SlideShare une entreprise Scribd logo
1  sur  39
The Politics of Economic Instability in the 21st Century:
 Argentina and the Dissipation of an Economic Miracle
                                  Christopher Rinaldi
                          POL 95W -- Senior Capstone Seminar
                                     Thesis Paper
                               Professor Caroline Arnold


 This paper was written in 2008 for a capstone seminar course to complete my political

                        science major at CUNY Brooklyn College.

                                      Introduction

       In 1998, following the East Asian Financial Crisis and Russian Fiscal Crisis, the

economies of Latin America were confronted with the possibility of economic crises of

their own. A decade later the result of this confrontation seems to favor the resilient

economies of Latin America. This would be true, except for the case of Argentina, which

overshadows the achievements of their neighbors in avoiding economic disaster.

       Not only was Argentina overcome by an economic crisis, but the Argentine

economy was overcome, wholly, leading to a complete economic collapse. The central

question that this paper aims to answer is: Why did Argentina‟s economic crisis devolve

into utter economic collapse?

       I argue that, at first, Argentina‟s reaction to the crisis was deficient and

inefficient. The government failed to make change in monetary policies to ease the

shocks of devaluing their severely overvalued dollar. They maintained the currency

board, pegging the value of the Argentine peso to the US dollar, therefore encouraging

                                              1
capital flight out of the country, since the peso could be easily converted to the safer US

dollar currency of equal value.

          The manner of their privatization programs (Structural Adjustment Programs)

was extremely laissez-faire. This included a lack of regulatory boards, tax reforms,

budgetary reforms, and any necessary reform policies that should accompany

liberalization. Adequate policy to address the enormous public debt and the possibility of

bank insolvency was lacking as well. This left Argentina unprepared to maintain any

ground underneath their economy. Problems with fiscal responsibility at the provincial

level were never dealt with in any capacity by either federal or provincial governments.

By this, it is meant that during Argentina's economic boom until their economic collapse,

the government never made any reform that tackled the problem of maintaining spending

limits. This was compounded with a poor tax collection system which, as well, never

received any effective reform initiatives.

       All of these deficiencies displayed an economy built on a bubble defenseless to

the prodding international economy and economic shocks. This fragile economy was a

product of unstable politics and the Argentine government's reaction to the crisis they

faced, yet again, was produced by unstable politics. In sum, the faults of Argentina‟s

economy and their economic recovery efforts trace their roots to a political structure in

which political actors find no calculation worth making besides political ones. From the

federal to provincial level all issues, including economic issues, are political issues.

       The Argentine collapse is important to understand because it tells us something

about the new international economy and the shifting rules of capital. Capital, today, has

                                              2
an abundance of investment options compared to the Cold War period before the

dissolution of the Soviet Union. No longer is capital so single-minded to allocate itself

based on economic philosophies. In an environment in which almost every country is

liberalizing to some extent, and joining the international economy, capital‟s options

expand, and even sitting on capital in the short-term may be better than rash investments,

for the simple fact that if profits are missed in one country today, there will be another

country tomorrow.

       The consequences of this is that capital demands security in structures, not

philosophy. Therefore, the most liberal economy should be subject to stronger scrutiny.

Structures are the new magnetizing force for capital.     In a time when “hot money” and

disruptive capital flows can drive the economy down, capital flees towards gains, but also

safety. A country which can‟t accommodate capital‟s ever growing (and changing)

wants and needs is doomed for failure.     But to think that economic structures are not a

product of political structures, or to write this off as unimportant, is consistent with

philosophies which speak of the market as if it is natural and pre-existing. Humanity built

the market and humanity built its structures. Where there is conflict in humanity (politics)

there will be a conflict in the structures (economics). This conflict defines Argentina from

1991-2002, and it explains the country‟s economic collapse.

       Other scholars present varying explanations of the Argentine economic crisis

including: the unilateral action of Brazil in fixing their economic woes; IMF-style

development policy and privatization, and the formation of a small economic power bloc

of large domestic and international business interests that controlled capital and insisted

                                               3
on the maintenance of the currency board at the sake of Argentina‟s economy. These will

be considered against my hypothesis.

            I intend to focus on Argentina‟s economic collapse as an illustration of the

necessity to have a political system which allows for dexterity in economic policy and a

separation of that policy from political calculations. It is not an argument about state‟s

and their involvement with the economy, so much as it is an argument about states and

their ability to allow their economies to successfully react to and interact with the

international economy.

            Before undertaking my argument and taking on other explanations of the crisis, I

will lay out a brief history of the Argentine economy. This begins with the economic rise

in the first-half of the 1990‟s along with introduction of the fixed currency board. It ends

in 2002, after three years of deep recession leading to economic collapse.

            Following this, I will analyze and address alternative explanations of the

Argentine financial crisis. Finally, I will provide empirical support for my argument that

the politics of Argentina created an environment opposed to sustainable and competitive

economic development.

                                  A History of Argentina: 1991-20021

            At the beginning of the 1990‟s Argentina faced a dire problem of hyperinflation.

