Chapter 5 Efficiency and Equity· Using prices in markets to a.docx
Chapter 5 Efficiency and Equity· Using prices in markets to a.docx
Chapter 5 Efficiency and Equity· Using prices in markets to a.docx
Chapter 5 Efficiency and Equity· Using prices in markets to a.docx
Chapter 5 Efficiency and Equity· Using prices in markets to a.docx
Chapter 5 Efficiency and Equity· Using prices in markets to a.docx
Chapter 5 Efficiency and Equity· Using prices in markets to a.docx
Chapter 5 Efficiency and Equity· Using prices in markets to a.docx
Chapter 5 Efficiency and Equity· Using prices in markets to a.docx
Chapter 5 Efficiency and Equity· Using prices in markets to a.docx
Chapter 5 Efficiency and Equity· Using prices in markets to a.docx
Chapter 5 Efficiency and Equity· Using prices in markets to a.docx
Chapter 5 Efficiency and Equity· Using prices in markets to a.docx
Chapter 5 Efficiency and Equity· Using prices in markets to a.docx
Chapter 5 Efficiency and Equity· Using prices in markets to a.docx
Chapter 5 Efficiency and Equity· Using prices in markets to a.docx
Chapter 5 Efficiency and Equity· Using prices in markets to a.docx
Chapter 5 Efficiency and Equity· Using prices in markets to a.docx
Chapter 5 Efficiency and Equity· Using prices in markets to a.docx
Chapter 5 Efficiency and Equity· Using prices in markets to a.docx
Chapter 5 Efficiency and Equity· Using prices in markets to a.docx
Chapter 5 Efficiency and Equity· Using prices in markets to a.docx
Chapter 5 Efficiency and Equity· Using prices in markets to a.docx
Chapter 5 Efficiency and Equity· Using prices in markets to a.docx
Chapter 5 Efficiency and Equity· Using prices in markets to a.docx
Chapter 5 Efficiency and Equity· Using prices in markets to a.docx
Chapter 5 Efficiency and Equity· Using prices in markets to a.docx
Chapter 5 Efficiency and Equity· Using prices in markets to a.docx
Prochain SlideShare
Economic-Efficiency and EquityEconomic-Efficiency and Equity
Chargement dans ... 3
1 sur 28

Contenu connexe

Plus de christinemaritza(20)

Chapter 5 Efficiency and Equity· Using prices in markets to a.docx

  1. Chapter 5: Efficiency and Equity · Using prices in markets to allocate scarce resources is one of many alternative methods of allocating scarce resources. · Tools such as consumer surplus and producer surplus help evaluate efficiency. · The outcomes from the various methods used to allocate scarce resources, especially markets, can be examined in terms of both their efficiency and fairness. I. Resource Allocation Methods Resources are scarce, so they somehow must be allocated. Different methods of allocating resources include: · Market price: The people who are willing and able to buy a resource get the resource. · Command: a command system allocates resources by the order (command) of someone in authority. A command system works well in organizations with clear lines of authority but does not work well at allocating resources in the entire economy. · Majority rule: resources are allocated in accordance with majority vote. Majority rule works well when the allocation decisions being made affect a large number of people and self- interest leads to bad decisions. · Contest: resources are allocated to the winner. Contests work well when the efforts of the players are hard to measure, such as top managers being in a contest to be named CEO of a company.
  2. · First-come, first-serve: resources are allocated to those who are first in line. This allocation method works well when the resource can serve just one user at a time in a sequence, as is the case with, say, a bank teller or an ATM. · Lottery: resources are allocated to the people who pick the winning number, choose the lucky card, etc. Lotteries work best when there is no effective way to distinguish among potential users of a scarce resource. · Personal characteristics: resources are allocated to people with the “right” characteristics. · Force: resources are allocated to those who can forcibly take the resources. II. Benefit, Cost, and Surplus Demand, Willingness to Pay, and Value · The value of one more unit of a good or service is its marginal benefit. Marginal benefit is the maximum price that people are willing to pay for another unit of a good or service. And the willingness to pay for a good or service determines the demand for it. Consequently the demand curve for a good or service is also its marginal benefit curve. · The market demand curve is the horizontal sum of the individual demand curves and is formed by adding the quantities demanded by all the individuals at each price. · The demand curve in the figure shows that the maximum price a person is willing to pay for the 6 millionth gallon of milk per month is $3, so $3 is the marginal benefit of this gallon.
