SlideShare une entreprise Scribd logo
1  sur  23
Télécharger pour lire hors ligne
ECE Department




Monetary Policy According to the
Reserve Bank of Australia
Jonathon Flegg and Mieke Klanker




                            0

                                j.c.flegg@nus.edu.sg | mieke.klanker@sciences-po.org
Contents
1.     Introduction .......................................................................................................................................................2
2.     Inflation-Targeting Pioneer .................................................................................................................................2
Institutional Development and the Australian Economy ....................................................................................................... 2
Reserve Bank Finds its Independence .................................................................................................................................... 4
Board Structure and Current Independence .......................................................................................................................... 6
3.     Inflation-Targeting Framework ...........................................................................................................................8
A Flexible Target ..................................................................................................................................................................... 9
The Operational Target ........................................................................................................................................................... 9
Credibility and Transparency ................................................................................................................................................ 10
4.     Inflation-Targeting Success ............................................................................................................................... 11
Hitting the Target.................................................................................................................................................................. 11
Reducing Inflation Volatility.................................................................................................................................................. 13
Anchoring Inflation Expectations.......................................................................................................................................... 13
A Macroeconomic ‘Free Lunch’ ............................................................................................................................................ 15
5.     Not an Inflation-Targeting ‘Nutter’ ................................................................................................................... 15
Output and Employment Gaps ............................................................................................................................................. 16
Asset Price Bubbles ............................................................................................................................................................... 17
6.     Concluding Remarks ..................................................................................................................................................... 18
7.      Bibliography ................................................................................................................................................................. 20




                                                                                           1
1. Introduction
Since 1993 there has been a silent revolution in way the Reserve Bank of Australia (RBA) conducts monetary
policy. In that year without any fanfare or public pronouncements the RBA quietly moved to developing a new
framework of inflation-targeting. New Zealand was the first country to initiate a similar regime but that had only
been initiated a short three years earlier and operationally was very different to anything being discussed across
in Australia. Certainly in advanced economies just coming out of stagflation the verdict on central banks targeting
inflation was still open.


Now in 2011 the RBA and its framework for targeting inflation are still going strong. The unique framework that
the RBA has developed over time can most aptly be described by three core characteristics: credibility,
transparency and flexibility. The target is distinctive internationally for its flexibility: 2 to 3 per cent inflation, on
average, over the business cycle. What is surprising however is that this amount of flexibility afforded to the RBA
in meeting this medium-term target coexists with a comparatively low-level of political independence. If the RBA
has an Achilles’ heel it is certainly the lack of institutionalised independence from the Government it currently
operates with. Ultimately though it is likely that the three characteristics described above are its great strength,
and maintaining them has afforded the RBA the capacity to steer the real economy through some difficult times.


In this assessment of the RBA’s practice of monetary policy we will first discuss the pioneering days when the RBA
was feeling its way into inflation-targeting, and how and why the framework developed, politically and
experientially, into the distinctive form we observe today. In the next section we will explain the mechanics of the
how the RBA operationalises inflation-targeting, and if given its short history we can regard it as a success. And to
finish we will demonstrate how the unique characteristics of the framework, its focus on credibility, transparency
and flexibility, allow the RBA to also focus on achieving a number of secondary policy objectives.


2. Inflation-Targeting Pioneer
Institutional Development and the Australian Economy
Prior to the Reserve Bank Act of 1959, the government-owned Commonwealth Bank of Australia possessed the
functions of both a central and commercial bank. The Australia Government, judging that these dual roles were
inconsistent, created a new statutory body called the Reserve Bank of Australia, which relieved the
Commonwealth Bank of its duties as a nation’s central bank.


Section 10(2) of the Act specifies the ‘Charter’ of the RBA as:


      It is the duty of the Reserve Bank Board, within the limits of its powers, to ensure that the monetary
      and banking policy of the Bank is directed to the greatest advantage of the people of Australia and


                                                            2
that the powers of the Bank ... are exercised in such a manner as, in the opinion of the Reserve Bank
          Board, will best contribute to:
                a. the stability of the currency of Australia;
                b. the maintenance of full employment in Australia; and
                c. the economic prosperity and welfare of the people of Australia.


    While the ‘Charter’ is clearly loaded with the economics of Keynesian times, actual policy is for the most part free
    to be operationalised by the Government of the day, and in more recent times, the RBA itself. Open to
    interpretation is the meaning of “stability of the currency”. While it could be understood as exchange rate or price
    stability, the RBA now chooses to have the Charter find “practical expression” in the current inflation-targeting
    regime (RBA, 2011).




                            Figure 1: Real Exchange Rate and Terms of Trade (Battellino and Plumb, 2009: 11)



    The Australian economy is as a small and open economy with a high-level of income per capita. However its
    strong dependence on export commodities has led it be susceptible to extreme fluctuations in its terms of trade.
    The Bretton Woods system of pegged exchange rates left the Australian economy vulnerable to debilitating
    booms and busts. In fact the inflexibility of exchange rates was one of the major reasons why Australia was one of
    the only major international economies not to join the IMF when it was established in 1944 (Henry, 2003)1.


    It was little surprise then that Australia was not far behind the United States in moving to a floating currency in
    1983. The event was a culmination of first switching the peg from the British Pound to the US Dollar in 1971, then
    to a trade-weighted exchange rate index in 1974, followed by periodic valuation in 1976. The current floating
    exchange rate dampens the impact of commodity booms and busts on the economy. When exports in Australian


1
 The other major economy that refused to join the IMF was Russia. Prime Minister Chifley was successful in reversing Australia’s
decision not to join in 1947.
                                                                   3
commodities are booming, the Australian Dollar appreciates to provide some dampening to inflation (note the
particularly robust relationship since 1983 in Figure 1)2.


The floating of the exchange rate was an important reform that now assists the RBA to dampen inflation. Because
of its high volatility the Australian Dollar is now commonly referred to by Australians as the “little Aussie battler”.
Floating the currency also allowed for the foreign exchange controls in Australia to be liberalised, leading to the
‘internationalisation’ of the dollar. It now ranks as the sixth most traded currency globally (Battellino and Plumb,
2009: 5).


Abandoning the peg produced its own challenges for monetary policy however. Monetary targeting was adopted
first and then abandoned by 1985, when it had become clear that resulting from financial liberalisation and
innovation the monetary aggregates no longer bore a stable relationship to prices or nominal incomes. In the
period that followed, the approach to monetary policy was could best be described as an ad hoc “checklist” of
indicators (Edey, 2005:3). The Government’s preferred position was to target the Current Account Balance (Bell,
2004), while many at the RBA realised that Australia’s status as a commodity exporter made targeting an external
position infeasibility difficult. This gulf in attitudes set the scene for independence.

Reserve Bank Finds its Independence
Within the Australian media it is an often-repeated maxim that the RBA is independent of the Government. In
practice what is meant is the RBA enjoys de facto independence, a kind that should not be confused with the type
of institutionalised independence we might ascribe to the European Central Bank. The RBA’s de facto
independence was the not a consequence of conscious institutional design, but rather it was the product of a
series of political events culminating in the 1996 Statement on the Conduct of Monetary Policy (RBA, 1996). Prior
to that agreement the status quo, according to the former Governor Ian Macfarlane (in Bell, 2004: 110), was that
the “Treasurer made monetary policy on the advice of the Reserve Bank and the Treasury” indicating a lack of
independence. Prime Minister Keating jealously guarded this arrangement, and once ignited a firestorm in 1990
by boasting to the Federal Press Gallery:


      I have Treasury in my pocket, the Reserve Bank in my pocket, wages policy in my pocket, the financial
      community both here and overseas in my pocket (Keating in Bell, 2004).


The RBA’s credibility suffered greatly as a result of this comment. To maintain the Government’s control over
monetary policy, PM Keating appointed a trusted colleague and former Treasury Secretary, Bernie Fraser, to the
position of RBA Governor in 1989. However once appointed Fraser came to the view, along with many others at
the RBA, that Australian monetary policy should be primarily focused on targeting inflation rather than the


2
 This occurs through greater substitution of imported goods and services for domestically-produced ones and through the
departure of liquidity.
                                                             4
current account deficit, a position upheld by the Government (Bell, 2004: 63). Inflation-targeting had been
    introduced relatively recently in a number of other small and open economies, such as New Zealand and Canada,
    and had been shown to be performing well.


    The decision by Fraser and the RBA to contravene explicit Government policy enraged Keating, at a time when his
    political fortunes were fading3. The inflation-targeting policy was a bureaucratic declaration of independence at a
    time in the political cycle most conducive to such a manoeuvre. Keating confessed in his memoires that going into
    the 1996 election:


          The option for me, near a difficult election, was to have an open brawl with the Bank and [Governor]
          Bernie Fraser. Further away from an election, I would have dealt with the Bank’s unreasonable
          intransigence in much sterner and more decisive terms (Keating in Bell, 2004: 127).


    The incoming Liberal-National Government led by Prime Minister John Howard recognising the strength of
    operational independence and inflation-targeting over the preceding three years, and decided to acknowledge
    the RBA’s independence in the joint Statement on the Conduct of Monetary Policy (RBA, 1996). Like a peace treaty
    it was signed and issued jointly by two equal representatives of both sides of the conflict, the Federal Treasurer
    and the Governor of the RBA.


    The unique evolution of independence for the RBA serves to illustrate a number of characteristics of the
    Australian system of setting monetary policy. Firstly, the RBA does not neatly follow the intuition that
    independence and flexibility go hand-in-hand. The RBA developed as one of the less formally independent central
    banks, yet enjoys a considerable degree of flexibility in achieving its final target.


    Secondly, this anomaly to some degree can be explained by the fact that the introduction of inflation-targeting
    was entirely bureaucratic-led rather than government-imposed. The system that the RBA developed without the
    blessing of the Government is inherently flexible and provides the Board with considerable discretion in how they
    reach the target. It was always within the interests of the RBA to conduct a system that ‘bound their hands’ as
    little as possible and even allowed them to decide on what other macroeconomic goals to focus. However, the
    independence that allowed the RBA to develop inflation-targeting was not bestowed upon them but was because
    it occurred at a unique point in the political cycle when the Government was weak.



3
  By the 1993 Federal Election the Labor Government, credited with the floating of the Australian Dollar in 1983, was struggling to
maintain public support. While inflation was lower, so was Prime Minister Keating credentials on the economy, given the size of the
Government’s deficit and high interest rates. The Liberal-National Coalition failed to secure an election victory in 1993 mainly
because of public concerns about their most well-known policy was to introduce a Goods and Services Tax. However by the 1996
election the Liberal-National Coalition, led by a new leader John Howard, had publicly scrapped the GST policy and went on to win a
strong majority in Parliament.
                                                                 5
This is linked to a final point, the RBA’s independence can hardly be considered institutionalised. While the
    Statement is an agreement between the two parties that has gained acceptance through time, ultimately the RBA
    enjoys its freedom because of its support by from the Government, not despite it. In a way the Government can
    be considered to currently benefit from the political cover for never being directly responsible for raising interest
    rates, but conversely being able to claim responsibility for ‘creating a strong economic environment’ when rates
    remain low. However the strongest source of support of maintaining RBA independence remains their on-going
    perceived performance rather than correct institutional procedure. As Coleman (2004) warned that in different
    economic times and with different political figures the threat of government ‘capture’ still remains at the RBA.

    Board Structure and Current Independence
    The Reserve Bank Board consists of nine members all appointed by the Government: Three executive and six non-
    executive members. The three executive members consist of the Governor, Deputy Governor and the Treasury
    Secretary. The Governor and Deputy Governor are appointed by the Government Treasurer for an eight year
    term, and both are eligible for reappointment and termination. The non-executive members are also appointed
    by the Treasurer. Most non-executive appointments are made from the within the corporate community, and
    there is a tradition of placing one academic on the Board (Bell, 2004)4. To protect anonymity within the Board’s
    membership, neither member-votes nor minutes are publicly reproduced.



                                                        Moderately
                                                        Low Policy
                                                      Independence




                                                      Comparatively            High
                                     High Financial
                                                        Low Overall         Instrument
                                     Independence
                                                      Independence        Independence




                                                           Low
                                                        Personnel
                                                      Independence




                          Figure 2: The RBA according to Cukierman’s (1992) Central Bank Independence Index




    The current RBA’s separation from Government can be understood along the four dimensions of independence
    determined by Cukierman (1992): policy, instrument, personnel, and financial independence. The RBA has high
    instrument independence, but unlike some other inflation-targeting central banks has minimal ability to change




4
 To protect the Board from political ‘capture’ Coleman (2004) has suggested reforming appointments along the lines of the Bank of
England Board to include more economists and public sector representatives from institutions such as the Productivity Commission
or ACCC.
                                                                      6
the policy framework without the agreement of the Government5. However as we have seen the system is quite
    flexible, and for the most part was a framework designed by the RBA themselves between 1993 and 1996. RBA’s
    personnel independence is quite low because all members of the Board are government-appointed, but it is
    responsible for its own budget, giving it substantial financial independence (RBA, 1994: 7; Arnone et al, 2006).


    Compared with other inflation-targeting regimes, the RBA’s overall independence is usually rated as quite low. In
    an assessment of the personal, political and financial independence of central banks, Sousa (2002) placing the
    RBA’s independence second only to the Bank of Canada (see Figure 3). According to a cross-country IMF study by
    Arnone et al (2006), the RBA was the only central bank where political independence diminished between 1991
    and 2003 because of the loss of some “legal protections that strengthen the central bank’s position in the event
    of a conflict with the government” (2006: 5).




                    Figure 3: Accountability versus Independence within inflation-targeting central banks (Sousa, 2002)


    The converse of a lack of independence compared with other central banks is that the RBA is quite accountable to
    Government, and indirectly responsible to the Australian people. This accountability is maintained not only
    through the Board’s appointment system but also through the executive and senior staff appearing at least twice
    a year before the House of Representatives Standing Committee on Economics. However accountability must be
    weighed against the vast literature that has emerged on the positive relationship between central bank
    independence and economic performance 6. The continued rise in home ownership in Australia has only
    strengthened the powerful incentives for politicians to prefer downward-biased interest rates in the short-term.
    This potential political pressure makes the institutionalisation of the RBA’s independence even more vital.



