrict consumer choice. In the EU, Microsoft had to pay a E497 million Euro fine for anti-competitive practices related to Windows Media Player.
  40. The discussion of Tying has key implications for commercial managers making decisions about packaging or bundling multiple products or services into an integrated offering. Package solutions should be designed to differentiate but not limit competition, to increase not limit consumer choice. While “loss-leaders” are an acceptable marketing strategy, managers should be careful anytime there are broad discrepancies in margin-realization between packaged or bundled products. In generally, packaged solutions should involve closely related products and services. The packaging of unrelated products and services can be more easily characterized as Horizontal Tying.