(Gallo et al, 2004, 196). When President Carlos Menem took office in 1991 this would

quickly change. He and his political ally, economic minister Domingo Cavallo, undertook

an IMF style austerity plan to revive the stagnant Argentine economy. At the center of

1
    All statistics in this section are taken from Gallo et al, Table 1: Economic Indicators, pg197.
                                                            4
this plan was the creation of a convertible currency board which pegged the Argentine

peso to the US dollar. In other words, 1 peso equaled 1 dollar. The currency board was

paired with privatization efforts, and soon the Argentine economy was well on its way to

development. The economy grew at a meteoric rate of 31.5% from 1991-1994.

        In 1995 the Mexican economic crisis caused shocks throughout the world, but

particularly in Latin America. Argentina saw economic recession after its quick boom.

The currency board, now fixed as law due to the iron-fisted President Menem, remained

in place (Gallo et al, 196). This seemed to be no problem though, as the Argentine

economy grew an astounding 13.6% in 1996 and 1997, including a 8.1% rate of growth

in 1997.

        1998 and 1999, by contrast, witnessed rates of growth, but below 4% for each

year. Still, more troubling, in 1999 GDP per capita declined at 4.3% in a year which the

GDP grew 3.4%. At this point, pessimism about the economy might have been helpful to

the extent it could have prompted reform. Unfortunately, both a critical eye and critical

action were not present in Argentina.

        Argentina saw the national budget deficit continually grow. As the government

tried to reel in its spending, the politics of pandering, particularly at the provincial level,

continued to contribute to a growing government debt. This debt continued to put

downward pressure on an Argentine peso that was already overvalued, and this would be

a precipitant of the crisis.

        Growth plummeted after 2000: GDP declined -.7% in 2000 which was followed

over the next two years by a further 15.3% decline in GDP. In 2003 the economy grew

                                               5
8.8%, mostly due to the fact it had already reached its floor.

        There are many factors to consider when assessing what happened to cause, both

in its creation and extent, the Argentine economic crisis, but only one reason it led to the

ruins of an “economic miracle”. Therefore, many hypotheses serve as attractive answers

to the question, but only one can account for deep-seated problems that cause economic

collapse--- that is political instability.

        The Argentine economic collapse was accompanied by social strain and social

unrest. The crisis serves to display what economic prescriptions are needed to avoid

doom, but it also serves as a reminder that economic collapse equates to social collapse.

Macroeconomic troubles are not confined to paper, but instead are a build up of

individual, human troubles.

        Just as economic troubles are representative of the individual struggles of people

in society, they are also symbolic of the struggles in the politics of a country. In the end,

an economy is only as stable as its government and political institutions. The economy

will not have more dexterity than the political institutions that regulate it; economic

growth will not outpace the growth of leadership, and although good politics may be able

to fix an irresponsible market, a market, responsible or not, can not fix the irresponsible

politics which created it.

                                     Literature Review

                                    Privatization Hypothesis

        The first, and most basic, explanation of the Argentine economic collapse points

to economic factors. This explanation posits that privatization and economic reforms in
                                               6
peripheral countries, such as Argentina, are bound to fail.   In the vein of dependency

theory, it claims that international financial institutions such as the IMF, governments of

the west (core countries), and multi-national companies, push privatization in an attempt

to advance their economic interests at the expense of developing countries.

       In this view Argentina is seen as an economic pawn that serves the interests of

more powerful interests. “The Rise and Collapse of Neoliberalism in Argentina: The Role

of Economic Groups”, by Miguel Teubal, criticizes the post-ISI liberalization policies

adopted by Argentina beginning in the mid-1970‟s for these very reasons.      Teubal

claims that economic liberalization created societal tension by eroding an old system in

which large business interests co-mingled with small and mid-sized businesses (Teubal,

174). Under the structural adjustment policy (SAP), adopted through the 1990's by

President Carlos Menem, large economic conglomerates, both national and transnational,

came to dominate the adjustment process. Therefore, the process favored large enterprise

and involved a tighter concentration of capital among them.

       In the late-1980‟s Argentina was facing hyperinflation in their currency.

Argentina‟s showdown with hyperinflation is seen by Teubal as the perfect environment

to introduce the currency board (181-185). Menem and Cavallo fixed the value of

Argentina‟s peso to the US dollar and the problem of inflation was solved. According

to Teubal, it also provided a solid footing to enhance the privatization processes by

"limiting... the central bank to... an exchange broker" and "eliminating all government

discretionality [over] monetary and foreign exchange policy." (Teubal, 181) Therefore,

as industry privatized, foreign interests would be attracted by a strong currency,

                                             7
prompting more international mobility for their capital earned in Argentina.

         As the process became enhanced, the welfare of the Argentine majority became

neglected. Without proper instruments to guard against capital flight and the

“[exclusion of] the institutionalization of efficient regulatory boards, which in the First

World are an essential part of most privatization programs”, the Argentine economy was

fundamentally flawed (Teubal, 181). Since the Argentinian peso was pegged 1:1 with the

dollar, it was a simple decision to exchange pesos into dollars, put those dollars in a

foreign account, and therefore cash-out at the overvalued rate opposed to the undervalued

rate that lied inevitably ahead. Large enterprise, both foreign and domestic, could do this

easily though their transnational financial service companies, while draining the money

supply of the Argentine nation and their banks. On the other hand, the Argentine people

were vulnerable to be hit the hardest from the crisis. Their only protection was a

government which had spent the last quarter of a century deconstructing itself (Teubal,

186-187).