5
  Policy independence refers to the capacity of the central bank to determine its own policy goals and processes, while instrument
independence is a measure of its control over the use of the policy instrument, the short-term official interest rate.
6
  See Bofinger (2001: 216-20) for a summary of the evidence.
                                                                    7
3. Inflation-Targeting Framework
The principal objective of the RBA’s inflation-targeting framework is to achieve price stability through achieving a
predetermined inflation target. In the 1996 Statement the Governor and the Treasurer agreed that the
appropriate official target for monetary policy was a consumer price inflation rate of “2-3 per cent, on average,
over the cycle” (RBA, 1996). The design of the framework allowed “for the natural short run variation in
underlying inflation over the cycle while preserving a clearly identifiable benchmark performance over time”
(RBA, 1996). This line made clear from the beginning the Australian framework was at the flexible end of the
spectrum of inflation-targeting central banks. The distinct characteristics of the Australian inflation-targeting
framework are credibility, transparency and flexibility.




                            Figure 4: Key Characteristics of the RBA’s Inflation-targeting Framework




The 2-3 per cent target was defined based on the best average performances since WWII which were in the “two
point something” region with quite a wide degree of variation around that average (Stevens, 2003:20). According
to Governor Stevens (2003:20) the Bundesbank was also a lead example in defining this target. The RBA’s target
was quite different to what Greenspan was suggesting at the time as an optimal target for the Federal Reserve: “I
would say the number is zero, if inflation is properly measured.”(in FOMC, 1996).




                              Summary of the RBA’s Inflation-targeting Framework
          Measure of inflation                              Headline CPI
          Target band and horizon                           Average of 2-3% over the medium term
          Policy timeline                                   No explicit timeline for corrections
          Policy rate                                       Overnight cash rate
                                 Table 1: Summary of the RBA's Inflation-targeting Framework




The inflation target is expressed in terms of the average rate of increase in the consumer price index (CPI).
Although the ultimate objective for the RBA is specified in terms of headline CPI, an important input into
forecasting inflation are measures of underlying inflation which attempt to abstract from the short-term volatility
in some prices (Richards and Rosewall 2010:7). The measure of underlying inflation most used by the RBA is the
trimmed-mean rate of inflation, the average rate of inflation after ‘trimming’ away a certain percentage of the

                                                               8
distribution of price changes at both ends of that distribution (Richards and Rosewall, 2010:8). In a recent study
Brischetto and Richards (2006) found that trimmed measures tend to out-perform headline and exclusion
measures, which are used by other central banks, on a range of different criteria. In practice, the RBA has tended
to focus on two particular trims: the 15 per cent trimmed mean and the weighted median, which trims 50 per
cent of the distribution from both ends (Richards and Rosewall, 2010:8).




A Flexible Target
The Australian inflation-targeting regime differs in two ways from conventional regimes which are both related to
the definition as “2-3 per cent, on average, over the cycle”. Firstly, unlike other inflating-targeting central banks, is
the RBA is not faced with an explicit timeline to correct deviations from the target band. This allows the Reserve
Bank the flexibility to pay attention to the state of the economy, as measured by output or unemployment, in its
deliberations about the stance of monetary policy.


Secondly, the 2-3 per cent range was not intended to specify outer limits, but rather to convey the idea of an
approximate central tendency, or “thick point”, as Debelle and Stevens (1995: 3) have referred to it. Though other
early adopters of inflation-targeting have a point target (such as the Bank of England), or a range (in New Zealand
and Canada), the RBA had observed that inflation was hard to control in a precise way and attempts to do so over
short periods risked are aggravating the economic instability the RBA is trying to reduce (Stevens 2003:20). Thus
the formulation of the inflation target of the RBA allows for the inevitable uncertainties that are involved in
forecasting and lags in the effects of monetary policy on the economy.




The Operational Target
The formal policy rate is the target cash rate, or the overnight rate, which is a market interest rate (Ho, 2009: 4).
Changes in monetary policy by the RBA entail a change in the operating target for the cash rate, and hence a shift
in the interest rate structure prevailing in the financial system. The two main instruments used by the RBA are
repurchase agreements and discretionary operations. Repurchase agreements are of the deposit facility type with
a ceiling and floor differing with 25 basis points from the prevailing policy rate. Discretionary operations are
mainly repo and reverse repo as well as outright transactions and foreign exchange swaps (Ho 2009). Unlike many
other central banks, such the Federal Reserve, the reserves at the RBA are only used for settlement in the
payments system and not for reserve requirements.

The close relationship between the cash rate and other money market interest rates is demonstrated in Figure 5.
According to Ho (2009: 10), this low volatility is typical for central banks that are targeting the overnight rate. The
RBA has taken up a proactive stance by providing the right amount of liquidity through its discretionary
operations which has made the overnight rate seldom venture towards the boundaries. Furthermore, the RBA has
                                                           9
defined a narrow corridor around the formal policy rate which also serves to dampen short-term market rate
      volatility (Ho 2009: 20).




                                             Figure 5: Short-term Interest Rates (RBA, 2011)




      Credibility and Transparency
      Critical to the RBA’s current strategy is establishing and maintaining credibility and transparency in their
      relationship with the private sector. Compared with previous decades this has managed to solidly anchor
      expectations around the top of the target band. It is important not to understate this achievement. According to
      Governor Stevens (2003:18), after decades of high inflation Australians were suffering from “inflation
      psychology”. The erosion of the value of money that had become a permanent feature for an entire generation of
      Australians was now reversed.

      The RBA is considered to be one of the most transparent central banks in the world. Openness is maintained by a
      regular dialogue with the public, through media releases, speeches and their comprehensive website. Monthly
      decisions pertaining to the cash rate are associated with an explanation of the reasons behind their action or
      inaction. Fracasso et al (2003) , in an comprehensive analysis of the quality and accessibility of information provided
      by inflation-targeting central banks, argue while the RBA’s written inflation reports remain relatively concise they
      rely more heavily on their disseminating data regularly through their website.

      Quarterly the RBA also releases an exhaustive Statement of Monetary Policy which includes detailed forecasting of
      international and domestic market conditions7. Inflation forecasts are a vital part of this statement and thus of the
      RBA’s communication strategy. Forecasts of inflation and GDP growth are point estimates over a 1-2 year period and




7
    See the RBA website (http://www.rba.gov.au/) for records of previous Statements on Monetary Policy.
                                                                   10
crucially assume no change in the instrument (Edey, 2005: 12). There has been some discussion of changing the ‘no
    policy change’ assumption, as it could be misinterpreted by the private sector for expectations of inflation8.

    Credibility is considerably more difficult to establish than transparency, as it presumably requires the private sector
    to develop trust in the RBA’s record of hitting the target over time. Unlike monetary aggregate targeting where the
    private sector can immediately see the proof of the central bank performance, inflation-targeting involves a
    considerable lag before the target is realised. Hence being credible is critical to performance otherwise wages can
    easily get out of control.

    As mentioned above during the early 1990s the RBA suffered a lack of credibility given a string of comments made by
    Prime Minister Keating. Surprisingly though with the advent of inflation-targeting, expectations were quite quick to
    revert to the target band, and since then have stayed relatively stable. Although prior to the Global Financial Crisis it
    appears that the Australian public suffered from some second thoughts about the ability of the RBA to maintain
    inflation, overall the credibility of the current framework and the faith in the competency of the Board’s leadership is
    quite strong.



    4. Inflation-Targeting Success
    There are several approaches we can employ in evaluating the success of the RBA’s inflation-targeting. Assistant
    Governor Debelle (1995) noted that it might be as simple as, “if, some years hence, we can look back and observe
    that the average rate of inflation has a ‘2’ in front of the decimal place that will be regarded as a success”. First,
    we will look at whether the RBA has achieved the target it has set for inflation. Secondly, it is assessed whether
    inflation-targeting has led to lower inflation volatility. Thirdly, the issue of inflation expectations will be dealt with
    by examining whether the inflation ‘psychology’, ubiquitous until the early 1990s, has left Australian mindsets.
    The last section will go into detail on whether IT has been associated with any cost to growth or unemployment.


    Hitting the Target
    For RBA Governors the flexibility of the target makes it not only easier to achieve, but also convenient for claiming
    success. In 2003 Governor Stevens (2003: 21) noted that after ten years of inflation-targeting the average
    inflation rate over the 38 quarters up to December 2002 was 2.4 per cent. In this way, he explained, the inflation
    target had been achieved. Truman (2003) does not view this as much of a surprise. He categorises Australia as a
    “maintainer”, a country that had already achieved its low-level target inflation prior to inflation-targeting being
    adopted.
    Figure 6 shows that if Australia’s target were strict rather than flexible the results would not be encouraging. CPI
    was only in line with the target in the period 2002-2006 and showed deviations (mainly above the 3 per cent

8
  In reality it rarely the case there is no change in the instrument over the timeframe of a 1-2 year forecast, so in this sense forecast
inflation should not be confused with an inflation expectation, because rational actors would expect the RBA to move the
instrument in the event of a forecast outside the target band. Possible reforms might include releasing a probability distribution fan
chart or an endogenous instrument change forecast (such as is done by the Bank of England).
                                                                   11
upper band) during the remaining periods. It is noteworthy that the deviations from the inflation targets have not
been symmetric; while there have been breaches both on the upside and the downside, most have been on the
upside.



                                                 Australian Consumer Price Index
                                  7.0
                                  6.0
          CPI (annual % change)




                                  5.0
                                  4.0
                                                                                                                     lower band
                                  3.0
                                                                                                                     upper band
                                  2.0
                                  1.0                                                                                Consumer price index

                                  0.0
                                         Mar-1993
                                         Mar-1994
                                         Mar-1995
                                         Mar-1996
                                         Mar-1997
                                         Mar-1998
                                         Mar-1999
                                         Mar-2000
                                         Mar-2001
                                         Mar-2002
                                         Mar-2003
                                         Mar-2004
                                         Mar-2005
                                         Mar-2006
                                         Mar-2007
                                         Mar-2008
                                         Mar-2009
                                         Mar-2010
                                  -1.0



                                               Figure 6: CPI inflation, headline from 1993 to 2011 (Source: RBA, 2011)




As the RBA has defined the inflation target as “on average, over the cycle”, it is of interest to take a closer look at
the performance of the main underlying indicator, the weighted median, in terms of its average over the cycle.
Table 2 clearly shows that compared with the pre-period, inflation over the cycle has diminished towards the
target as set by the RBA. However, the most recent cycle shows an upward deviation, partly caused by increased
inflation during the global financial crisis. Though this does not seem to be part of a long term trend, the trimmed
mean CPI of 2010 indicates that inflation has come back to its previous path with an average of 2.6 per cent over
the year. On the whole, the RBA’s flexible inflation target seems to have been achieved by the RBA for the period
of 1993-2010.


                                          CPI inflation, weighted median (on average over the period, in %)
             1985-89                          1990-94           1995-99         2000-04           2005-09                          2010
               7.7                               3.3              2.2             2.6               3.4                             2.6
                            Table 2: 5 Year averaged CPI inflation, trimmed mean (Source: Edey, 2005; and authors’ own calculations)




                                                                                 12
Figure 7: CPI inflation volatility from 1984 to 2008 (Source: Lim, 2009)



Reducing Inflation Volatility
Successful inflation-targeting should not only constraint the level of inflation, but should also reduce its volatility.
Lower inflation volatility would increase credibility and consequently strengthen lower inflation expectations
(Filardo and Genberg 2009: 13). Figure 7 shows that prior to the implementation of the inflation-targeting
framework in 1993, the volatility of CPI decreased considerably. The standard deviation over 5 year periods in
Table 3 shows a similar trend.



                               CPI inflation, weighted median (standard deviation, in %)
          1985-89              1990-94           1995-99          2000-04           2005-09                          2010
            1.1                  1.8               0.4              0.3               0.8                             0.4
        Table 3: 5 Year standard deviation in CPI inflation, trimmed mean (Source: Edey, 2005; and author's own calculations)



Anchoring Inflation Expectations
One of the reasons behind adopting the inflation-targeting framework was it was hoped its credibility would
eventually rein in the nation’s high expectations of future inflation. As Figure 8 shows, inflation expectations in
Australia have decreased greatly with the adoption of inflation-targeting in 1993. This shows that the RBA had
sent out a strong signal that inflation control was a priority. The policy had been well communicated with people
expecting and acting on the prospect of stable prices. The benefit of controlling inflation expectations is it an
additional ‘soft’ method of controlling actual inflation compared with the ‘hard’ cash rate instrument. To the
extent that the economy is ‘self-controlling’ when it comes to inflation, the instrument becomes more available to
realise other secondary goals (Bofinger, 2001: 113; Bernanke, 2004).




                                                                  13
Figure 8: Inflation expectations from 1975 to 2003 (Source: Stevens, 2003)



Figure 9 shows the high correlation between the actual underlying inflation and consumer inflation expectations.
Since introducing inflation-targeting, inflation expectations have been on the upper side of the range defined by the
RBA as shown in Table 4. It seems that there continues to be a significant proportion of households anticipating
inflation higher than defined by the RBA. Particularly in the period leading up to the financial crisis, between
December 2006 and June 2008, inflation expectations exceeded the CPI, and during the global downturn inflation
and inflation expectations both significantly exceeded the target band. This may indicate that the RBA’s credibility
was tested while moving the through the uncharted waters of the crisis.


                                    Consumers' inflation expectation (average, in %)
                                1995-99             2000-04           2005-09                       2010
                                  2.5                  3.1              3.5                          3.1
                   Table 4: 5 Year consumer inflation expectation (Source: RBA, 2011: and authors' own calculations)




                                      Inflation Expectations and CPI
            7.0
            6.0
            5.0
            4.0
            3.0
            2.0
            1.0
            0.0
             Jun-1993 Jun-1995 Jun-1997 Jun-1999 Jun-2001 Jun-2003 Jun-2005 Jun-2007 Jun-2009
           -1.0

                                   Consumers' inflation expectation               Consumer price index

                            Figure 9: Inflation Expectations and CPI from 1993 to 2010 (Source: RBA, 2011)



                                                                  14
Taking a long-term perspective, Finlay and Wende (2011:13) hold that 1-year-ahead inflation expectations are
much more volatile than 5- and 10-year-ahead expectations and are strongly influenced by current inflation.
Longer-term inflation expectations appear to be well-anchored within the 2 to 3 per cent target range.



A Macroeconomic ‘Free Lunch’
Some authors, such as Truman (2003), have argued that inflation-targeting can reduce inflation without
negatively effecting output growth or employment in the real economy, the equivalent of a macroeconomic “free
lunch”. Figures 10 and 11 demonstrate that the lower average level of inflation and the decreased volatility have
not come at the expense of slower or more variable output growth. On the contrary, unemployment is lower and
output variability has decreased.