  3. · MSB curve: In the absence of externalities, which will be discussed later, the market demand curve is also the economy’s marginal social benefit (MSB) curve. It reflects the number of dollars’ worth of other goods and services willingly given up to obtain one more unit of a good. · The figure shows that the maximum price a consumer is willing and able to pay for the 6 millionth gallon of milk is $3, so the marginal social benefit of the 6 millionth gallon of milk is $3. · Consumer surplus is the value (or marginal benefit) of the good minus the price paid for it, summed over the quantity bought. The figure illustrates the consumer surplus as the shaded triangle when the price is $3 per gallon. Supply, Cost, and Minimum Supply-Price · The cost of producing one more unit of a good or service is its marginal cost. Marginal cost is the minimum price that producers must receive to induce them to produce another unit of the good or service. And the minimum acceptable price determines the quantity supplied. Consequently the supply curve for a good or service is also its marginal cost curve. · The market supply curve is the horizontal sum of the individual supply curves and is formed by adding the quantities supplied by all the producers at each price. · MSC curve: In the absence of externalities, the market supply curve is the economy’s marginal social cost (MSC) curve. · The supply curve in the figure shows that the minimum price a producer must receive to be willing to produce the 6 millionth gallon of milk per month is $3, so $3 is the marginal social cost of this gallon.
  4. · Producer surplus is the price of a good minus its minimum supply-price (or marginal cost), summed over the quantity sold. The figure illustrates the producer surplus as the shaded triangle when the price is $3 per gallon. III. Is the Competitive Market Efficient? Efficiency of Competitive Equilibrium · The marginal benefit to the entire society is the marginal social benefit curve, MSB. If all the benefits from consuming a good go to its consumers, the market demand curve is the same as the MSB curve. · The marginal cost to the entire society is the marginal social cost curve, MSC. If all the costs of producing a good are paid by the producers, the market supply curve is the same as the MSC curve. · When the marginal social benefit of the last unit produced equals its marginal social cost, society attains efficiency. However, because the demand curve is the same as the MSB curve and the supply curve is the same as the MSC curve, the efficient quantity that sets the MSB equal to the MSC also sets the quantity demanded equal to the quantity supplied and so is the equilibrium quantity. The figure illustrates how the efficient quantity of milk, 6 million gallons per month, also is the equilibrium quantity of milk. · When the efficient quantity of milk is produced, the sum of the consumer surplus and producer surplus (total surplus) is maximized. All the results of efficiency at this point can be summarized as follows:
  5. · By definition, efficiency requires that resources are being used where they are most highly valued. · When resources are used where they are most highly valued, MSB = MSC. · When the demand and supply curves intersect, QD = QS, and the market achieves equilibrium. · At equilibrium the total surplus in the market is maximized. Buyers and sellers acting in their own self-interest maximize social well-being. The Invisible Hand · Adam Smith, in his 1776 book The Wealth of Nations, articulated how competition led self-interested consumers and producers to make choices that unintentionally promote the social interest as if they were led by an “invisible hand.” Underproduction and Overproduction · Inefficiency can occur because either too little of an item is produced (underproduction) or too much is produced (overproduction). · In either case, a deadweight loss occurs. A deadweight loss is the decrease in the consumer surplus and producer surplus (decrease in total surplus) that results from producing at an inefficient level of production. The figure illustrates the deadweight loss from overproduction of milk and from underproduction. Obstacles to Efficiency