       Teubal‟s analysis touches on many problems, such as how SAP left the people of

Argentina without a hope in the worst of times. He portrays the idea that the classes

which controlled capital used Argentina as a sponge for their debts, while acting as a

vacuum for capital produced within Argentina. The Argentine people were the most

effected and during this privatization process they saw their interests abandoned.

                                   Regional Hypothesis

       A developing international economy means more economic integration,

particularly at the regional level. In the Americas, regional economic integration

                                              8
highlights itself in the organization MERCOSUR and the trade pact NAFTA. The

former, MERCOSUR, is of concern. It is a South American trade association with four

full members, including Argentina and Brazil (Genna and Hiroi, 337).

       As mentioned prior, financial hardship faced many countries approaching the new

century, and Brazil‟s economy demanded policy adjustment to be saved. “The Effects of

Unequal Size: The Costs and Benefits of Unilateral Action in the Development of

MERCOSUR”, by Gaspare M. Genna and Taeko Hiroi, explains the role of Brazil as the

largest member of MERCOSUR, and the effect that this has upon smaller member states

of MERCOSUR.

       Genna and Hiroi, explaining the crisis through a liberal viewpoint, argue that

Brazil finds itself in a unique role in MERCOSUR as its largest and most wealthy

member. Due to their status, Brazil becomes the country that all of the other

MERCOSUR members will look to in times of crisis or despair. Brazil will be expected

absorb shocks and fix problems (Genna and Hiroi, 338).

       The authors contend that a study of Brazilian policy displays that their active

engagement in regional crises is necessary for smaller states to work through their crises.

If they act unilaterally, as they did when they faced a currency crisis in 1999, the smaller

neighboring economies can be directly affected due to their integrated position with

Brazil. As they note, “Much of the existing political economy literature on free trade and

regional integration argues that successful trade liberalization and economic integration

requires a regional preponderant power that acts as a core provider of collective goods for

member states.” (Genna and Hiroi, 338)

                                              9
Once Brazil was able to devalue their way through their crisis and return to its

feet, the Argentine economy was at its knees. Instead of focusing only on itself, Brazil‟s

policymakers were able to concern themselves with the current situation in Argentina,

which was about to devalue their peso. This time, Brazil actively pursued trade and credit

policies that would ease the burden on the Argentine economy. When President Duhalde

was ready to devalue the Argentine peso in 2002, he sought Brazilian assistance. The

communications between the countries resulted in lower tariffs for Argentine exporters,

while a reciprocal credit accord gave the central banks of Argentina and Brazil the right

and responsibility to exchange exporter‟s currency received for domestic currency. As

well, Brazil became a mouthpiece for Argentina on the international level, lobbying the

IMF, US government, the World Bank, and other important financial institutions to help

Argentina. (Genna and Hiroi, 347-349) In order to support their speech, “the Brazilian

National Bank of Economic and Social Development opened a line of credit for Brazilian

foreign direct investment in Argentina.” (Genna and Hiroi, 351)

       Genna and Hiroi study a key aspect of the Argentine Financial Crisis. Over the

last decade of the 20th Century, Argentina had become part of MERCOSUR. As the new

century neared, MERCOSUR remained a young institution in which member states

contracted in policies that attempted to evolve towards integration and coordination, but

were not yet there. The effects that Brazil‟s devaluation would have on Argentina‟s

economy were not considered because for Brazil, “their primary concern may not be on

the effect that their actions will have on regional partners but the effect on their domestic

constituencies.” (Genna and Hiroi, 338)

                                             10
Capital Relations Hypothesis

        David Woodruff„s study, “Boom, Gloom, Doom: Balance Sheets, Monetary

Fragmentation, and the Politics of Financial Crisis in Argentina and Russia”, offers an

alternative explanation to the Argentine financial crisis.   Woodruff sees the problem in

Argentina‟s economy lying directly with the fixed currency board and the capital

relations that built around it.

        First, Woodruff contends that currency boards have three phases. The first is

boom, or large economic growth. The second is gloom, or slowdown from such large

economic growth. The third, and final phase, is doom, or the collapse of the economic

growth which was heralded in the „boom‟ phase. (Woodruff, 4)

        As well, the study views capital from an “institutional-sociological” point of

view. This view allows for an explanation of the impact the currency board had on the

majority of capital interests (Woodruff, 6). This is combined with an analysis of business

interests and actions which define the purpose of business action and interests as relating

solely to the balance sheet of a business (Woodruff, 9-10).

        Woodruff maintains that when these two perspectives are used the Argentine

maintenance of the currency board, and therefore their economic collapse, can be

explained. Argentine banks and utility companies, the largest capital interests, mannered

their balance sheets to assume liabilities and assets in dollars. When the peso could no

longer keep up with the dollar, in terms of value, these businesses were so entrenched,

that they were better off “gambling for resurrection”, as opposed to disbanding the

currency board itself, which would have to be done in due time anyway. Woodruff terms

                                               11
these interests “go-for-brokers” whom will be willing to issue any number of “costly

signals” of their commitment to maintaining the peg, since these signals will in fact add

nothing to their costs in the event the peg fails” (Woodruff, 30)

       These “go-for-brokers”, representing a majority of the capital that created the

boom in Argentina, lost their chance to cut their losses (lobby for a repeal of the currency

board) in the gloom, and became willing to fight for their position until all the money

available from all sources had dried up, and the doom turned into an inevitable retraction

of the currency board. The other group that represented Argentine capital interests is the

“good fighters”. This group tried to cut their losses and support the currency board,

although they are not all-in, and become aware that devaluation may be the best option at

a certain point. Eventually, this group will reach the point where they maximize their

cover of dollar denominated asset liability. At this point, peso devaluation will help them

cover remaining liabilities more than maintaining convertibility (Woodruff, 31-32).