The conclusion that this is a causal relationship must be taken with a grain of salt though. Global economic
conditions since 1993 have been quite conducive to economic growth and countries that do not target inflation as
part of their monetary policy have seen similar improvements in economic conditions (Filardo and Genberg,
2009). The period also overlaps with the longest resources boom in Australian history.




               Figure 10 and 11: GDP Growth Rate and Unemployment Rate from 1984 to 2008 (Source: Lim, 2009)




5. Not an Inflation-Targeting ‘Nutter’
In 1997 the then Chief Economist of the Bank of England, Mervyn King, coined the term, “inflation nutter” to refer
to the burgeoning number of central banks who appeared to be operating as strict inflation-targeters. The RBA is
certainly not a strict inflation-targeting “nutter”. The combination of being credible and transparent with the
public strengthens low and stable inflation expectations, while the flexibility the RBA enjoys in hitting its medium-
term inflation target, gives considerable ‘room’ in the short-term. The combination of all these attributes permits
the RBA the capacity to also focus on secondary policy objectives, particularly in the short-term. It should be

                                                            15
remembered that the framework affords the RBA the capacity to also focus on secondary policy objectives, but
does not compel them to do so. However since 1993 there is strong evidence that the RBA has made use of this
capacity by targeting short-term output and employment gaps, and more controversially asset price bubbles.




                  Figure12: How the RBA's Policy Framework Affords Secondary Policy Objectives Beyond Inflation




Output and Employment Gaps
If the Reserve Bank Board is in a position to compare two “paths” to the medium-term target, the Pareto-optimal
“path”, as far as welfare is concerned, is the one that causes the least amount of volatility to the real economy. A
typical decision might be to “go hard” now against rising inflation or to “go hard” later. Faced with such a
decision, the Board may decide to use the short-term Phillips Curve to generate ‘surprise’ inflation in order to
achieve the least amount of volatility to output and employment gaps (Debelle, 1995). Or as Bernanke (2004) puts
it, “well-anchored inflation expectations may afford the central bank more short-term flexibility to respond to
economic disturbances that affect output and employment”.




     Figure13: Inflation and Unemployment Gaps and Non-Zero Official Cash Rate Changes from 1993 to 2007 (Source: Lim, 2009)
                                                               16
The evidence since 1993 suggests the RBA frequently has often decided to use this flexibility to target real gaps in
    the economy. Figure 13 shows all non-zero interest rates changes against the inflation and employed gap, with
    black representing positive movements and the white for negative ones. A simple interpretation of the policy of
    strict inflation-targeting should produce positive interest rates changes with positive inflation gaps and vice versa
    for negative inflation gaps9. In about half the Board’s decisions when inflation was high and unemployment was
    high they decided to respond to unemployment by cutting rates. A similar pattern of exceptions to strict inflation-
    targeting can be noticed when interest rate decisions are plotted against the output gap.



    Asset Price Bubbles
    A more controversial notion is that the RBA uses monetary policy to combat perceived asset price bubbles. This
    practice has been likened by Posen (2009) to be a case of, “When the only tool you have is a hammer, it is
    tempting to treat everything as if it were a nail”. There is strong evidence during 2002-04 that this is exactly what
    the RBA did. Concerns built throughout 2002 and 2003 that a property bubble was developing in Australia due to
    the introduction of the first home-buyer grant in 2000 and changes to capital gains exemptions in 1999. In the five
    years following 1997 housing prices doubled, increasing by 40 per cent over 2002 and 2003 alone (Bloxham et al,
    2010: 2). In response the RBA during 2002 to 2004 ‘chased the bubble’ by tightening interest rates. This occurred
    in contrast to increasing interest rates in every other developed economy, and most large developing economies
    during the same period.




                    Figure14: Average Nominal House Prices, Australia and the United States (Source: ABS, Datastream)



9
 This analysis only considers the inflation gap at the time of the interest rate decision, and does not assess projected inflation,
which would be a more appropriate form of analysis. For example, while a current inflation gap might be positive, the trend might
be receding with projected inflation expected to be on or below target. In this case an interest rate reduction might be warranted to
maintain the inflation target.
                                                                   17
As an additional tool the RBA implemented a campaign of ‘open mouth operations’ in an attempt dampen the
     property market, involving repeatedly explanating that monetary policy was actively being used to combat
     “overheating in the property market”10. The most elucidating comment by Governor Stevens that the RBA
     believed in actively targeting the property bubble was, “… a case might be made, on rare occasions, to adopt a
     policy of ‘least regret’ so far as asset prices are concerned, if financial and macroeconomic stability were thought
     to be at risk” (Stevens, 2003).


     The use of monetary policy was remarkably successful in completely halting the growth of the bubble (see Figure
     14), however it is unknown as to what cost to the real economy these interest rate rises came. An interesting ex
     post comparison can be made with the United States, where loose monetary policy is blamed by some for fuelling
     the property boom that culminated in the sub-prime mortgage crisis of 2007 (Taylor, 2009). Now many
     commentators believe Australia is in the midst of another housing bubble, with The Economist (2010) concluding
     that housing prices are currently on average 63 per cent over-valued.



     6. Concluding Remarks
     The pioneering and flexible inflation-targeting of the RBA can be regarded, so far, as a success. However two notes
     of moderation must be trumpeted before we herald the end of Australian monetary history. Firstly, the onset of
     inflation-targeting in Australia has also coincided with the longest commodity boom in Australian history. As a result
     attributing the gains in the real economy during this period to the new monetary framework is problematic. However
     the fact that the framework has largely caged Australia’s decades of post-war inflation is not too much of a stretch to
     suggest. Secondly, the flexibility of the target itself has permitted subsequent Governors to rhetorically get away
     with a fuzzier version of what actually counts as success, compared with stricter frameworks.

     The design of an inflation-targeting framework that focuses on maintaining the triumvirate of credibility,
     transparency and flexibility is a pragmatic way of conducting monetary policy that allows the RBA not to fall into a
     monofocal obsession with simply the monetary phenomenon of inflation. Transparency is a relatively easy reform to
     introduce, one the RBA has achieved through publishing comprehensive volumes of timely explanations of its use of
     the cash rate instrument and forecasts of future inflation and other economic indicators. Credibility is considerably
     harder and involves gaining the private sector’s trust that the economy will, more or less, hit the inflation-target.
     While inflation expectations did get out hand in the period just prior to the Global Financial Crisis, overall




10                   th
   For example on 8 May 2002 a RBA media release stated, “To persist with a strongly expansionary policy setting … could fuel
other imbalances such as the current overheating in the housing market, potentially jeopardising the economy’s continued
expansion”. The quarterly Statement on Monetary Policy in February 2003 reaffirmed to risk of the asset price bubble, “… the
run-up in housing prices and associated expansion in housing related debt were a source of concern for most of the past year,
given the potential of such a process to remain disconnected from fundamentals and develop into a significant imbalance over
time.”

                                                               18
expectations have generally sat nicely around the top of the target band since 1993. The younger generations of
Australians appear no longer afflicted by Steven’s (2003: 18) “inflation psychology”.

Flexibility is the final ingredient that possibly makes the RBA’s framework attractive as a model for other countries
considering reforming monetary policy to emulate. Target flexibility may permit a prudent Reserve Bank Board to
outperform stricter frameworks by also smoothing the volatility felt by the real economy en route to the inflation
target. The policy flexibility the RBA enjoys and its considerable instrument independence is also balanced by a high
degree of accountability to the nation’s democratic government. However this fact may also conceal its greatest
weakness, given that the current institutional arrangement does not protect the RBA’s independence from capture
from a more domineering future Government.




                                                        19
7. Bibliography


Arnone, M., Laurens, B. J. and Segalotto., J.F.

                        (2006). "The Measurement of Central Bank Autonomy: Survey of Models, Indicators, and
                        Empirical Evidence“. IMF Working Paper No. 06/227.

Battellino, R. and M. Plumb

                        (2009). “A Generation of an Internationalised Australian Dollar”. Address to BIS/Bank of
                        Korea Seminar on Currency Internationalisation, Seoul. Retrieved from: http://www.bis.org/ .

Bell, S.                (2004). Australia’s Money Mandarins: The Reserve Bank and the Politics of Money.
                        Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Bernanke, B.            (2004). “Central Bank Talk and Monetary Policy”. Retrieved from:
                        http://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/2004/200410072/default.htm/ .

Bloxham, P., Kent, C. and Robson, M.

                        (2010). “Asset Prices, Credit Growth, and Monetary and Other Policies: An Australian Case
                        Study”. Reserve Bank of Australia Research Discussion Paper 2010-06.

Bofinger, P.            (2001). Monetary Policy: Goals, Institutions, Strategies, and Instruments. Oxford, Oxford
                        University Press.

Brischetto, A. and Richards, A.

                        (2006). The Performance of Trimmed Mean Measures of Underlying Inflation. RBA Research
                        Discussion Paper, December 2006. Retrieved at: http://www.rba.gov.au/ .

Coleman, W.             (2004). “How the Bank Got Its Groove Back”. Retrieved from: http://epress.anu.edu.au/.

Cukierman, A.           (1992). Central Bank Strategies, Credibility, and Independence: Theory and Evidence.
                        Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

Economist, The          (2010, Oct 10). “Global House Prices: Floor to Ceiling”. Retrieved from:
                        http://www.economist.com/.

Edey, M.                 (2005). “An Australian Perspective on Inflation-targeting, Communication and Transparency”.
                         BIS Paper 31, Monetary policy in Asia: approaches and implementation: 3-24.

Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC)

                        (1996). “Meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee, 2-3, 1996”. Retrieved from:
                        http://www.federalreserve.gov/.

Filardo, A. and Genberg, H.

                        (2009). Targeting Inflation in Asia and the Pacific: lessons from the recent past. BIS Working
                        Paper 52.



                                                            20
Finlay, R. and Wende, S.

                        (2011). “Estimating Inflation Expectations with a Limited Number of Inflation-indexed
                        Bonds”. RBA Research Discussion Paper 2011-01.

Fracasso, A., Genberg, H., and Wyplosz, C.

                        (2003). “How do Central Banks Write? An Evaluation of Inflation-targeting Central Banks”.
                        Geneva Reports on the World Economy Special Report 2.

Fraser, B.              (1994). “Central Bank Independence: What Does It Mean?” Reserve Bank of Australia Bulletin
                        December 1994: 1-8.

Henry, K.               (2003). “Australia and the international financial architecture — 60 years on”. Retrieved
                        from: http://www.treasury.gov.au/.

Ho, C.                  (2009). Implementing monetary policy in the 2000s: operating procedures in Asia and beyond.
                        BIS Working Paper 253.

Lim, G.C.               (2009). “Inflation-targeting”. Australian Economic Review, vol. 42(1): 110–118.

Posen, A. S.            (2009). “Finding the Right Tool for Dealing with Asset Price Booms”. Speech to the MPR
                        Monetary Policy and the Economy Conference, London. Retrieved from:
                        http://www.iie.com/publications/papers/posen1209.pdf .

Rasche, R.H. and Thornton, D.L.

                        (2006). “Greenspan’s Unconventional View of the Long-Run Inflation/Output Trade-off.
                        Monetary Trends”. Monetary Trends. Retrieved at: http://research.stlouisfed.org .

Reserve Bank of Australia (RBA)

                        (1996). Statement on the Conduct of Monetary Policy. Retrieved from:
                        http://www.rba.gov.au/monetary-policy/framework/stmt-conduct-mp-1-14081996.html .

                        (2011). “About Monetary Policy”. Retrieved from: http://www.rba.gov.au/monetary-
                        policy/about.html

Richards, A. and Rosewall, T.

                        (2010). “Measuring Underlying Inflation”. In: RBA Statement on Monetary Policy March 2010.
                        Retrieved at: http://www.rba.gov.au/ .

Sousa, P.               (2002). Central Bank Independence and Democratic Accountability. Portucalense University,
                        Mimeo.

Stevens, G.             (2003). “Inflation-targeting: A Decade of Australian Experience”. Reserve Bank of Australia
                        Bulletin April 2003.

Stevens, G. and Debelle, G.

                        (1995). “Monetary Policy Goals for Inflation in Australia”. In A.G. Haldane (ed.), Targeting
                        Inflation: 81-100. London: Bank of England.


                                                            21
Taylor, J. B.   (2009). “The financial crisis and the policy responses: An empirical analysis of what went
                wrong”. NBER Working Paper 14631.

Truman, E.      (2003). Inflation-targeting in the World Economy. Washington, DC: Institute of International
                Economics.