  6. Sometimes a market overproduces or underproduces a good or service. The key obstacles to achieving an efficient allocation of resources in a market are: · Price and Quantity Regulations: A price ceiling sets the highest legal price and a price floor sets the lowest legal price. If a price ceiling or price floor makes the equilibrium price illegal, it can lead to inefficiency. Quantity regulations that limit the amount produced also lead to inefficiency. (Studied in Chapter 6) · Taxes and Subsidies: Taxes and subsidies place a wedge between the prices consumers pay and the prices producers receive. Both can lead to inefficiency. (Studied in Chapter 6) · Externalities: An externality is a cost or a benefit that affects someone other than the seller or the buyer. In that case, the demand curve is not the same as the marginal social benefit curve and/or the supply curve is not the same as the marginal social cost curve. In these cases, inefficiency results. (Studied in Chapter 16) · Public Goods and Common Resources: A public good is a good or service that is consumed simultaneously by everyone even if they don’t pay for it. Public goods lead to a free-rider problem, in which people do not pay for their share of the good. A common resource is owned by no one but available to be used by everyone. Common resources are generally over-used because no one owns the resource. In both cases, inefficiency can occur. (Studied in Chapter 17) · Monopoly: A monopoly is a firm that has sole control of a market. To maximize its profit, a monopoly produces less than the efficient quantity and so creates inefficiency. (Studied in Chapter 13)
  7. · High transactions costs: The opportunity costs of making a trade are transactions costs. When these costs are high, a market might underproduce because too few transactions take place. Alternatives to the Market If markets do not allocate resources efficiently, then one of the alternatives might do a better job. For instance, using first- come, first-serve to allocate spaces in a line at a movie theater probably works better than a market. IV. Is the Competitive Market Fair? · Efficiency is a positive term, while equity is a normative term. Not everyone can agree upon what is fair. · There are two general ways of defining fairness: “It’s not fair if the results aren’t fair” and “It’s not fair if the rules aren’t fair.” It’s Not Fair If the Result Isn’t Fair · Utilitarianism adopts this view. Utilitarianism is a principle that states that we should strive to achieve “the greatest happiness for the greatest number.” This principle argues that fairness requires equality of incomes, which requires that incomes be redistributed. · Redistribution leads to the big tradeoff, the tradeoff between efficiency and fairness. The tradeoff occurs because taxes decrease people’s incentives to work, thereby decreasing the size of the “economic pie.” In addition, taxes lead to administration costs that also decrease the economic pie. · John Rawls argued that redistribution should strive to make the poorest as well off as possible which may mean a smaller piece of a bigger pie, rather than an equal piece, to keep
  8. incentives in place. It’s Not Fair If the Rules Aren’t Fair · This perspective relies on the symmetry principle—the requirement that people in similar situations should be treated similarly. In economics, this means equality of economic opportunity rather than equality of economic outcomes. · Robert Nozick suggests government should promote fairness by establishing property rights for individuals and allowing only voluntary exchange of these resources. · If private property rights are enforced, if voluntary exchange takes place in a competitive market, and if none of the obstacles to efficiency listed before exist, then according to Nozick, the competitive market is fair. Chapter 4: Elasticity Elasticity · The price elasticity of demand measures how strongly buyers respond to a change in the price of a good. · The price elasticity of demand can be used to make quantitative predictions of how changes affect the price and quantity demanded of a good. · The income elasticity of demand measures how strongly demanders respond to a change in income, and the cross elasticity of demand measures how strongly demanders respond to the change in the price of another good.