       Argentine provinces began issuing their own surrogate pesos which “by the end of

the year…had been issued to almost a quarter of the volume of pesos.” (Woodruff, 28) A

monetary surrogate is a form of capital that is not legally recognized. For example, in

Russia, Woodruff points out (24-25) that the electric companies used to accept metal

from metal companies to compensate for missed electric payments by the metal

companies. But surrogates appeared only in 2001 and in much more restricted form (I.e.,

no bartering) in Argentina (Woodruff, 27-28). They only served to speed up the

devaluation process so much as they were looked upon as actual notes that could service

payment in provinces.

                                             12
The lack of monetary surrogates, Woodruff argues, also points to the large

international interests in the Argentine economy. Utilities and financial interests derived

mobile capital from Argentina due to the 1:1 fixed ratio of the peso and the dollar. They

could not accept surrogates for a value that was fixed so high on their balance sheets

(Woodruff, 23-24).

       Woodruff leaves little to question about the phases of boom, doom, and gloom

involving the implementation and maintenance of currency boards. But, what if the

currency board is enacted and repealed in gloom times, before doom onsets? What if it is

repealed at the beginning of a crisis? Take the Brazilian case, for example.

       His analysis gives one possible answer to a puzzling question concerning the

Argentine financial crisis, which is why did the currency board remain intact so long?

He says that powerful capital interests viewed the currency board as essential to

maintaining their balance sheets.

                                    Political Hypothesis

       “The Role of Political Institutions in the Resolution of Economic Crises: The

Case of Argentina 2001–05”, by Andres Gallo, Juan Pablo Stegmann, and Jeffery W.

Steagall, frame Argentina‟s economic woes as a result of political instability. The

country, since hyperinflation that struck at the end of the 1980‟s, has been dominated by

corrupt political rule that is inefficient. Corruption and inefficiency can also be credited

to an unresolved federalism, which has led to a lack of coordination on economic issues

between Argentine provinces and the federal government. The study identifies that, “At

the root of Argentina‟s economic problems lies an irresolvable conflict between the

                                              13
nation‟s federal and provincial political powers.” (Gallo et al, 195)

       Beginning with President Menem, and his insistence on the creation of the

currency board and IMF-style development, political instability is indexed. Menem used

tactics such as manipulation of the Supreme Court, which led him to rule through

“executive decrees” and to undermine legitimate legal institutions. Menem‟s policies

advanced development, but a development built on a false foundation of political unity on

economic issues (Gallo et al, 196).

       The provincial authorities, at odds with Menem‟s reforms, undermined them with

rogue spending on enhancing budgets, and eventually with the production of monetary

surrogates, as Woodruff noted. But unlike Woodruff‟s hypothesis, which says that this

was due to an exhaustion of the benefits of the currency board, Gallo finds the cause of

this occurrence in the exhaustion of political outlets to form economic policy (Gallo et al,

198-201).

       When devaluation was finally on the brink the political in situation in Argentina

was at the height of its fracture. The country faced the difficult task of devaluation, and

had no mechanisms in place that could ensure a fair and efficient devaluation (Gallo et al

201-202). At this point the extent and impact of the poor political structures of Argentina

bared itself to the world and the Argentine nation.

       Policies that continued into the economic collapse were ill-fated due to their lost

nature and their inherent failure to actually deal with the problem. Instead, they dealt with

the political power‟s problems. The corralito on deposits harmed the depositor, as their

deposits fell victim to devaluation. A series of measures that attacked bondholders of

                                             14
Argentine debt, bank depositors, and banks themselves persisted due to the government‟s

drive to fix their own budget at the expense of private property rights (Gallo et al

201,208).

       The attempt to close the budget deficit was a political and self-interested

calculation done to remain in power and not to benefit the Argentine economy or

population. The government continues in this vein. Long-term resolutions to solve the

federal-provincial power and revenue sharing and revenue sharing problems, along with

banking reform, remain untouched due to the lack of political coordination. Successful

debt restructuring is also hindered by the retarded political system, and as long as this

continues, the Argentine people can expect to slowly pay off the first great economic

crash of the 21st Century (Gallo et al 208-210).

                                   Empirical Review

       Gallo‟s argument, the political hypothesis, explains many of the problems that the

other scholars mentioned have explored. It seems that: a) privatization is not the problem,

but the politics of Argentine privatization is; b) Brazilian unilateral action in the context

of MERCOSUR had an effect on Argentina, but it is nothing that could have not been

avoided by unilateral action of Argentina, and c) a small power bloc controlling exchange

rate policy, whether true or not, does not answer the main question, why is there a

concentrated power bloc controlling these decisions? The answer is an unstable political

system. Below I aim to detail a political system filled with corruption, incomplete

reforms, fragmentation, and incompetence, leaving no room in between for sound

economic policy and development. Also, keep in mind, politics is important because it
                                              15
creates economic structures. Today, these structures are more important than ever.