                                                   22

Contenu connexe

Tendances

An Overview Of US Monetary Policy: The Implications of Quantatitive Easing (N...
An Overview Of US Monetary Policy: The Implications of Quantatitive Easing (N...An Overview Of US Monetary Policy: The Implications of Quantatitive Easing (N...
An Overview Of US Monetary Policy: The Implications of Quantatitive Easing (N...danielbooth
 
Central Bank Mania Continues
Central Bank Mania ContinuesCentral Bank Mania Continues
Central Bank Mania ContinuesMark Beckrich
 
julius bär investment opportunities outlook 2014
julius bär investment opportunities outlook 2014julius bär investment opportunities outlook 2014
julius bär investment opportunities outlook 2014Claude Gaudin
 
Exchange Rates and External Adjustment
Exchange Rates and External AdjustmentExchange Rates and External Adjustment
Exchange Rates and External AdjustmentSadaf Zafar
 
12013 forecast topic 5 slides
12013 forecast topic 5 slides12013 forecast topic 5 slides
12013 forecast topic 5 slidesHoward McCallum
 
Daily i-forex-report-1 by epic research 27 may 2013
Daily i-forex-report-1 by epic research 27 may 2013Daily i-forex-report-1 by epic research 27 may 2013
Daily i-forex-report-1 by epic research 27 may 2013Epic Daily Report
 
Weekly Forex News February 10th 2013
Weekly Forex News February 10th 2013Weekly Forex News February 10th 2013
Weekly Forex News February 10th 2013FCTOFX
 
Japan Lost Decade vs US, EZ
Japan Lost Decade vs US, EZJapan Lost Decade vs US, EZ
Japan Lost Decade vs US, EZIndra Pratama
 
Watching for FOMC minutes and yield curves this week
Watching for FOMC minutes and yield curves this week Watching for FOMC minutes and yield curves this week
Watching for FOMC minutes and yield curves this week Hantec Markets
 
Can the EU survive the Eurozone Crisis?
Can the EU survive the Eurozone Crisis?Can the EU survive the Eurozone Crisis?
Can the EU survive the Eurozone Crisis?Massimiliano Hasan
 
Monetary Policy in Bangladesh
Monetary Policy in BangladeshMonetary Policy in Bangladesh
Monetary Policy in BangladeshPantho Sarker
 
F Inancial Crises And Its Impact On Indian Economy
F Inancial Crises And Its Impact On Indian EconomyF Inancial Crises And Its Impact On Indian Economy
F Inancial Crises And Its Impact On Indian EconomyArif Anis Malik FRSA
 
To focus on the study of examine “U.S. financial crisis and its impact on Ind...
To focus on the study of examine “U.S. financial crisis and its impact on Ind...To focus on the study of examine “U.S. financial crisis and its impact on Ind...
To focus on the study of examine “U.S. financial crisis and its impact on Ind...Rahul Dabhi
 
How to Apply VECM to Detect the J-Curve in the Case of Japan
How to Apply VECM to Detect the J-Curve in the Case of JapanHow to Apply VECM to Detect the J-Curve in the Case of Japan
How to Apply VECM to Detect the J-Curve in the Case of JapanDr. Kelly YiYu Lin
 
Daily i-forex-report by epic reseach 11 july 2013
Daily i-forex-report by epic reseach 11 july 2013Daily i-forex-report by epic reseach 11 july 2013
Daily i-forex-report by epic reseach 11 july 2013Epic Daily Report
 
A study on the impact of global currency fluctuations with a special focus to...
A study on the impact of global currency fluctuations with a special focus to...A study on the impact of global currency fluctuations with a special focus to...
A study on the impact of global currency fluctuations with a special focus to...Aman Vij
 
The Impact of Monetary Policy on Economic Growth and Price Stability in Kenya...
The Impact of Monetary Policy on Economic Growth and Price Stability in Kenya...The Impact of Monetary Policy on Economic Growth and Price Stability in Kenya...
The Impact of Monetary Policy on Economic Growth and Price Stability in Kenya...iosrjce
 
The IMF’s latest forecasts for global growth in 2013
The IMF’s latest forecasts for global growth in 2013 The IMF’s latest forecasts for global growth in 2013
The IMF’s latest forecasts for global growth in 2013 QNB Group
 

Tendances (20)

An Overview Of US Monetary Policy: The Implications of Quantatitive Easing (N...
An Overview Of US Monetary Policy: The Implications of Quantatitive Easing (N...An Overview Of US Monetary Policy: The Implications of Quantatitive Easing (N...
An Overview Of US Monetary Policy: The Implications of Quantatitive Easing (N...
 
Central Bank Mania Continues
Central Bank Mania ContinuesCentral Bank Mania Continues
Central Bank Mania Continues
 
julius bär investment opportunities outlook 2014
julius bär investment opportunities outlook 2014julius bär investment opportunities outlook 2014
julius bär investment opportunities outlook 2014
 
Exchange Rates and External Adjustment
Exchange Rates and External AdjustmentExchange Rates and External Adjustment
Exchange Rates and External Adjustment
 
12013 forecast topic 5 slides
12013 forecast topic 5 slides12013 forecast topic 5 slides
12013 forecast topic 5 slides
 
Daily i-forex-report-1 by epic research 27 may 2013
Daily i-forex-report-1 by epic research 27 may 2013Daily i-forex-report-1 by epic research 27 may 2013
Daily i-forex-report-1 by epic research 27 may 2013
 
Weekly Forex News February 10th 2013
Weekly Forex News February 10th 2013Weekly Forex News February 10th 2013
Weekly Forex News February 10th 2013
 
monetory policy
monetory policymonetory policy
monetory policy
 
Japan Lost Decade vs US, EZ
Japan Lost Decade vs US, EZJapan Lost Decade vs US, EZ
Japan Lost Decade vs US, EZ
 
TJEF January Issue
TJEF January IssueTJEF January Issue
TJEF January Issue
 
Watching for FOMC minutes and yield curves this week
Watching for FOMC minutes and yield curves this week Watching for FOMC minutes and yield curves this week
Watching for FOMC minutes and yield curves this week
 
Can the EU survive the Eurozone Crisis?
Can the EU survive the Eurozone Crisis?Can the EU survive the Eurozone Crisis?
Can the EU survive the Eurozone Crisis?
 
Monetary Policy in Bangladesh
Monetary Policy in BangladeshMonetary Policy in Bangladesh
Monetary Policy in Bangladesh
 
F Inancial Crises And Its Impact On Indian Economy
F Inancial Crises And Its Impact On Indian EconomyF Inancial Crises And Its Impact On Indian Economy
F Inancial Crises And Its Impact On Indian Economy
 
To focus on the study of examine “U.S. financial crisis and its impact on Ind...
To focus on the study of examine “U.S. financial crisis and its impact on Ind...To focus on the study of examine “U.S. financial crisis and its impact on Ind...
To focus on the study of examine “U.S. financial crisis and its impact on Ind...
 
How to Apply VECM to Detect the J-Curve in the Case of Japan
How to Apply VECM to Detect the J-Curve in the Case of JapanHow to Apply VECM to Detect the J-Curve in the Case of Japan
How to Apply VECM to Detect the J-Curve in the Case of Japan
 
Daily i-forex-report by epic reseach 11 july 2013
Daily i-forex-report by epic reseach 11 july 2013Daily i-forex-report by epic reseach 11 july 2013
Daily i-forex-report by epic reseach 11 july 2013
 
A study on the impact of global currency fluctuations with a special focus to...
A study on the impact of global currency fluctuations with a special focus to...A study on the impact of global currency fluctuations with a special focus to...
A study on the impact of global currency fluctuations with a special focus to...
 
The Impact of Monetary Policy on Economic Growth and Price Stability in Kenya...
The Impact of Monetary Policy on Economic Growth and Price Stability in Kenya...The Impact of Monetary Policy on Economic Growth and Price Stability in Kenya...
The Impact of Monetary Policy on Economic Growth and Price Stability in Kenya...
 
The IMF’s latest forecasts for global growth in 2013
The IMF’s latest forecasts for global growth in 2013 The IMF’s latest forecasts for global growth in 2013
The IMF’s latest forecasts for global growth in 2013
 

En vedette

Economic Forecasts - Dec. 2015-Jan. 2016
Economic Forecasts - Dec. 2015-Jan. 2016Economic Forecasts - Dec. 2015-Jan. 2016
Economic Forecasts - Dec. 2015-Jan. 2016Mark Kooymans (M.Econ)
 
Monetary policy and_gdp
Monetary policy and_gdpMonetary policy and_gdp
Monetary policy and_gdpSyed Ali
 
Australian Money
Australian MoneyAustralian Money
Australian Moneykath81
 
Monetary policy
Monetary policyMonetary policy
Monetary policynight seem
 
15 interest rates and monetary policy new
15 interest rates and monetary policy new15 interest rates and monetary policy new
15 interest rates and monetary policy newagjohnson
 
Regional Trade Agreement
Regional Trade AgreementRegional Trade Agreement
Regional Trade AgreementNikhil Soares
 
Monetary Policy Of Pakistan 2013-14
Monetary Policy Of Pakistan 2013-14Monetary Policy Of Pakistan 2013-14
Monetary Policy Of Pakistan 2013-14Jawad Ahmed
 
ROLE OF MONETARY POLICY IN INDIA
ROLE OF MONETARY POLICY IN INDIAROLE OF MONETARY POLICY IN INDIA
ROLE OF MONETARY POLICY IN INDIABooma Thayumanavar
 
State Bank of Pakidtan-Monetary Policy
State Bank of Pakidtan-Monetary PolicyState Bank of Pakidtan-Monetary Policy
State Bank of Pakidtan-Monetary PolicySalma Bashir
 
Monetary policy tools
Monetary policy toolsMonetary policy tools
Monetary policy toolsskazka
 
State Bank Of Pakistan (SBP)- Monetary Policy
State Bank Of Pakistan (SBP)- Monetary PolicyState Bank Of Pakistan (SBP)- Monetary Policy
State Bank Of Pakistan (SBP)- Monetary PolicySalma Bashir
 
Monetary policy & inflation@ ppt
Monetary policy & inflation@ pptMonetary policy & inflation@ ppt
Monetary policy & inflation@ pptBabasab Patil
 

En vedette (20)

Reserve Bank of Australia
Reserve Bank of AustraliaReserve Bank of Australia
Reserve Bank of Australia
 
Economic Forecasts - Dec. 2015-Jan. 2016
Economic Forecasts - Dec. 2015-Jan. 2016Economic Forecasts - Dec. 2015-Jan. 2016
Economic Forecasts - Dec. 2015-Jan. 2016
 
Monetary policy and_gdp
Monetary policy and_gdpMonetary policy and_gdp
Monetary policy and_gdp
 
Australian Money
Australian MoneyAustralian Money
Australian Money
 
Monetary policy
Monetary policyMonetary policy
Monetary policy
 
15 interest rates and monetary policy new
15 interest rates and monetary policy new15 interest rates and monetary policy new
15 interest rates and monetary policy new
 
Monetary System Of Pakistan
Monetary System Of PakistanMonetary System Of Pakistan
Monetary System Of Pakistan
 
Lecture # 3 (30.01.2017) @ ibt monetary policy
Lecture # 3 (30.01.2017) @ ibt monetary policyLecture # 3 (30.01.2017) @ ibt monetary policy
Lecture # 3 (30.01.2017) @ ibt monetary policy
 
Regional Trade Agreement
Regional Trade AgreementRegional Trade Agreement
Regional Trade Agreement
 
Monetary Policy Of Pakistan 2013-14
Monetary Policy Of Pakistan 2013-14Monetary Policy Of Pakistan 2013-14
Monetary Policy Of Pakistan 2013-14
 
Currency
CurrencyCurrency
Currency
 
ROLE OF MONETARY POLICY IN INDIA
ROLE OF MONETARY POLICY IN INDIAROLE OF MONETARY POLICY IN INDIA
ROLE OF MONETARY POLICY IN INDIA
 
State Bank of Pakidtan-Monetary Policy
State Bank of Pakidtan-Monetary PolicyState Bank of Pakidtan-Monetary Policy
State Bank of Pakidtan-Monetary Policy
 
Monetary policy tools
Monetary policy toolsMonetary policy tools
Monetary policy tools
 
State Bank Of Pakistan (SBP)- Monetary Policy
State Bank Of Pakistan (SBP)- Monetary PolicyState Bank Of Pakistan (SBP)- Monetary Policy
State Bank Of Pakistan (SBP)- Monetary Policy
 
Monetary policy & inflation@ ppt
Monetary policy & inflation@ pptMonetary policy & inflation@ ppt
Monetary policy & inflation@ ppt
 
Brexit
BrexitBrexit
Brexit
 
Money markets in australia
Money markets in australiaMoney markets in australia
Money markets in australia
 
Trabajo de diego
Trabajo de diegoTrabajo de diego
Trabajo de diego
 
Christmas
ChristmasChristmas
Christmas
 

Similaire à Monetary Policy According to the Reserve Bank of Australia

Australian Economy.docx
Australian Economy.docxAustralian Economy.docx
Australian Economy.docxwrite12
 
Seigniorage
SeigniorageSeigniorage
Seignioragereaudace
 
Presentation1.pptx
Presentation1.pptxPresentation1.pptx
Presentation1.pptxmaaz46
 
The Impact of RBA Monetary Surprises -Chapman (2014)
The Impact of RBA Monetary Surprises -Chapman (2014)The Impact of RBA Monetary Surprises -Chapman (2014)
The Impact of RBA Monetary Surprises -Chapman (2014)Blair Chapman
 
EconThesisSecondDraft
EconThesisSecondDraftEconThesisSecondDraft
EconThesisSecondDraftJames Supeene
 
Development of Islamic Banks in Australia
Development of Islamic Banks in AustraliaDevelopment of Islamic Banks in Australia
Development of Islamic Banks in AustraliaAin Atiya Azmi
 
Global Macro-economics, Trends, Portfolio Implications
Global Macro-economics, Trends, Portfolio ImplicationsGlobal Macro-economics, Trends, Portfolio Implications
Global Macro-economics, Trends, Portfolio ImplicationsNikunj Sanghvi
 
The Henley Market Outlook July 2013
The Henley Market Outlook July 2013The Henley Market Outlook July 2013
The Henley Market Outlook July 2013Tania Scott
 
Bordo and haubrich Predictive power of term structure of interest rates
Bordo and haubrich Predictive power of term structure of interest ratesBordo and haubrich Predictive power of term structure of interest rates
Bordo and haubrich Predictive power of term structure of interest ratesAliya Urazaliyeva
 
Who Profits from Peace? Belfast Trades Council Mayday Lecture 2013
Who Profits from Peace? Belfast Trades Council Mayday Lecture 2013Who Profits from Peace? Belfast Trades Council Mayday Lecture 2013
Who Profits from Peace? Belfast Trades Council Mayday Lecture 2013Conor McCabe
 
CHAPTER I HISTORY OF CENTRAL BANK.pdf
CHAPTER I HISTORY OF CENTRAL BANK.pdfCHAPTER I HISTORY OF CENTRAL BANK.pdf
CHAPTER I HISTORY OF CENTRAL BANK.pdfMengsongNguon
 
Occam\'s Razor - Inflation (Sept. 2009)
Occam\'s Razor - Inflation (Sept. 2009)Occam\'s Razor - Inflation (Sept. 2009)
Occam\'s Razor - Inflation (Sept. 2009)MAMC84
 
Occam\'s Razor on Inflation
Occam\'s Razor on InflationOccam\'s Razor on Inflation
Occam\'s Razor on InflationMAMC84
 
The Case for Sterling - September 2013
The Case for Sterling - September 2013The Case for Sterling - September 2013
The Case for Sterling - September 2013Mickey Petley
 

Similaire à Monetary Policy According to the Reserve Bank of Australia (19)

Australian Economy.docx
Australian Economy.docxAustralian Economy.docx
Australian Economy.docx
 
Seigniorage
SeigniorageSeigniorage
Seigniorage
 
Presentation1.pptx
Presentation1.pptxPresentation1.pptx
Presentation1.pptx
 
The Impact of RBA Monetary Surprises -Chapman (2014)
The Impact of RBA Monetary Surprises -Chapman (2014)The Impact of RBA Monetary Surprises -Chapman (2014)
The Impact of RBA Monetary Surprises -Chapman (2014)
 