  9. · The price elasticity of supply measures how strongly producers respond to a change in the price of a good. I. Price Elasticity of Demand · In general, elasticity measures responsiveness. The price elasticity of demand measures how responsive demanders are to a change in the price of the good. This information is often useful for both businesses and governments because it can predict the impact of a price change on total revenue or total expenditure. Calculating Price Elasticity of Demand · The price elasticity of demand is a units-free measure of the responsiveness of the quantity demanded of a good to a change in its price when all other influences on a buyer’s plans remain unchanged. The price elasticity of demand is equal to the absolute value of: · . price in change Percentage demanded quantity
  10. in change Percentage The demand elasticity formula yields a negative value, because price and quantity move in opposite directions. However, it is the magnitude, or absolute value, of the measure that reveals how responsive the quantity change has been to a price change. So we use the magnitude or the absolute value of the price elasticity of demand. · The table to the right has two points on the demand curve for pizza from a particular pizza parlor. · The absolute value of the percent change in quantity demanded is [(500 ( 400) ( 450] ( 100 = 22.2 percent. · The absolute value of the percentage change in price is [($14 ( $16) ( $15] ( 100 = 13.3 percent. · Between these two points on the demand curve, the price elasticity of demand is 22.2% ( 13.3% = 1.67. Inelastic and Elastic Demand · If the price elasticity of demand is less than 1.0, the good is said to have an inelastic demand. In this case, the percentage change in the quantity demanded is less than the percentage change in price. · If the quantity demanded remains constant when the price changes, then the good is said to have perfectly inelastic demand. The price elasticity of demand is 0 and the good’s
  11. demand curve is a vertical line. · If the price elasticity of demand is equal to 1.0, the good is said to have a unit elastic demand. In this case, the percentage change in the quantity demanded equals the percentage change in price. · If the price elasticity of demand is greater than 1.0, the good is said to have an elastic demand. In this case, the percentage change in the quantity demanded exceeds the percentage change in price. Furniture 1.26 Motor Vehicles 1.14 Clothing 0.64 Oil 0.05 · If the quantity demanded changes by an infinitely large percentage in response to a tiny price change, then the good is said to have perfectly elastic demand. The price elasticity of demand is infinite. · The table has some “real-life” elasticities from the book. Elasticity Along a Linear Demand Curve · With the exception of a vertical demand curve and a horizontal demand curve (along which the elasticity is 0 and infinite, respectively) the price elasticity of demand changes when moving along a linear demand curve. · As the figure illustrates, at points on the demand curve above the midpoint, the price elasticity of demand is elastic while at points below the midpoint, the price elasticity of demand is
  12. inelastic. At the midpoint, the price elasticity of demand is unit elastic. Total Revenue and Elasticity · The total revenue from the sale of a good equals the price of the good multiplied by the quantity sold. · If demand is elastic, a 1 percent price cut increases the quantity sold by more than 1 percent and total revenue increases. · If demand is unit elastic, a 1 percent price cut increases the quantity sold by 1 percent and total revenue does not change. · If demand is inelastic, a 1 percent price cut increases the quantity sold by less than 1 percent and total revenue decreases. · The total revenue test is a method of estimating the price elasticity of demand by observing the change in total revenue that results from a change in price, when all other influences on the quantity sold remain the same. · If a price cut increases total revenue, demand is elastic. And if a price hike decreases total revenue, demand is elastic. · If a price cut does not change total revenue, demand is unit elastic. And if a price hike does not change total revenue, demand is unit elastic. · If a price cut decreases total revenue, demand is inelastic. And if a price hike increases total revenue, demand is inelastic. · Similarly, when a price changes, a consumer’s change in expenditure depends on the consumer’s elasticity of demand.