                               The Politics of Carlos Menem

       When Carlos Menem was elected into office he was faced with the political

nightmare of hyperinflation. As talked about before, he solved this problem by

implementing economic adjustment reforms based around the currency board. But, the

currency board and economic liberalization was not universally accepted in Argentina.

While some politicians and citizens supported the liberalization reforms, others were

against them and believed that solving the problem of hyperinflation required something

other than the currency board and liberalizing the economy.

       Moreover, Menem faced a Supreme Court that was hostile to his new economic

reforms. Therefore, Menem had to answer two evident questions to reform Argentina‟s

economy: 1) how can enough political support be garnered to pass economic reforms?,

and 2) how can these reforms be maintained through judicial support?      In essence,

Menem needed to devise a plan to suppress a majority of political representation and

tarnish Argentina‟s judicial integrity, or reverse a long history of legal precedent which

restricted liberal economic policies.

       First, concerning the issue of the judiciary, Menem saw his best option as

compromising judicial integrity. Menem, very early on, “packed” the Supreme Court

with loyal judges by expanding the court itself. Other government auditing and

prosecuting institutions were compromised by Menem‟s attempt to consolidate political

and legal power in support of his economic reforms (Blake, 7-8).

       The consequence of the forceful consolidation was that Argentina‟s economy was

                                             16
built on a legal system backed by a political machine. By 1995, Menem‟s reforms and

political style were falling out of favor and he was lacking credibility with the Argentine

population. 1995 also marked Menem‟s second term, which was only allowed after a

generous legal alteration to the electoral rules (Blake, 8). He won re-election and

continued to erode national confidence in democratic institutions. While he was

internationally praised, he was nationally disdained. His popularity in 1995 was nearly

equal to that of his predecessor, Raul Alfonsin, whom led the country during

hyperinflation (Blake, 17-18). Still, no one considered what would happen to the

economy when the only politician supporting the economic structure ceased being a

politician.

        Secondly, there is the issue of passing these reforms through the legislative

process. How did Menem do this? Well, he often did not. When he came into office he

was granted the utilitarian political tool of economic disaster. The country‟s dire

economic situation swayed Congress to grant Menem powers “equivalent to a blank

check, as Congress authorized the president to enact economic reforms through executive

orders.” (Blake, 7) Menem, the Peronist candidate, was also given the benefit of a

friendly Chamber of Deputies (congress) filled with other Peronist politicians, who found

their self in power, like Menem, due to the country‟s dire economic situation. Menem

leveraged his force with a poor economic situation, a competitive political unit in

Congress, and a compromising of the Argentine legal system. Charles H. Blake, in the

paragraph below, details Menem‟s political force in the early years:


     As a result, early privatization measures and other key reforms were implemented with minimal
                                                     17
congressional oversight. The legislature established the Comision Bicameral de la Reforma del Estado
 (CBRE), a congressional commission to monitor the privatization process. The CBRE could request that
  the executive branch justify its plans, but had no power to stop a sale. Interestingly enough, when the
 time came to vote for the State Reform Law, the Chamber of Deputies lacked the prescribed quorum. To
       bypass the problem, the Peronist leadership apparently brought into the voting session several
                    congressional employees, who voted in support of the measure. (7)

        Soon enough, Argentina‟s economic reform included a currency board. The

pegging of the Argentine peso to the US dollar finally eliminated inflation, but it came

with other consequences. The system propelled a rigid economy that took away the

possibility of nearly all monetary adjustments for the future. It also presents a more

attractive environment for foreign investment, as the currency‟s value becomes backed by

US dollars, and therefore comes with the security of the US dollar. Not to mention, the

peg was a political strength too--- the times of inflation were over. But, were the causes

of inflation really dealt with?


                               Sub-national Politics in Argentina

        The politics of Argentina‟s provinces and nature of Argentine federalism are

important in an analysis of the country in any topic or at any level.            In any federal

system the distribution of power and revenue are important, but in Argentina it is even

more important due to the important and dependent, but not harmonious, relationship

which defines the co-existence between the provincial and federal governments.

        There are 24 provinces in Argentina, containing 1,100 municipalities (Rezk,

2002). While they each have ample taxing powers, most taxation is done by the federal

government. This money is then distributed to each province based on population. This

tax arrangement is referred to as “co-participation” in Argentina (Edwards, 2002). In


                                                   18
2001 the provinces drew 52.7% of their revenues from this federal sharing program

(Rezk, 2002). In addition to a bulk of their revenue flowing from the federal to state

level, budget performance numbers flow the opposite way (Remmer and Wibbles, 430).

Therefore, a province, technically, never has a budget surplus or deficit, because this will

be reflected in the Argentine federal government budget.

       Also, party politics change at this level. Smaller parties, not involved in federal

politics, are important in politics at the provincial level. A handful of them can either oust

a national party, or in some provinces, the national party or provincial party may come to

solely dominate provincial politics (Remmer and Wibbels, 429).


         Sub-national Politics in the Context of National Economic Adjustment

       Although Menem first pushed his economic reforms, at some point fiscal and

administrative reform would be needed to ensure economic success. Argentina came into

the 1990‟s with a large budget deficit. Addressing the deficit was put on hold temporarily

by a restructuring of debt resulting in the issuances of Brady bonds to cover the country‟s

debt (Cavallo and Cottani, 18). But, reforming the country‟s fiscal prudence was essential

to economic success. A country which converts to a currency board can not have its

reserves threatened because the reserves are what back the currency (Blake, 8).