EconThesisSecondDraft
EconThesisSecondDraftEconThesisSecondDraft
EconThesisSecondDraft
 
Development of Islamic Banks in Australia
Development of Islamic Banks in AustraliaDevelopment of Islamic Banks in Australia
Development of Islamic Banks in Australia
 
Global Macro-economics, Trends, Portfolio Implications
Global Macro-economics, Trends, Portfolio ImplicationsGlobal Macro-economics, Trends, Portfolio Implications
Global Macro-economics, Trends, Portfolio Implications
 
The Henley Market Outlook July 2013
The Henley Market Outlook July 2013The Henley Market Outlook July 2013
The Henley Market Outlook July 2013
 
Bordo and haubrich Predictive power of term structure of interest rates
Bordo and haubrich Predictive power of term structure of interest ratesBordo and haubrich Predictive power of term structure of interest rates
Bordo and haubrich Predictive power of term structure of interest rates
 
Global Economy - Currency Wars
Global Economy - Currency WarsGlobal Economy - Currency Wars
Global Economy - Currency Wars
 
Who Profits from Peace? Belfast Trades Council Mayday Lecture 2013
Who Profits from Peace? Belfast Trades Council Mayday Lecture 2013Who Profits from Peace? Belfast Trades Council Mayday Lecture 2013
Who Profits from Peace? Belfast Trades Council Mayday Lecture 2013
 
CHAPTER I HISTORY OF CENTRAL BANK.pdf
CHAPTER I HISTORY OF CENTRAL BANK.pdfCHAPTER I HISTORY OF CENTRAL BANK.pdf
CHAPTER I HISTORY OF CENTRAL BANK.pdf
 
mayu llc business analysis
mayu llc business analysismayu llc business analysis
mayu llc business analysis
 
Occam\'s Razor - Inflation (Sept. 2009)
Occam\'s Razor - Inflation (Sept. 2009)Occam\'s Razor - Inflation (Sept. 2009)
Occam\'s Razor - Inflation (Sept. 2009)
 
Occam\'s Razor on Inflation
Occam\'s Razor on InflationOccam\'s Razor on Inflation
Occam\'s Razor on Inflation
 
Federal Reserve Essay
Federal Reserve EssayFederal Reserve Essay
Federal Reserve Essay
 
The Case for Sterling - September 2013
The Case for Sterling - September 2013The Case for Sterling - September 2013
The Case for Sterling - September 2013
 
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 402 - Does the Crisis Experience Call for a...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 402 - Does the Crisis Experience Call for a...CASE Network Studies and Analyses 402 - Does the Crisis Experience Call for a...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 402 - Does the Crisis Experience Call for a...
 
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 301 -
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 301 - CASE Network Studies and Analyses 301 -
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 301 -
 

Plus de Jonathon Flegg

Introduction to the Strategy of Game Theory
Introduction to the Strategy of Game TheoryIntroduction to the Strategy of Game Theory
Introduction to the Strategy of Game TheoryJonathon Flegg
 
Evaluating Thailand's Alcohol Excise Tax System
Evaluating Thailand's Alcohol Excise Tax SystemEvaluating Thailand's Alcohol Excise Tax System
Evaluating Thailand's Alcohol Excise Tax SystemJonathon Flegg
 
Cost-Benefit Analysis of Sydney's Second Airport
Cost-Benefit Analysis of Sydney's Second AirportCost-Benefit Analysis of Sydney's Second Airport
Cost-Benefit Analysis of Sydney's Second AirportJonathon Flegg
 
Choosing Between an MPA or MPP Degree
Choosing Between an MPA or MPP DegreeChoosing Between an MPA or MPP Degree
Choosing Between an MPA or MPP DegreeJonathon Flegg
 
Swimming in a Sea of Finance: the Occasional Logic of Capital Controls
Swimming in a Sea of Finance: the Occasional Logic of Capital ControlsSwimming in a Sea of Finance: the Occasional Logic of Capital Controls
Swimming in a Sea of Finance: the Occasional Logic of Capital ControlsJonathon Flegg
 
Reforming Pakistan’s National Accounts: A Proposed 2002 Program
Reforming Pakistan’s National Accounts: A Proposed 2002 Program Reforming Pakistan’s National Accounts: A Proposed 2002 Program
Reforming Pakistan’s National Accounts: A Proposed 2002 Program Jonathon Flegg
 
Measuring the effects of alcohol-supply restrictions in indigenous communitie...
Measuring the effects of alcohol-supply restrictions in indigenous communitie...Measuring the effects of alcohol-supply restrictions in indigenous communitie...
Measuring the effects of alcohol-supply restrictions in indigenous communitie...Jonathon Flegg
 
Education for All in India: Financing India's Elementary Education
Education for All in India: Financing India's Elementary EducationEducation for All in India: Financing India's Elementary Education
Education for All in India: Financing India's Elementary EducationJonathon Flegg
 
A Rational Choice Model of Compulsory Voting
A Rational Choice Model of Compulsory VotingA Rational Choice Model of Compulsory Voting
A Rational Choice Model of Compulsory VotingJonathon Flegg
 
Term Limits: Why or Why Not?
Term Limits: Why or Why Not?Term Limits: Why or Why Not?
Term Limits: Why or Why Not?Jonathon Flegg
 
How to Rig an Election: A Study of Electoral Manipulation in Afghanistan
How to Rig an Election: A Study of Electoral Manipulation in AfghanistanHow to Rig an Election: A Study of Electoral Manipulation in Afghanistan
How to Rig an Election: A Study of Electoral Manipulation in AfghanistanJonathon Flegg
 
Deng Xiaoping Reforms: Changes and Challenges
Deng Xiaoping Reforms: Changes and ChallengesDeng Xiaoping Reforms: Changes and Challenges
Deng Xiaoping Reforms: Changes and ChallengesJonathon Flegg
 
Outcomes of Globalisation: Trade for All
Outcomes of Globalisation: Trade for AllOutcomes of Globalisation: Trade for All
Outcomes of Globalisation: Trade for AllJonathon Flegg
 

Plus de Jonathon Flegg (13)

Introduction to the Strategy of Game Theory
Introduction to the Strategy of Game TheoryIntroduction to the Strategy of Game Theory
Introduction to the Strategy of Game Theory
 
Evaluating Thailand's Alcohol Excise Tax System
Evaluating Thailand's Alcohol Excise Tax SystemEvaluating Thailand's Alcohol Excise Tax System
Evaluating Thailand's Alcohol Excise Tax System
 
Cost-Benefit Analysis of Sydney's Second Airport
Cost-Benefit Analysis of Sydney's Second AirportCost-Benefit Analysis of Sydney's Second Airport
Cost-Benefit Analysis of Sydney's Second Airport
 
Choosing Between an MPA or MPP Degree
Choosing Between an MPA or MPP DegreeChoosing Between an MPA or MPP Degree
Choosing Between an MPA or MPP Degree
 
Swimming in a Sea of Finance: the Occasional Logic of Capital Controls
Swimming in a Sea of Finance: the Occasional Logic of Capital ControlsSwimming in a Sea of Finance: the Occasional Logic of Capital Controls
Swimming in a Sea of Finance: the Occasional Logic of Capital Controls
 
Reforming Pakistan’s National Accounts: A Proposed 2002 Program
Reforming Pakistan’s National Accounts: A Proposed 2002 Program Reforming Pakistan’s National Accounts: A Proposed 2002 Program
Reforming Pakistan’s National Accounts: A Proposed 2002 Program
 
Measuring the effects of alcohol-supply restrictions in indigenous communitie...
Measuring the effects of alcohol-supply restrictions in indigenous communitie...Measuring the effects of alcohol-supply restrictions in indigenous communitie...
Measuring the effects of alcohol-supply restrictions in indigenous communitie...
 
Education for All in India: Financing India's Elementary Education
Education for All in India: Financing India's Elementary EducationEducation for All in India: Financing India's Elementary Education
Education for All in India: Financing India's Elementary Education
 
A Rational Choice Model of Compulsory Voting
A Rational Choice Model of Compulsory VotingA Rational Choice Model of Compulsory Voting
A Rational Choice Model of Compulsory Voting
 
Term Limits: Why or Why Not?
Term Limits: Why or Why Not?Term Limits: Why or Why Not?
Term Limits: Why or Why Not?
 
How to Rig an Election: A Study of Electoral Manipulation in Afghanistan
How to Rig an Election: A Study of Electoral Manipulation in AfghanistanHow to Rig an Election: A Study of Electoral Manipulation in Afghanistan
How to Rig an Election: A Study of Electoral Manipulation in Afghanistan
 
Deng Xiaoping Reforms: Changes and Challenges
Deng Xiaoping Reforms: Changes and ChallengesDeng Xiaoping Reforms: Changes and Challenges
Deng Xiaoping Reforms: Changes and Challenges
 
Outcomes of Globalisation: Trade for All
Outcomes of Globalisation: Trade for AllOutcomes of Globalisation: Trade for All
Outcomes of Globalisation: Trade for All
 

Dernier

The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 30.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 30.pdfThe Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 30.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 30.pdfGale Pooley
 
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 18.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 18.pdfThe Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 18.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 18.pdfGale Pooley
 
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Wadgaon Sheri 6297143586 Call Hot Ind...
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Wadgaon Sheri  6297143586 Call Hot Ind...Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Wadgaon Sheri  6297143586 Call Hot Ind...
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Wadgaon Sheri 6297143586 Call Hot Ind...Call Girls in Nagpur High Profile
 
Instant Issue Debit Cards - School Designs
Instant Issue Debit Cards - School DesignsInstant Issue Debit Cards - School Designs
Instant Issue Debit Cards - School Designsegoetzinger
 
06_Joeri Van Speybroek_Dell_MeetupDora&Cybersecurity.pdf
06_Joeri Van Speybroek_Dell_MeetupDora&Cybersecurity.pdf06_Joeri Van Speybroek_Dell_MeetupDora&Cybersecurity.pdf
06_Joeri Van Speybroek_Dell_MeetupDora&Cybersecurity.pdfFinTech Belgium
 
03_Emmanuel Ndiaye_Degroof Petercam.pptx
03_Emmanuel Ndiaye_Degroof Petercam.pptx03_Emmanuel Ndiaye_Degroof Petercam.pptx
03_Emmanuel Ndiaye_Degroof Petercam.pptxFinTech Belgium
 
(DIYA) Bhumkar Chowk Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...
(DIYA) Bhumkar Chowk Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...(DIYA) Bhumkar Chowk Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...
(DIYA) Bhumkar Chowk Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...ranjana rawat
 
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Shivane 6297143586 Call Hot Indian Gi...
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Shivane  6297143586 Call Hot Indian Gi...Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Shivane  6297143586 Call Hot Indian Gi...
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Shivane 6297143586 Call Hot Indian Gi...Call Girls in Nagpur High Profile
 
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 25.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 25.pdfThe Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 25.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 25.pdfGale Pooley
 
High Class Call Girls Nagpur Grishma Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escorts
High Class Call Girls Nagpur Grishma Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur EscortsHigh Class Call Girls Nagpur Grishma Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escorts
High Class Call Girls Nagpur Grishma Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escortsranjana rawat
 
00_Main ppt_MeetupDORA&CyberSecurity.pptx
00_Main ppt_MeetupDORA&CyberSecurity.pptx00_Main ppt_MeetupDORA&CyberSecurity.pptx
00_Main ppt_MeetupDORA&CyberSecurity.pptxFinTech Belgium
 
Malad Call Girl in Services 9892124323 | ₹,4500 With Room Free Delivery
Malad Call Girl in Services  9892124323 | ₹,4500 With Room Free DeliveryMalad Call Girl in Services  9892124323 | ₹,4500 With Room Free Delivery
Malad Call Girl in Services 9892124323 | ₹,4500 With Room Free DeliveryPooja Nehwal
 
Top Rated Pune Call Girls Viman Nagar ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex...
Top Rated  Pune Call Girls Viman Nagar ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex...Top Rated  Pune Call Girls Viman Nagar ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex...
Top Rated Pune Call Girls Viman Nagar ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex...Call Girls in Nagpur High Profile
 
Stock Market Brief Deck (Under Pressure).pdf
Stock Market Brief Deck (Under Pressure).pdfStock Market Brief Deck (Under Pressure).pdf
Stock Market Brief Deck (Under Pressure).pdfMichael Silva
 
Instant Issue Debit Cards - High School Spirit
Instant Issue Debit Cards - High School SpiritInstant Issue Debit Cards - High School Spirit
Instant Issue Debit Cards - High School Spiritegoetzinger
 
WhatsApp 📞 Call : 9892124323 ✅Call Girls In Chembur ( Mumbai ) secure service
WhatsApp 📞 Call : 9892124323  ✅Call Girls In Chembur ( Mumbai ) secure serviceWhatsApp 📞 Call : 9892124323  ✅Call Girls In Chembur ( Mumbai ) secure service
WhatsApp 📞 Call : 9892124323 ✅Call Girls In Chembur ( Mumbai ) secure servicePooja Nehwal
 
Dividend Policy and Dividend Decision Theories.pptx
Dividend Policy and Dividend Decision Theories.pptxDividend Policy and Dividend Decision Theories.pptx
Dividend Policy and Dividend Decision Theories.pptxanshikagoel52
 
Call Girls Service Nagpur Maya Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escorts
Call Girls Service Nagpur Maya Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur EscortsCall Girls Service Nagpur Maya Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escorts
Call Girls Service Nagpur Maya Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escortsranjana rawat
 
Pooja 9892124323 : Call Girl in Juhu Escorts Service Free Home Delivery
Pooja 9892124323 : Call Girl in Juhu Escorts Service Free Home DeliveryPooja 9892124323 : Call Girl in Juhu Escorts Service Free Home Delivery
Pooja 9892124323 : Call Girl in Juhu Escorts Service Free Home DeliveryPooja Nehwal
 

Dernier (20)

The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 30.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 30.pdfThe Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 30.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 30.pdf
 
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 18.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 18.pdfThe Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 18.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 18.pdf
 
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Wadgaon Sheri 6297143586 Call Hot Ind...
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Wadgaon Sheri  6297143586 Call Hot Ind...Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Wadgaon Sheri  6297143586 Call Hot Ind...
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Wadgaon Sheri 6297143586 Call Hot Ind...
 