  13. · If demand is elastic, then a price cut means that expenditure on the item increases. · If demand is inelastic, then a price cut means that expenditure on the item decreases. · If demand is unit elastic, then a price cut means that expenditure on the item does not change. The Factors that Influence the Elasticity of Demand The magnitude of the price elasticity of demand depends on: · The closeness of substitutes: The closer and more numerous the substitutes for a good or service, the more elastic the demand. This is critical for understanding demand in the market structure section later in the book. · The proportion of income spent on the good: The greater the proportion of income spent on a good or service, the more elastic the demand. · The amount of time elapsed since the price change: The longer the time elapsed since the price change, the more elastic the demand. II. More Elasticities of Demand Income Elasticity of Demand · The income elasticity of demand is a measure of the responsiveness of the demand for a good to a change in the income, other things remaining the same. · The income elasticity of demand is equal to:
  14. . income in change Percentage demanded quantity in change Percentage The changes in the quantity demanded and income are percentages of the average income and quantity demanded over the range of change. · The income elasticity of demand is positive for normal goods and negative for inferior goods. · If the income elasticity of demand is greater than 1, demand is income elastic and the good is a normal good. As income increases, the percentage of income spent on income elastic goods increases. Airline Travel 5.82 Restaurant Meals
  15. 1.61 Clothing 0.51 Food 0.14 · If the income elasticity of demand is positive but less than 1, demand is income inelastic and the good is a normal good. As income increases, the percentage of income spent on income inelastic goods decreases. · If the income elasticity of demand is negative the good is an inferior good. · The table has some “real-life” income elasticities from the book. Cross Elasticity of Demand · The cross elasticity of demand is a measure of the responsiveness of the demand for a good to a change in the price of a substitute or complement, other things remaining the same. · The cross elasticity of demand is equal to: . complement or substitute a of
  16. price in change Percentage demanded quantity in change Percentage The changes in the quantity demanded and the price are percentages of the average price and quantity demanded over the range of change. · The cross elasticity of demand is positive for substitutes and negative for complements. III. Elasticity of Supply · The elasticity of supply measures how responsive producers are to a change in the price of the good. · The elasticity of supply measures the responsiveness of the quantity supplied to a change in the price of a good when all other influences on selling plans remain unchanged. · The elasticity of supply is equal to:
  17. . price in change Percentage supplied quantity in change Percentage Three Cases of Elasticity of Supply · Supply is perfectly inelastic if the elasticity of supply equals 0. In this case, the supply curve is vertical. · Supply is unit elastic if the elasticity of supply equals 1. In this case, the supply curve is linear and passes through the origin. If any supply curve is linear and passes through the origin, the supply is unit elastic; the slope of the supply curve is irrelevant. · Supply is perfectly elastic if the elasticity of supply is infinite. In this case, the supply curve is horizontal. Price (dollars per pizza) Quantity supplied (pizzas per week)
  18. 14 300 16 400 · The table to the right has two points on the supply curve for pizza from a particular pizza parlor. · The percentage change in the quantity supplied is [(400 ( 300) ( 350] ( 100 = 28.6 percent. · The percentage change in price is [($16 ( $14) ( $15] ( 100 = 13.3 percent. · Between these two points, the elasticity of supply is 28.6% ( 13.3% = 2.15. · Supply is elastic if the elasticity of supply exceeds 1.0, unit elastic if the elasticity of supply equals 1.0, and inelastic if the elasticity of supply is less than 1.0. The Factors that Influence the Elasticity of Supply · Resource substitution possibilities: The more unique or rare the resources used to produce the good, the smaller the elasticity of supply. The more common the resources used to produce the good, the larger the elasticity of supply. · The time frame for substitution possibilities: The longer the amount of time producers have to adjust to a change in price, the more elastic the supply will be. · Momentary supply refers to the period of time immediately following a price change. For some goods, the momentary supply can be perfectly inelastic—fresh fish the day of a price hike. For other goods, the momentary supply can be quite elastic—when the number of telephone calls increases on a holiday, the supply increases with no change in price.