       Beating back the budget deficit was not something that could be dealt with

through economic adjustment on the national level. It involved policy changes that the

national government had to initiate and carry through. The provincial level is where the

spending takes place, as “the federal government has been collecting more than 80% of


                                              19
public revenues and retaining 55%”. The other 25%, or 5% of GDP, makes it ways into

provincial coffers (Remmer and Wibbels, 430).

       The “co-participation” law unevenly distributes money to provinces. The

distribution, despite being based on population, doesn‟t even out per capita. The result is

this: small provinces (ex. Santa Cruz), in terms of population, are left with a large amount

of revenue, while the larger (ex. Buenos Aires) provinces are given a small amount

revenue in account of its large population (Remmer and Wibbels, 435). As Karen

Remmer and Erik Wibbels point out (432), the situation of a large budget in a small

province facilitates political patronage networks.     “Public sector employment figures

reflect the divergence in national and provincial policies. After increasing approximately

25% between 1983 and 1990, the number of civil servants in the national public

administration was cut dramatically from 835,485 in 1990 to 190,414 in 1994. At the

provincial level, the trend was diametrically the opposite. After expanding 40% between

1983 and 1990, provincial public sector employment may be estimated to have increased

by an additional 77% between 1990 and 1995, a period marked by one of the most

intense stabilization efforts in Argentine history.”

       From 1984-1985 to 19952 provincial revenues grew, overall, at a rate of 67.6%,

while their expenditures grew at a rate of 71.2%. Revenues from co-participation and

their own taxes grew 130.1% and 82.4% respectively. Still, in this scenario only three

provinces, including Buenos Aires, kept their budgets out of the red by the end of 1995.

2
 The statistics following within the paragraph are all taken from Remmer and Wibbels,
Table 2: Revenues of the Argentine Province, 1984/1985-1995 (Constant 1995 US
Dollars), pg 431
                                              20
Combined, the provincial governments ran a deficit of $3,275,000,0003 pesos in 1995

alone. With “salaries [absorbing] roughly 60% of current revenues” (Remmer and

Wibbels, 436), the Argentine provinces used the co-participation fund as a civil servant

fund. Between 1991 and 1994, the provinces raised their payroll 41%, meanwhile, overall

spending spiked 38.9% between 1991 and 1995 (Remmer and Wibbels, 438-439).

Therefore, some of Miguel Teubal‟s grievances about the government‟s social

expenditures find a stronger link to patronage networks and corruption, opposed to

privatization.

          This is, again, important for several reasons. The point is that not only were the

provinces adding to a deficit, but they were doing it at the expense of the currency board.

Menem, with his political career tied to the boards success, did not attack the problems of

the provinces. He either supported the spending or was trying to win political favor, as

displayed when ,“Under the auspices of [the] stabilization program, these

[co-participation] arrangements were renegotiated in 1992 and 1993, when the number

and percentage of taxes subject to co-participation were lowered in exchange for federal

agreement to a minimal contribution of 8.9 million pesos, which represented a 50%

increase over the amount received by the provinces in 1990.” (Remmer and Wibbels,

430)

          The problem of the provinces was not solely shown in the budget deficit. The

effect it had upon the budget deficit caused a reaction. The Argentine national

government compensated for overspending with under spending. “The success of

3
    Table 3: Provincial Operating Balances, 1991-1995 (millions of pesos), pg 438,
                                               21
Argentine adjustment effort of the early 1990s was thus achieved through policies of

over-adjustment at the national level that compensated for public sector expansion and

financial fragilities at the provincial level”(Remmer and Wibbels, 432), meaning the

government continued in its privatization efforts, without funding it with proper

regulation and oversight. On the eve of Menem‟s departure in 1999 Peter Hudson (1999)

wrote “a reduction in local costs will demand that Menem‟s successor pays urgent

attention to tasks left undone: a major restructuring of the tax system to stamp out

evasion, lowering of taxes on employment, a reduction in public-utilities tariffs, and a

reorganization of inefficient government spending.” (180)


            Economics as Politics and Vice Versa: Maintaining ‘The Peg’

       So far some of the problems with the currency board have been explored.         In this

section, I will talk about them more, but first, here‟s a list of the problems the currency

board causes:


            1) Low exports due to the relative high price of manufacturing
         2) High percentage of import consumption due to monetary strength
              3) The currency board can not manage high budget deficits
  4) Small domestic manufacturing sector (see (1)), low real wages due to high monetary
                  value, and high unemployment for the same reason.


       The currency board is a reasonable tool, in the sense in can begin to ignite

investor confidence by securing a currency and it can remove a population from the perils

of inflation. But, an environment like the one described above does not facilitate the



Remmer and Wibbels (2000)
                                              22
currency board as a permanent feature. Much of the literature on Argentina‟s economic

reforms refers to Menem and Cavallo‟s reforms as „shock therapy‟. This term itself points

to the temporality and care which these reforms necessitate.