Instant Issue Debit Cards - School Designs
Instant Issue Debit Cards - School DesignsInstant Issue Debit Cards - School Designs
Instant Issue Debit Cards - School Designs
 
Veritas Interim Report 1 January–31 March 2024
Veritas Interim Report 1 January–31 March 2024Veritas Interim Report 1 January–31 March 2024
Veritas Interim Report 1 January–31 March 2024
 
06_Joeri Van Speybroek_Dell_MeetupDora&Cybersecurity.pdf
06_Joeri Van Speybroek_Dell_MeetupDora&Cybersecurity.pdf06_Joeri Van Speybroek_Dell_MeetupDora&Cybersecurity.pdf
06_Joeri Van Speybroek_Dell_MeetupDora&Cybersecurity.pdf
 
03_Emmanuel Ndiaye_Degroof Petercam.pptx
03_Emmanuel Ndiaye_Degroof Petercam.pptx03_Emmanuel Ndiaye_Degroof Petercam.pptx
03_Emmanuel Ndiaye_Degroof Petercam.pptx
 
(DIYA) Bhumkar Chowk Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...
(DIYA) Bhumkar Chowk Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...(DIYA) Bhumkar Chowk Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...
(DIYA) Bhumkar Chowk Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...
 
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Shivane 6297143586 Call Hot Indian Gi...
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Shivane  6297143586 Call Hot Indian Gi...Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Shivane  6297143586 Call Hot Indian Gi...
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Shivane 6297143586 Call Hot Indian Gi...
 
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 25.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 25.pdfThe Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 25.pdf
The Economic History of the U.S. Lecture 25.pdf
 
High Class Call Girls Nagpur Grishma Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escorts
High Class Call Girls Nagpur Grishma Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur EscortsHigh Class Call Girls Nagpur Grishma Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escorts
High Class Call Girls Nagpur Grishma Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escorts
 
00_Main ppt_MeetupDORA&CyberSecurity.pptx
00_Main ppt_MeetupDORA&CyberSecurity.pptx00_Main ppt_MeetupDORA&CyberSecurity.pptx
00_Main ppt_MeetupDORA&CyberSecurity.pptx
 
Malad Call Girl in Services 9892124323 | ₹,4500 With Room Free Delivery
Malad Call Girl in Services  9892124323 | ₹,4500 With Room Free DeliveryMalad Call Girl in Services  9892124323 | ₹,4500 With Room Free Delivery
Malad Call Girl in Services 9892124323 | ₹,4500 With Room Free Delivery
 
Top Rated Pune Call Girls Viman Nagar ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex...
Top Rated  Pune Call Girls Viman Nagar ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex...Top Rated  Pune Call Girls Viman Nagar ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex...
Top Rated Pune Call Girls Viman Nagar ⟟ 6297143586 ⟟ Call Me For Genuine Sex...
 
Stock Market Brief Deck (Under Pressure).pdf
Stock Market Brief Deck (Under Pressure).pdfStock Market Brief Deck (Under Pressure).pdf
Stock Market Brief Deck (Under Pressure).pdf
 
Instant Issue Debit Cards - High School Spirit
Instant Issue Debit Cards - High School SpiritInstant Issue Debit Cards - High School Spirit
Instant Issue Debit Cards - High School Spirit
 
WhatsApp 📞 Call : 9892124323 ✅Call Girls In Chembur ( Mumbai ) secure service
WhatsApp 📞 Call : 9892124323  ✅Call Girls In Chembur ( Mumbai ) secure serviceWhatsApp 📞 Call : 9892124323  ✅Call Girls In Chembur ( Mumbai ) secure service
WhatsApp 📞 Call : 9892124323 ✅Call Girls In Chembur ( Mumbai ) secure service
 
Dividend Policy and Dividend Decision Theories.pptx
Dividend Policy and Dividend Decision Theories.pptxDividend Policy and Dividend Decision Theories.pptx
Dividend Policy and Dividend Decision Theories.pptx
 
Call Girls Service Nagpur Maya Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escorts
Call Girls Service Nagpur Maya Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur EscortsCall Girls Service Nagpur Maya Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escorts
Call Girls Service Nagpur Maya Call 7001035870 Meet With Nagpur Escorts
 
Pooja 9892124323 : Call Girl in Juhu Escorts Service Free Home Delivery
Pooja 9892124323 : Call Girl in Juhu Escorts Service Free Home DeliveryPooja 9892124323 : Call Girl in Juhu Escorts Service Free Home Delivery
Pooja 9892124323 : Call Girl in Juhu Escorts Service Free Home Delivery
 