  19. · Short-run supply shows how the quantity supplied responds to a price change when only some of the technological adjustments have been made. · Long-run supply shows how the quantity supplied responds to a price change when all of the technological adjustments have been made. Price�(dollars per pizza)� Quantity demanded�(pizzas per week)� � 14� 500� � 16� 400� � _1143217591.unknown _1143217956.unknown _1143217114.unknown _1143213000.unknown Chapter 5 Assignment The purpose of this assignment is to give you a better understanding of consumer and producer surplus. To keep it simple, keep in mind the formula for
  20. finding the area of a triangle which is: Area equals one-half of the height of the triangle multiplied by the base of the triangle, or A=.5(h x b) A local restaurant sells the best hotwings in town. A single consumer’s demand for the hotwings is shown in the table and graph below Price 14 Price Quantity $14 0 12 $12 1 $10 2 10 $8 3 A Supply $6 4 8 $4 5 $2 6 6 $0 7
  21. B 4 2 Demand 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 Quantity a) If the equilibrium price of a serving of hotwings is $6.00, how much consumer surplus does the consumer receive? (figure out the area of triangle A) b) Explain how you calculated it. c) What is the producer surplus? (figure out the area of triangle B) 14 12
  22. 10 A Supply 8 B D 6 C 4 2 Demand 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 d) Now, let the price of a serving of hotwings increase to $8.00. By how much does your consumer surplus decrease? (Your new consumer surplus is area A above. Compare that to your answer to question “a” above. The difference is your reduction in consumer surplus.)
  23. e) What is the producer surplus with the $8.00 price? (Remember, producer surplus is the area above the supply curve and below the price. So it will be the sum of areas B and C (area of C is 7.5).) f) By how much did the producer surplus increase? (You need to compare your answer to “e” with your answer to “c”.) g) With the price being $8.00, what is the deadweight loss? (You can figure that out by calculating the areas of the two small triangles I labeled as D, or you can subtract the sum of the consumer and producer surplus when the price is $8.00 from the sum of the consumer and producer surplus when the price is $6.00) The next week, the restaurant owner decides to offer an “all you can eat” special for $20. This means that you pay $20 at the door. And once you enter, you can eat all the wings you want for no additional charge. h) Assuming your demand curve for servings of hotwings is still represented by the demand
  24. curve in the graphs above, how many servings of hotwings will you eat now, and how much consumer surplus do you receive now? (Once you pay the $20, your marginal cost for each serving of hotwings that you eat is zero. So, figure out your consumer surplus with a zero price (the entire triangle), then subtract the $20 you had to pay to get in.) i) If you want to press your luck, answer this one. If your demand curve represents the demand of the “typical customer” of this restaurant, what is the highest price the restaurant could charge for the “all you can eat” special and still attract customers? (At this point, price is 5, and the quantity supplied is 3) Chapter 4 Assignment: The tables below show the cumulative demand for 12 ounce cans of Coca-Cola as provided by students in a previous class. Original Income Doubles
  25. Pepsi is $.20 cheaper than Coke Price 950 200 Avg. Price 950 200 Avg. Price 950 200 Avg. $1.50 54 26 40 $1.50 87 40 64 $1.50 44 20 32 $1.25 63 30 47 $1.25 100
  26. 46 73 $1.25 55 27 41 $1.00 83 36 60 $1.00 125 56 91 $1.00 67 35 51 $0.75 115 53 84 $0.75 175 82 129 $0.75 92 48 70 $0.50
  27. 160 75 118 $0.50 241 106 174 $0.50 140 70 105 1. Using the “Avg.” column in the first table calculate self-price elasticity assuming the price of Coke increases from $1.00 to $1.25 per can (use the mid-point formula). 2. Using the first table and the second table (the “Avg. columns) calculate the income elasticity for Coke assuming income doubles and the price is $1.00 per can (again, use the mid-point formula). No matter what level of income you have, if you double it the percent change in income (when using the mid- point formula) will always be 66.7%. So, 66.7% will be your denominator. 3. Using the first table and the third table (the “Avg. columns) calculate the cross-price elasticity of demand for Coke assuming that table one shows the demand for Coke when the price of Coke is $1.00 per can and the price of Pepsi is $1.00 per can, and that table three shows the demand for Coke when the price of Coke is $1.00 per can and the price of Pepsi is $.80 per can (again, use the mid-point formula).