         The problem is that Menem and Cavallo found themselves and their reputations,

for the former nationally and the latter internationally, on the line with the success of the

currency board. They hailed it as the be-all-end-all of economic reforms. Not even the

IMF encouraged and supported these reforms (Cavallo and Cottani, 19). Matter of fact,

they discouraged these reforms. Cavallo lived up to his reputation as a bellicose public

figure with a brazen attack on the IMF and floating exchange rates in his paper

“Argentina‟s Convertibility Plan and the IMF”, written with Joaquin A. Cottani, and

presented at the Hundred and Fourth Annual Meeting of the American Economic

Association in 1997.

         Cavallo‟s conclusions about the currency board are questionable and almost

delusional. He emphasizes the need for consistent, rule-based economic policy. This of

course, is provided by the currency board. On the other hand, discretionary, or floating

currency value, is portrayed as a political tool (Cavallo and Cottani, 19-20).

         He goes on to speak of reform by a “democratic government, with no

extraordinary foreign assistance.” This reform, backed by the currency board, is

responsible for “improvements in technology and management” at the microeconomic

level.   The former claim is misleading and the latter claim, even if true, does not speak

to the fact that these improvements were all for naught. What Cavallo forgets to mention

is that the “improvements in technology and management” manifest themselves as debt in
                                              23
a failing economy. Exports remained dismally below the levels of the region (See (1)

above) and “the supply-side shocks” were not enough to offset import consumption with

domestic consumption.

         As Cavallo continues to read from his personal economic history book the words

become more surreal. He speaks of “Argentina‟s outstanding use of IMF credit” which

goes against much of the conclusions in the literature on the issue. Many people tend to

point to the IMF as lending and advising in a manner that caused Argentina‟s downfall.

According to Domingo Cavallo the IMF was certainly in conflict with Argentina, but not

as the consensus believes.

         “Nevertheless, differences of opinion have existed in matters of economic policy

between the Argentine authorities and the IMF staff since the beginning of the

Convertibility Plan”, he says, “the IMF never believed in the currency board as a

long-term arrangement.” He also reveals that many of the tax cuts initiated in Argentina

were not supported by the IMF and they were blatantly discouraged (Cavallo and Cottani,

19).

         David Woodruff‟s paradigm of “go-for-brokers”, “unwinders“, and “good

fighters” seems correct, but not in his context. The political players in Argentina were

looking at their balance sheets. The political balance sheet is denominated in something

far more intangible than dollars and can not explain how society shapes around economic

policy, but instead how politics shapes around economic policy.


       The Election of 1999 and the Revolving Presidency: Inheriting A Political and
                                  Economic Nightmare
                                             24
The election of 1999 marked the end of Carlos Menem‟s reign as President. There

was talk of him, that March, attempting to run for a third time. This would be done

through bypassing electoral law through a popular referendum. The previous July, of

1998, saw Menem announce that he would not seek to maneuver his way into a third

term, but something seemed to spark a change of heart. The fickle Menem, in July of

1999, explicitly dropped his bid for a third term, most likely resulting from party pressure

and the possible embarrassment of being beaten by Eduardo Duhalde in the Peronist‟s

run-off elections.

       The election of 1999 also marked the beginning of the end for Argentina‟s

“economic miracle”. The ensuing three years would see three presidents, in addition to

one “provisional president for 48 hours”. These three years saw: additional loans from the

international community; an initial run of the banks; the re-introduction of Domingo

Cavallo as Minister of the Economy; the issuance of “provincial bonds…to pay public

salaries”; various debt swaps; a debt moratorium; a final run on the banks leading to

devaluation; rising unemployment, and social unrest (Hornbeck, 2002). As capital fled

the country and provincial bonds were used to service salaries the inevitable devaluation

and its economic and social consequences continued to deteriorate.

       As spoken of before, devaluation is a process that should have occurred sometime

near the beginning of Menem‟s second term, before overvaluation of the peso was locked

in and problematic. The campaign of 1999 was not a pretty one as well and added to the

burden on the Argentine economy. Eduardo Duhalde and Fernando De La Rua provided


                                             25
populist rhetoric and economic evaluations which hurt investor confidence. Cavallo

railed each of the candidates for their behavior on the campaign trail, in his typically

blunt fashion. Still, despite the two candidate perceived disagreement with the policies of

the 1990‟s, the winner, Fernando De La Rua, maintained these same policies. When they

proved especially difficult to manage, De La Rua turned to Cavallo himself to fix the

economy (Makuc, 73).

       The disaster of maintaining a pegged currency in Russia was available as

evidence, while Brazil at this time was going through a devaluation process of there own.

Why then, was there such faith in the currency board in Argentina? Even more, why from

an administration that ran a campaign presenting policies opposed to the currency board?

One reason, as discussed prior, is that the strength of the political benefit of enacting the

currency board in Argentina would have produced the exact opposite political effect with

equal strength when the currency board was retracted. The economic institutions,

political institutions, and legal institutions were all built around the currency board and

loyalty to Carlos Menem. Although the following thought is not supported by empirical

facts, it doesn‟t seem presumptuous to assume Argentina may not have possessed the

human capital to devalue. In the end, the populist rhetoric in the 1999 campaign was

political pandering and served no other purpose than to hurt everyone‟s confidence in the

system.