Monetary Policy According to the Reserve Bank of Australia

  • 1. ECE Department Monetary Policy According to the Reserve Bank of Australia Jonathon Flegg and Mieke Klanker 0 j.c.flegg@nus.edu.sg | mieke.klanker@sciences-po.org
  • 2. Contents 1. Introduction .......................................................................................................................................................2 2. Inflation-Targeting Pioneer .................................................................................................................................2 Institutional Development and the Australian Economy ....................................................................................................... 2 Reserve Bank Finds its Independence .................................................................................................................................... 4 Board Structure and Current Independence .......................................................................................................................... 6 3. Inflation-Targeting Framework ...........................................................................................................................8 A Flexible Target ..................................................................................................................................................................... 9 The Operational Target ........................................................................................................................................................... 9 Credibility and Transparency ................................................................................................................................................ 10 4. Inflation-Targeting Success ............................................................................................................................... 11 Hitting the Target.................................................................................................................................................................. 11 Reducing Inflation Volatility.................................................................................................................................................. 13 Anchoring Inflation Expectations.......................................................................................................................................... 13 A Macroeconomic ‘Free Lunch’ ............................................................................................................................................ 15 5. Not an Inflation-Targeting ‘Nutter’ ................................................................................................................... 15 Output and Employment Gaps ............................................................................................................................................. 16 Asset Price Bubbles ............................................................................................................................................................... 17 6. Concluding Remarks ..................................................................................................................................................... 18 7. Bibliography ................................................................................................................................................................. 20 1
  • 3. 1. Introduction Since 1993 there has been a silent revolution in way the Reserve Bank of Australia (RBA) conducts monetary policy. In that year without any fanfare or public pronouncements the RBA quietly moved to developing a new framework of inflation-targeting. New Zealand was the first country to initiate a similar regime but that had only been initiated a short three years earlier and operationally was very different to anything being discussed across in Australia. Certainly in advanced economies just coming out of stagflation the verdict on central banks targeting inflation was still open. Now in 2011 the RBA and its framework for targeting inflation are still going strong. The unique framework that the RBA has developed over time can most aptly be described by three core characteristics: credibility, transparency and flexibility. The target is distinctive internationally for its flexibility: 2 to 3 per cent inflation, on average, over the business cycle. What is surprising however is that this amount of flexibility afforded to the RBA in meeting this medium-term target coexists with a comparatively low-level of political independence. If the RBA has an Achilles’ heel it is certainly the lack of institutionalised independence from the Government it currently operates with. Ultimately though it is likely that the three characteristics described above are its great strength, and maintaining them has afforded the RBA the capacity to steer the real economy through some difficult times. In this assessment of the RBA’s practice of monetary policy we will first discuss the pioneering days when the RBA was feeling its way into inflation-targeting, and how and why the framework developed, politically and experientially, into the distinctive form we observe today. In the next section we will explain the mechanics of the how the RBA operationalises inflation-targeting, and if given its short history we can regard it as a success. And to finish we will demonstrate how the unique characteristics of the framework, its focus on credibility, transparency and flexibility, allow the RBA to also focus on achieving a number of secondary policy objectives. 2. Inflation-Targeting Pioneer Institutional Development and the Australian Economy Prior to the Reserve Bank Act of 1959, the government-owned Commonwealth Bank of Australia possessed the functions of both a central and commercial bank. The Australia Government, judging that these dual roles were inconsistent, created a new statutory body called the Reserve Bank of Australia, which relieved the Commonwealth Bank of its duties as a nation’s central bank. Section 10(2) of the Act specifies the ‘Charter’ of the RBA as: It is the duty of the Reserve Bank Board, within the limits of its powers, to ensure that the monetary and banking policy of the Bank is directed to the greatest advantage of the people of Australia and 2
  • 4. that the powers of the Bank ... are exercised in such a manner as, in the opinion of the Reserve Bank Board, will best contribute to: a. the stability of the currency of Australia; b. the maintenance of full employment in Australia; and c. the economic prosperity and welfare of the people of Australia. While the ‘Charter’ is clearly loaded with the economics of Keynesian times, actual policy is for the most part free to be operationalised by the Government of the day, and in more recent times, the RBA itself. Open to interpretation is the meaning of “stability of the currency”. While it could be understood as exchange rate or price stability, the RBA now chooses to have the Charter find “practical expression” in the current inflation-targeting regime (RBA, 2011). Figure 1: Real Exchange Rate and Terms of Trade (Battellino and Plumb, 2009: 11) The Australian economy is as a small and open economy with a high-level of income per capita. However its strong dependence on export commodities has led it be susceptible to extreme fluctuations in its terms of trade. The Bretton Woods system of pegged exchange rates left the Australian economy vulnerable to debilitating booms and busts. In fact the inflexibility of exchange rates was one of the major reasons why Australia was one of the only major international economies not to join the IMF when it was established in 1944 (Henry, 2003)1. It was little surprise then that Australia was not far behind the United States in moving to a floating currency in 1983. The event was a culmination of first switching the peg from the British Pound to the US Dollar in 1971, then to a trade-weighted exchange rate index in 1974, followed by periodic valuation in 1976. The current floating exchange rate dampens the impact of commodity booms and busts on the economy. When exports in Australian 1 The other major economy that refused to join the IMF was Russia. Prime Minister Chifley was successful in reversing Australia’s decision not to join in 1947. 3
  • 5. commodities are booming, the Australian Dollar appreciates to provide some dampening to inflation (note the particularly robust relationship since 1983 in Figure 1)2. The floating of the exchange rate was an important reform that now assists the RBA to dampen inflation. Because of its high volatility the Australian Dollar is now commonly referred to by Australians as the “little Aussie battler”. Floating the currency also allowed for the foreign exchange controls in Australia to be liberalised, leading to the ‘internationalisation’ of the dollar. It now ranks as the sixth most traded currency globally (Battellino and Plumb, 2009: 5). Abandoning the peg produced its own challenges for monetary policy however. Monetary targeting was adopted first and then abandoned by 1985, when it had become clear that resulting from financial liberalisation and innovation the monetary aggregates no longer bore a stable relationship to prices or nominal incomes. In the period that followed, the approach to monetary policy was could best be described as an ad hoc “checklist” of indicators (Edey, 2005:3). The Government’s preferred position was to target the Current Account Balance (Bell, 2004), while many at the RBA realised that Australia’s status as a commodity exporter made targeting an external position infeasibility difficult. This gulf in attitudes set the scene for independence. Reserve Bank Finds its Independence Within the Australian media it is an often-repeated maxim that the RBA is independent of the Government. In practice what is meant is the RBA enjoys de facto independence, a kind that should not be confused with the type of institutionalised independence we might ascribe to the European Central Bank. The RBA’s de facto independence was the not a consequence of conscious institutional design, but rather it was the product of a series of political events culminating in the 1996 Statement on the Conduct of Monetary Policy (RBA, 1996). Prior to that agreement the status quo, according to the former Governor Ian Macfarlane (in Bell, 2004: 110), was that the “Treasurer made monetary policy on the advice of the Reserve Bank and the Treasury” indicating a lack of independence. Prime Minister Keating jealously guarded this arrangement, and once ignited a firestorm in 1990 by boasting to the Federal Press Gallery: I have Treasury in my pocket, the Reserve Bank in my pocket, wages policy in my pocket, the financial community both here and overseas in my pocket (Keating in Bell, 2004). The RBA’s credibility suffered greatly as a result of this comment. To maintain the Government’s control over monetary policy, PM Keating appointed a trusted colleague and former Treasury Secretary, Bernie Fraser, to the position of RBA Governor in 1989. However once appointed Fraser came to the view, along with many others at the RBA, that Australian monetary policy should be primarily focused on targeting inflation rather than the 2 This occurs through greater substitution of imported goods and services for domestically-produced ones and through the departure of liquidity. 4
  • 6. current account deficit, a position upheld by the Government (Bell, 2004: 63). Inflation-targeting had been introduced relatively recently in a number of other small and open economies, such as New Zealand and Canada, and had been shown to be performing well. The decision by Fraser and the RBA to contravene explicit Government policy enraged Keating, at a time when his political fortunes were fading3. The inflation-targeting policy was a bureaucratic declaration of independence at a time in the political cycle most conducive to such a manoeuvre. Keating confessed in his memoires that going into the 1996 election: The option for me, near a difficult election, was to have an open brawl with the Bank and [Governor] Bernie Fraser. Further away from an election, I would have dealt with the Bank’s unreasonable intransigence in much sterner and more decisive terms (Keating in Bell, 2004: 127). The incoming Liberal-National Government led by Prime Minister John Howard recognising the strength of operational independence and inflation-targeting over the preceding three years, and decided to acknowledge the RBA’s independence in the joint Statement on the Conduct of Monetary Policy (RBA, 1996). Like a peace treaty it was signed and issued jointly by two equal representatives of both sides of the conflict, the Federal Treasurer and the Governor of the RBA. The unique evolution of independence for the RBA serves to illustrate a number of characteristics of the Australian system of setting monetary policy. Firstly, the RBA does not neatly follow the intuition that independence and flexibility go hand-in-hand. The RBA developed as one of the less formally independent central banks, yet enjoys a considerable degree of flexibility in achieving its final target. Secondly, this anomaly to some degree can be explained by the fact that the introduction of inflation-targeting was entirely bureaucratic-led rather than government-imposed. The system that the RBA developed without the blessing of the Government is inherently flexible and provides the Board with considerable discretion in how they reach the target. It was always within the interests of the RBA to conduct a system that ‘bound their hands’ as little as possible and even allowed them to decide on what other macroeconomic goals to focus. However, the independence that allowed the RBA to develop inflation-targeting was not bestowed upon them but was because it occurred at a unique point in the political cycle when the Government was weak. 3 By the 1993 Federal Election the Labor Government, credited with the floating of the Australian Dollar in 1983, was struggling to maintain public support. While inflation was lower, so was Prime Minister Keating credentials on the economy, given the size of the Government’s deficit and high interest rates. The Liberal-National Coalition failed to secure an election victory in 1993 mainly because of public concerns about their most well-known policy was to introduce a Goods and Services Tax. However by the 1996 election the Liberal-National Coalition, led by a new leader John Howard, had publicly scrapped the GST policy and went on to win a strong majority in Parliament. 5
  • 7. This is linked to a final point, the RBA’s independence can hardly be considered institutionalised. While the Statement is an agreement between the two parties that has gained acceptance through time, ultimately the RBA enjoys its freedom because of its support by from the Government, not despite it. In a way the Government can be considered to currently benefit from the political cover for never being directly responsible for raising interest rates, but conversely being able to claim responsibility for ‘creating a strong economic environment’ when rates remain low. However the strongest source of support of maintaining RBA independence remains their on-going perceived performance rather than correct institutional procedure. As Coleman (2004) warned that in different economic times and with different political figures the threat of government ‘capture’ still remains at the RBA. Board Structure and Current Independence The Reserve Bank Board consists of nine members all appointed by the Government: Three executive and six non- executive members. The three executive members consist of the Governor, Deputy Governor and the Treasury Secretary. The Governor and Deputy Governor are appointed by the Government Treasurer for an eight year term, and both are eligible for reappointment and termination. The non-executive members are also appointed by the Treasurer. Most non-executive appointments are made from the within the corporate community, and there is a tradition of placing one academic on the Board (Bell, 2004)4. To protect anonymity within the Board’s membership, neither member-votes nor minutes are publicly reproduced. Moderately Low Policy Independence Comparatively High High Financial Low Overall Instrument Independence Independence Independence Low Personnel Independence Figure 2: The RBA according to Cukierman’s (1992) Central Bank Independence Index The current RBA’s separation from Government can be understood along the four dimensions of independence determined by Cukierman (1992): policy, instrument, personnel, and financial independence. The RBA has high instrument independence, but unlike some other inflation-targeting central banks has minimal ability to change 4 To protect the Board from political ‘capture’ Coleman (2004) has suggested reforming appointments along the lines of the Bank of England Board to include more economists and public sector representatives from institutions such as the Productivity Commission or ACCC. 6
  • 8. the policy framework without the agreement of the Government5. However as we have seen the system is quite flexible, and for the most part was a framework designed by the RBA themselves between 1993 and 1996. RBA’s personnel independence is quite low because all members of the Board are government-appointed, but it is responsible for its own budget, giving it substantial financial independence (RBA, 1994: 7; Arnone et al, 2006). Compared with other inflation-targeting regimes, the RBA’s overall independence is usually rated as quite low. In an assessment of the personal, political and financial independence of central banks, Sousa (2002) placing the RBA’s independence second only to the Bank of Canada (see Figure 3). According to a cross-country IMF study by Arnone et al (2006), the RBA was the only central bank where political independence diminished between 1991 and 2003 because of the loss of some “legal protections that strengthen the central bank’s position in the event of a conflict with the government” (2006: 5). Figure 3: Accountability versus Independence within inflation-targeting central banks (Sousa, 2002) The converse of a lack of independence compared with other central banks is that the RBA is quite accountable to Government, and indirectly responsible to the Australian people. This accountability is maintained not only through the Board’s appointment system but also through the executive and senior staff appearing at least twice a year before the House of Representatives Standing Committee on Economics. However accountability must be weighed against the vast literature that has emerged on the positive relationship between central bank independence and economic performance 6. The continued rise in home ownership in Australia has only strengthened the powerful incentives for politicians to prefer downward-biased interest rates in the short-term. This potential political pressure makes the institutionalisation of the RBA’s independence even more vital. 5 Policy independence refers to the capacity of the central bank to determine its own policy goals and processes, while instrument independence is a measure of its control over the use of the policy instrument, the short-term official interest rate. 6 See Bofinger (2001: 216-20) for a summary of the evidence. 7
  • 9. 3. Inflation-Targeting Framework The principal objective of the RBA’s inflation-targeting framework is to achieve price stability through achieving a predetermined inflation target. In the 1996 Statement the Governor and the Treasurer agreed that the appropriate official target for monetary policy was a consumer price inflation rate of “2-3 per cent, on average, over the cycle” (RBA, 1996). The design of the framework allowed “for the natural short run variation in underlying inflation over the cycle while preserving a clearly identifiable benchmark performance over time” (RBA, 1996). This line made clear from the beginning the Australian framework was at the flexible end of the spectrum of inflation-targeting central banks. The distinct characteristics of the Australian inflation-targeting framework are credibility, transparency and flexibility. Figure 4: Key Characteristics of the RBA’s Inflation-targeting Framework The 2-3 per cent target was defined based on the best average performances since WWII which were in the “two point something” region with quite a wide degree of variation around that average (Stevens, 2003:20). According to Governor Stevens (2003:20) the Bundesbank was also a lead example in defining this target. The RBA’s target was quite different to what Greenspan was suggesting at the time as an optimal target for the Federal Reserve: “I would say the number is zero, if inflation is properly measured.”(in FOMC, 1996). Summary of the RBA’s Inflation-targeting Framework Measure of inflation Headline CPI Target band and horizon Average of 2-3% over the medium term Policy timeline No explicit timeline for corrections Policy rate Overnight cash rate Table 1: Summary of the RBA's Inflation-targeting Framework The inflation target is expressed in terms of the average rate of increase in the consumer price index (CPI). Although the ultimate objective for the RBA is specified in terms of headline CPI, an important input into forecasting inflation are measures of underlying inflation which attempt to abstract from the short-term volatility in some prices (Richards and Rosewall 2010:7). The measure of underlying inflation most used by the RBA is the trimmed-mean rate of inflation, the average rate of inflation after ‘trimming’ away a certain percentage of the 8
  • 10. distribution of price changes at both ends of that distribution (Richards and Rosewall, 2010:8). In a recent study Brischetto and Richards (2006) found that trimmed measures tend to out-perform headline and exclusion measures, which are used by other central banks, on a range of different criteria. In practice, the RBA has tended to focus on two particular trims: the 15 per cent trimmed mean and the weighted median, which trims 50 per cent of the distribution from both ends (Richards and Rosewall, 2010:8). A Flexible Target The Australian inflation-targeting regime differs in two ways from conventional regimes which are both related to the definition as “2-3 per cent, on average, over the cycle”. Firstly, unlike other inflating-targeting central banks, is the RBA is not faced with an explicit timeline to correct deviations from the target band. This allows the Reserve Bank the flexibility to pay attention to the state of the economy, as measured by output or unemployment, in its deliberations about the stance of monetary policy. Secondly, the 2-3 per cent range was not intended to specify outer limits, but rather to convey the idea of an approximate central tendency, or “thick point”, as Debelle and Stevens (1995: 3) have referred to it. Though other early adopters of inflation-targeting have a point target (such as the Bank of England), or a range (in New Zealand and Canada), the RBA had observed that inflation was hard to control in a precise way and attempts to do so over short periods risked are aggravating the economic instability the RBA is trying to reduce (Stevens 2003:20). Thus the formulation of the inflation target of the RBA allows for the inevitable uncertainties that are involved in forecasting and lags in the effects of monetary policy on the economy. The Operational Target The formal policy rate is the target cash rate, or the overnight rate, which is a market interest rate (Ho, 2009: 4). Changes in monetary policy by the RBA entail a change in the operating target for the cash rate, and hence a shift in the interest rate structure prevailing in the financial system. The two main instruments used by the RBA are repurchase agreements and discretionary operations. Repurchase agreements are of the deposit facility type with a ceiling and floor differing with 25 basis points from the prevailing policy rate. Discretionary operations are mainly repo and reverse repo as well as outright transactions and foreign exchange swaps (Ho 2009). Unlike many other central banks, such the Federal Reserve, the reserves at the RBA are only used for settlement in the payments system and not for reserve requirements. The close relationship between the cash rate and other money market interest rates is demonstrated in Figure 5. According to Ho (2009: 10), this low volatility is typical for central banks that are targeting the overnight rate. The RBA has taken up a proactive stance by providing the right amount of liquidity through its discretionary operations which has made the overnight rate seldom venture towards the boundaries. Furthermore, the RBA has 9
  • 11. defined a narrow corridor around the formal policy rate which also serves to dampen short-term market rate volatility (Ho 2009: 20). Figure 5: Short-term Interest Rates (RBA, 2011) Credibility and Transparency Critical to the RBA’s current strategy is establishing and maintaining credibility and transparency in their relationship with the private sector. Compared with previous decades this has managed to solidly anchor expectations around the top of the target band. It is important not to understate this achievement. According to Governor Stevens (2003:18), after decades of high inflation Australians were suffering from “inflation psychology”. The erosion of the value of money that had become a permanent feature for an entire generation of Australians was now reversed. The RBA is considered to be one of the most transparent central banks in the world. Openness is maintained by a regular dialogue with the public, through media releases, speeches and their comprehensive website. Monthly decisions pertaining to the cash rate are associated with an explanation of the reasons behind their action or inaction. Fracasso et al (2003) , in an comprehensive analysis of the quality and accessibility of information provided by inflation-targeting central banks, argue while the RBA’s written inflation reports remain relatively concise they rely more heavily on their disseminating data regularly through their website. Quarterly the RBA also releases an exhaustive Statement of Monetary Policy which includes detailed forecasting of international and domestic market conditions7. Inflation forecasts are a vital part of this statement and thus of the RBA’s communication strategy. Forecasts of inflation and GDP growth are point estimates over a 1-2 year period and 7 See the RBA website (http://www.rba.gov.au/) for records of previous Statements on Monetary Policy. 10
  • 12. crucially assume no change in the instrument (Edey, 2005: 12). There has been some discussion of changing the ‘no policy change’ assumption, as it could be misinterpreted by the private sector for expectations of inflation8. Credibility is considerably more difficult to establish than transparency, as it presumably requires the private sector to develop trust in the RBA’s record of hitting the target over time. Unlike monetary aggregate targeting where the private sector can immediately see the proof of the central bank performance, inflation-targeting involves a considerable lag before the target is realised. Hence being credible is critical to performance otherwise wages can easily get out of control. As mentioned above during the early 1990s the RBA suffered a lack of credibility given a string of comments made by Prime Minister Keating. Surprisingly though with the advent of inflation-targeting, expectations were quite quick to revert to the target band, and since then have stayed relatively stable. Although prior to the Global Financial Crisis it appears that the Australian public suffered from some second thoughts about the ability of the RBA to maintain inflation, overall the credibility of the current framework and the faith in the competency of the Board’s leadership is quite strong. 4. Inflation-Targeting Success There are several approaches we can employ in evaluating the success of the RBA’s inflation-targeting. Assistant Governor Debelle (1995) noted that it might be as simple as, “if, some years hence, we can look back and observe that the average rate of inflation has a ‘2’ in front of the decimal place that will be regarded as a success”. First, we will look at whether the RBA has achieved the target it has set for inflation. Secondly, it is assessed whether inflation-targeting has led to lower inflation volatility. Thirdly, the issue of inflation expectations will be dealt with by examining whether the inflation ‘psychology’, ubiquitous until the early 1990s, has left Australian mindsets. The last section will go into detail on whether IT has been associated with any cost to growth or unemployment. Hitting the Target For RBA Governors the flexibility of the target makes it not only easier to achieve, but also convenient for claiming success. In 2003 Governor Stevens (2003: 21) noted that after ten years of inflation-targeting the average inflation rate over the 38 quarters up to December 2002 was 2.4 per cent. In this way, he explained, the inflation target had been achieved. Truman (2003) does not view this as much of a surprise. He categorises Australia as a “maintainer”, a country that had already achieved its low-level target inflation prior to inflation-targeting being adopted. Figure 6 shows that if Australia’s target were strict rather than flexible the results would not be encouraging. CPI was only in line with the target in the period 2002-2006 and showed deviations (mainly above the 3 per cent 8 In reality it rarely the case there is no change in the instrument over the timeframe of a 1-2 year forecast, so in this sense forecast inflation should not be confused with an inflation expectation, because rational actors would expect the RBA to move the instrument in the event of a forecast outside the target band. Possible reforms might include releasing a probability distribution fan chart or an endogenous instrument change forecast (such as is done by the Bank of England). 11
  • 13. upper band) during the remaining periods. It is noteworthy that the deviations from the inflation targets have not been symmetric; while there have been breaches both on the upside and the downside, most have been on the upside. Australian Consumer Price Index 7.0 6.0 CPI (annual % change) 5.0 4.0 lower band 3.0 upper band 2.0 1.0 Consumer price index 0.0 Mar-1993 Mar-1994 Mar-1995 Mar-1996 Mar-1997 Mar-1998 Mar-1999 Mar-2000 Mar-2001 Mar-2002 Mar-2003 Mar-2004 Mar-2005 Mar-2006 Mar-2007 Mar-2008 Mar-2009 Mar-2010 -1.0 Figure 6: CPI inflation, headline from 1993 to 2011 (Source: RBA, 2011) As the RBA has defined the inflation target as “on average, over the cycle”, it is of interest to take a closer look at the performance of the main underlying indicator, the weighted median, in terms of its average over the cycle. Table 2 clearly shows that compared with the pre-period, inflation over the cycle has diminished towards the target as set by the RBA. However, the most recent cycle shows an upward deviation, partly caused by increased inflation during the global financial crisis. Though this does not seem to be part of a long term trend, the trimmed mean CPI of 2010 indicates that inflation has come back to its previous path with an average of 2.6 per cent over the year. On the whole, the RBA’s flexible inflation target seems to have been achieved by the RBA for the period of 1993-2010. CPI inflation, weighted median (on average over the period, in %) 1985-89 1990-94 1995-99 2000-04 2005-09 2010 7.7 3.3 2.2 2.6 3.4 2.6 Table 2: 5 Year averaged CPI inflation, trimmed mean (Source: Edey, 2005; and authors’ own calculations) 12
  • 14. Figure 7: CPI inflation volatility from 1984 to 2008 (Source: Lim, 2009) Reducing Inflation Volatility Successful inflation-targeting should not only constraint the level of inflation, but should also reduce its volatility. Lower inflation volatility would increase credibility and consequently strengthen lower inflation expectations (Filardo and Genberg 2009: 13). Figure 7 shows that prior to the implementation of the inflation-targeting framework in 1993, the volatility of CPI decreased considerably. The standard deviation over 5 year periods in Table 3 shows a similar trend. CPI inflation, weighted median (standard deviation, in %) 1985-89 1990-94 1995-99 2000-04 2005-09 2010 1.1 1.8 0.4 0.3 0.8 0.4 Table 3: 5 Year standard deviation in CPI inflation, trimmed mean (Source: Edey, 2005; and author's own calculations) Anchoring Inflation Expectations One of the reasons behind adopting the inflation-targeting framework was it was hoped its credibility would eventually rein in the nation’s high expectations of future inflation. As Figure 8 shows, inflation expectations in Australia have decreased greatly with the adoption of inflation-targeting in 1993. This shows that the RBA had sent out a strong signal that inflation control was a priority. The policy had been well communicated with people expecting and acting on the prospect of stable prices. The benefit of controlling inflation expectations is it an additional ‘soft’ method of controlling actual inflation compared with the ‘hard’ cash rate instrument. To the extent that the economy is ‘self-controlling’ when it comes to inflation, the instrument becomes more available to realise other secondary goals (Bofinger, 2001: 113; Bernanke, 2004). 13
  • 15. Figure 8: Inflation expectations from 1975 to 2003 (Source: Stevens, 2003) Figure 9 shows the high correlation between the actual underlying inflation and consumer inflation expectations. Since introducing inflation-targeting, inflation expectations have been on the upper side of the range defined by the RBA as shown in Table 4. It seems that there continues to be a significant proportion of households anticipating inflation higher than defined by the RBA. Particularly in the period leading up to the financial crisis, between December 2006 and June 2008, inflation expectations exceeded the CPI, and during the global downturn inflation and inflation expectations both significantly exceeded the target band. This may indicate that the RBA’s credibility was tested while moving the through the uncharted waters of the crisis. Consumers' inflation expectation (average, in %) 1995-99 2000-04 2005-09 2010 2.5 3.1 3.5 3.1 Table 4: 5 Year consumer inflation expectation (Source: RBA, 2011: and authors' own calculations) Inflation Expectations and CPI 7.0 6.0 5.0 4.0 3.0 2.0 1.0 0.0 Jun-1993 Jun-1995 Jun-1997 Jun-1999 Jun-2001 Jun-2003 Jun-2005 Jun-2007 Jun-2009 -1.0 Consumers' inflation expectation Consumer price index Figure 9: Inflation Expectations and CPI from 1993 to 2010 (Source: RBA, 2011) 14
  • 16. Taking a long-term perspective, Finlay and Wende (2011:13) hold that 1-year-ahead inflation expectations are much more volatile than 5- and 10-year-ahead expectations and are strongly influenced by current inflation. Longer-term inflation expectations appear to be well-anchored within the 2 to 3 per cent target range. A Macroeconomic ‘Free Lunch’ Some authors, such as Truman (2003), have argued that inflation-targeting can reduce inflation without negatively effecting output growth or employment in the real economy, the equivalent of a macroeconomic “free lunch”. Figures 10 and 11 demonstrate that the lower average level of inflation and the decreased volatility have not come at the expense of slower or more variable output growth. On the contrary, unemployment is lower and output variability has decreased. The conclusion that this is a causal relationship must be taken with a grain of salt though. Global economic conditions since 1993 have been quite conducive to economic growth and countries that do not target inflation as part of their monetary policy have seen similar improvements in economic conditions (Filardo and Genberg, 2009). The period also overlaps with the longest resources boom in Australian history. Figure 10 and 11: GDP Growth Rate and Unemployment Rate from 1984 to 2008 (Source: Lim, 2009) 5. Not an Inflation-Targeting ‘Nutter’ In 1997 the then Chief Economist of the Bank of England, Mervyn King, coined the term, “inflation nutter” to refer to the burgeoning number of central banks who appeared to be operating as strict inflation-targeters. The RBA is certainly not a strict inflation-targeting “nutter”. The combination of being credible and transparent with the public strengthens low and stable inflation expectations, while the flexibility the RBA enjoys in hitting its medium- term inflation target, gives considerable ‘room’ in the short-term. The combination of all these attributes permits the RBA the capacity to also focus on secondary policy objectives, particularly in the short-term. It should be 15
  • 17. remembered that the framework affords the RBA the capacity to also focus on secondary policy objectives, but does not compel them to do so. However since 1993 there is strong evidence that the RBA has made use of this capacity by targeting short-term output and employment gaps, and more controversially asset price bubbles. Figure12: How the RBA's Policy Framework Affords Secondary Policy Objectives Beyond Inflation Output and Employment Gaps If the Reserve Bank Board is in a position to compare two “paths” to the medium-term target, the Pareto-optimal “path”, as far as welfare is concerned, is the one that causes the least amount of volatility to the real economy. A typical decision might be to “go hard” now against rising inflation or to “go hard” later. Faced with such a decision, the Board may decide to use the short-term Phillips Curve to generate ‘surprise’ inflation in order to achieve the least amount of volatility to output and employment gaps (Debelle, 1995). Or as Bernanke (2004) puts it, “well-anchored inflation expectations may afford the central bank more short-term flexibility to respond to economic disturbances that affect output and employment”. Figure13: Inflation and Unemployment Gaps and Non-Zero Official Cash Rate Changes from 1993 to 2007 (Source: Lim, 2009) 16
  • 18. The evidence since 1993 suggests the RBA frequently has often decided to use this flexibility to target real gaps in the economy. Figure 13 shows all non-zero interest rates changes against the inflation and employed gap, with black representing positive movements and the white for negative ones. A simple interpretation of the policy of strict inflation-targeting should produce positive interest rates changes with positive inflation gaps and vice versa for negative inflation gaps9. In about half the Board’s decisions when inflation was high and unemployment was high they decided to respond to unemployment by cutting rates. A similar pattern of exceptions to strict inflation- targeting can be noticed when interest rate decisions are plotted against the output gap. Asset Price Bubbles A more controversial notion is that the RBA uses monetary policy to combat perceived asset price bubbles. This practice has been likened by Posen (2009) to be a case of, “When the only tool you have is a hammer, it is tempting to treat everything as if it were a nail”. There is strong evidence during 2002-04 that this is exactly what the RBA did. Concerns built throughout 2002 and 2003 that a property bubble was developing in Australia due to the introduction of the first home-buyer grant in 2000 and changes to capital gains exemptions in 1999. In the five years following 1997 housing prices doubled, increasing by 40 per cent over 2002 and 2003 alone (Bloxham et al, 2010: 2). In response the RBA during 2002 to 2004 ‘chased the bubble’ by tightening interest rates. This occurred in contrast to increasing interest rates in every other developed economy, and most large developing economies during the same period. Figure14: Average Nominal House Prices, Australia and the United States (Source: ABS, Datastream) 9 This analysis only considers the inflation gap at the time of the interest rate decision, and does not assess projected inflation, which would be a more appropriate form of analysis. For example, while a current inflation gap might be positive, the trend might be receding with projected inflation expected to be on or below target. In this case an interest rate reduction might be warranted to maintain the inflation target. 17
  • 19. As an additional tool the RBA implemented a campaign of ‘open mouth operations’ in an attempt dampen the property market, involving repeatedly explanating that monetary policy was actively being used to combat “overheating in the property market”10. The most elucidating comment by Governor Stevens that the RBA believed in actively targeting the property bubble was, “… a case might be made, on rare occasions, to adopt a policy of ‘least regret’ so far as asset prices are concerned, if financial and macroeconomic stability were thought to be at risk” (Stevens, 2003). The use of monetary policy was remarkably successful in completely halting the growth of the bubble (see Figure 14), however it is unknown as to what cost to the real economy these interest rate rises came. An interesting ex post comparison can be made with the United States, where loose monetary policy is blamed by some for fuelling the property boom that culminated in the sub-prime mortgage crisis of 2007 (Taylor, 2009). Now many commentators believe Australia is in the midst of another housing bubble, with The Economist (2010) concluding that housing prices are currently on average 63 per cent over-valued. 6. Concluding Remarks The pioneering and flexible inflation-targeting of the RBA can be regarded, so far, as a success. However two notes of moderation must be trumpeted before we herald the end of Australian monetary history. Firstly, the onset of inflation-targeting in Australia has also coincided with the longest commodity boom in Australian history. As a result attributing the gains in the real economy during this period to the new monetary framework is problematic. However the fact that the framework has largely caged Australia’s decades of post-war inflation is not too much of a stretch to suggest. Secondly, the flexibility of the target itself has permitted subsequent Governors to rhetorically get away with a fuzzier version of what actually counts as success, compared with stricter frameworks. The design of an inflation-targeting framework that focuses on maintaining the triumvirate of credibility, transparency and flexibility is a pragmatic way of conducting monetary policy that allows the RBA not to fall into a monofocal obsession with simply the monetary phenomenon of inflation. Transparency is a relatively easy reform to introduce, one the RBA has achieved through publishing comprehensive volumes of timely explanations of its use of the cash rate instrument and forecasts of future inflation and other economic indicators. Credibility is considerably harder and involves gaining the private sector’s trust that the economy will, more or less, hit the inflation-target. While inflation expectations did get out hand in the period just prior to the Global Financial Crisis, overall 10 th For example on 8 May 2002 a RBA media release stated, “To persist with a strongly expansionary policy setting … could fuel other imbalances such as the current overheating in the housing market, potentially jeopardising the economy’s continued expansion”. The quarterly Statement on Monetary Policy in February 2003 reaffirmed to risk of the asset price bubble, “… the run-up in housing prices and associated expansion in housing related debt were a source of concern for most of the past year, given the potential of such a process to remain disconnected from fundamentals and develop into a significant imbalance over time.” 18
  • 20. expectations have generally sat nicely around the top of the target band since 1993. The younger generations of Australians appear no longer afflicted by Steven’s (2003: 18) “inflation psychology”. Flexibility is the final ingredient that possibly makes the RBA’s framework attractive as a model for other countries considering reforming monetary policy to emulate. Target flexibility may permit a prudent Reserve Bank Board to outperform stricter frameworks by also smoothing the volatility felt by the real economy en route to the inflation target. The policy flexibility the RBA enjoys and its considerable instrument independence is also balanced by a high degree of accountability to the nation’s democratic government. However this fact may also conceal its greatest weakness, given that the current institutional arrangement does not protect the RBA’s independence from capture from a more domineering future Government. 19
  • 21. 7. Bibliography Arnone, M., Laurens, B. J. and Segalotto., J.F. (2006). "The Measurement of Central Bank Autonomy: Survey of Models, Indicators, and Empirical Evidence“. IMF Working Paper No. 06/227. Battellino, R. and M. Plumb (2009). “A Generation of an Internationalised Australian Dollar”. Address to BIS/Bank of Korea Seminar on Currency Internationalisation, Seoul. Retrieved from: http://www.bis.org/ . Bell, S. (2004). Australia’s Money Mandarins: The Reserve Bank and the Politics of Money. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Bernanke, B. (2004). “Central Bank Talk and Monetary Policy”. Retrieved from: http://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/2004/200410072/default.htm/ . Bloxham, P., Kent, C. and Robson, M. (2010). “Asset Prices, Credit Growth, and Monetary and Other Policies: An Australian Case Study”. Reserve Bank of Australia Research Discussion Paper 2010-06. Bofinger, P. (2001). Monetary Policy: Goals, Institutions, Strategies, and Instruments. Oxford, Oxford University Press. Brischetto, A. and Richards, A. (2006). The Performance of Trimmed Mean Measures of Underlying Inflation. RBA Research Discussion Paper, December 2006. Retrieved at: http://www.rba.gov.au/ . Coleman, W. (2004). “How the Bank Got Its Groove Back”. Retrieved from: http://epress.anu.edu.au/. Cukierman, A. (1992). Central Bank Strategies, Credibility, and Independence: Theory and Evidence. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Economist, The (2010, Oct 10). “Global House Prices: Floor to Ceiling”. Retrieved from: http://www.economist.com/. Edey, M. (2005). “An Australian Perspective on Inflation-targeting, Communication and Transparency”. BIS Paper 31, Monetary policy in Asia: approaches and implementation: 3-24. Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) (1996). “Meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee, 2-3, 1996”. Retrieved from: http://www.federalreserve.gov/. Filardo, A. and Genberg, H. (2009). Targeting Inflation in Asia and the Pacific: lessons from the recent past. BIS Working Paper 52. 20
  • 22. Finlay, R. and Wende, S. (2011). “Estimating Inflation Expectations with a Limited Number of Inflation-indexed Bonds”. RBA Research Discussion Paper 2011-01. Fracasso, A., Genberg, H., and Wyplosz, C. (2003). “How do Central Banks Write? An Evaluation of Inflation-targeting Central Banks”. Geneva Reports on the World Economy Special Report 2. Fraser, B. (1994). “Central Bank Independence: What Does It Mean?” Reserve Bank of Australia Bulletin December 1994: 1-8. Henry, K. (2003). “Australia and the international financial architecture — 60 years on”. Retrieved from: http://www.treasury.gov.au/. Ho, C. (2009). Implementing monetary policy in the 2000s: operating procedures in Asia and beyond. BIS Working Paper 253. Lim, G.C. (2009). “Inflation-targeting”. Australian Economic Review, vol. 42(1): 110–118. Posen, A. S. (2009). “Finding the Right Tool for Dealing with Asset Price Booms”. Speech to the MPR Monetary Policy and the Economy Conference, London. Retrieved from: http://www.iie.com/publications/papers/posen1209.pdf . Rasche, R.H. and Thornton, D.L. (2006). “Greenspan’s Unconventional View of the Long-Run Inflation/Output Trade-off. Monetary Trends”. Monetary Trends. Retrieved at: http://research.stlouisfed.org . Reserve Bank of Australia (RBA) (1996). Statement on the Conduct of Monetary Policy. Retrieved from: http://www.rba.gov.au/monetary-policy/framework/stmt-conduct-mp-1-14081996.html . (2011). “About Monetary Policy”. Retrieved from: http://www.rba.gov.au/monetary- policy/about.html Richards, A. and Rosewall, T. (2010). “Measuring Underlying Inflation”. In: RBA Statement on Monetary Policy March 2010. Retrieved at: http://www.rba.gov.au/ . Sousa, P. (2002). Central Bank Independence and Democratic Accountability. Portucalense University, Mimeo. Stevens, G. (2003). “Inflation-targeting: A Decade of Australian Experience”. Reserve Bank of Australia Bulletin April 2003. Stevens, G. and Debelle, G. (1995). “Monetary Policy Goals for Inflation in Australia”. In A.G. Haldane (ed.), Targeting Inflation: 81-100. London: Bank of England. 21
  • 23. Taylor, J. B. (2009). “The financial crisis and the policy responses: An empirical analysis of what went wrong”. NBER Working Paper 14631. Truman, E. (2003). Inflation-targeting in the World Economy. Washington, DC: Institute of International Economics. 22