       The patience of the citizens is also in question concerning devaluation. President

de la Rua, or none of his successors, had the political clout to devalue. Adrian Makuc,

national director of foreign trade policy in Argentina beginning in 1998, said in 2002,

                                              26
while still in his official position: “Politicians are not credible in Argentina. When

somebody comes to the podium and talks as a politician in Argentina, nobody believes

him.” (Makuc, 73) By the time Duhalde devalued in 2002, there was little chance there

wouldn‟t be social unrest.    The social unrest was justified by the plight of the Argentine

population, but, although it could never be measured exactly, the Argentine people‟s

history of protest in the face of fiscal reform made devaluing an unattractive option in

2002 and prior. Still, in no way do I mean to indict the people of Argentina, because

politicians are supposed to be leaders, and therefore devaluation should have been

worked out in the face unpopular sentiment.

        The Argentine population‟s short patience for tough reforms is not only justified

by their economic realities, but also by the trust issue introduced by Makuc. Distrust of

Argentine politicians is quite reasonable in reference to history and the present. Carlos

Menem‟s regime became known for corruption which the politician was able to brush off

despite the fact the corruption did exist. Despite the “official” ability to survive, in reality

it tarnished his reputation and planted the seeds of distrust in society (Blake, 8).

Secondly, De La Rua followed by continuing to provide a safe haven for corruption. The

situation was so bad that his Vice President Carlos Alvarez resigned due to De La Rua‟s

inability and inaction in weeding out corruption from the government (Hornbeck,

CRS-3).

        Finally, to portray how bad the economic situation was concerning politics, look

at the events of power succession following de la Rua‟s resignation according to a

Congressional Report (Hornbeck 2002):

                                               27
December 20: President de la Rua resigns in the wake of continued rioting...
December 21: …Senate President Ramon Puerta is named provisional president for 48 hours
December 23: Congress appoints San Luis Governor Adolfo Rodriguez Saa as interim president until
elections in March 2002.
December 30: President Rodriguez Saa resigns after continued rioting…Senate leader Puerta resigns to
avoid second appointment as interim president… (CRS-4)

Essentially, no politician wanted to get their hands dirty with this devaluation. After less

than a week in presidency Rodriguez Saa, from his house in San Luis province, away

from the capital, gave an unsympathetic resignation to the Argentine people (Makuc,

2002):


         “…„Well, I‟m resigning.‟ He said „I am giving here to the armed forces officer that is with me, my
                 letter of resignation to take to the national capital.‟ That was original.
          He went there, secluded himself in his province like a big landlord and just told the thirty-seven
                     million Argentinians, „You can do whatever you want.‟ ” (74)

         Less than a week later Eduardo Duhalde, leader of the new Peronist party

(Menem‟s coalition representing the old Peronist bloc), officially ended the currency

board on January 6, 2002, after being appointed President (Hornbeck, CRS-5). At this

point the economy, society, the banking system, and practically all major areas of

Argentine life were dealt the long overdue, and therefore powerful, blow of devaluation.

This was the economic „shock therapy‟ that Domingo Cavallo could be proud of.

         Duhalde‟s devaluation made every US $1 equal to 1.4 pesos concerning loans.

Concerning deposits, there was an even 1:1 swap from what was a US dollar to the now

properly, and extremely low, valued peso. This made matters worse by hurting

confidence in the banking system and hurt depositors as well (Gallo et al 201,208).

Overall, Duhalde‟s policies weren‟t received well in “Menem‟s Court”, so at the expense

of legal integrity, again, the court was unpacked and re-packed to push through

                                                    28
Duhalde‟s reform. The new Peronist political machine has followed Duhalde‟s

presidency with the chosen successor Nestor Kirchner and in the name of democracy

Kirchner‟s wife, Cristina Elisabet Fernández Wilhem de Kirchner, followed in line and is

currently serving as President.


  Banking and Monetary Policy in the 21st Century: Brazil and Argentina Compared

       Argentina‟s banking system is the final issue in the analysis of the crisis.

Argentina had no foundation for banking law, including a lack of policy concerning

insolvent banks. As evidenced by a 2003 Economist article, Argentina, one year after

devaluation, had yet to sort out the problems within their banking system.    Again,

dealing with banks would open up political vulnerabilities. Despite the generally

optimistic Economist article, it ends on the same note that this paper is based upon: “Mr.

Duhalde will indeed leave Argentina in a much better state than he found it--but he is also

bequeathing many unpopular decisions to his successor.” (Economist, 2003)

       Social unrest in Argentina began in 2001 when the first hold on bank deposits

took place. The following corralito of 2002 worsened the social upheaval. This need

for freezing bank withdrawals and the uneven devaluation also highlighted the lack of

rules, regulations, and structure in the banking system and economy as a whole.       It also

displayed the lack of regulation and planning to monitor banks and their operating

abilities. Therefore, weather the devaluation ended up favoring depositors or borrowers

was arbitrary without the guidance of law. The government, being a prolific borrower,

constructed a devaluation policy favoring borrowers.     In reality each side should have


                                             29
sacrificed in a fair devaluation.

        In 1999 John W. Head thought that the East Asian Financial Crisis would teach

countries and supranational organizations lessons about banking standards in the

international economy, which would be “the silver lining to the dark cloud of the Asian

financial crisis.”   In the case of Argentina, he was wrong.     Head‟s other “silver linings”

was the crisis‟s ability to display the need for central bank independence and policies that

would thwart disruptive capital flows (for example, Chile heavily taxes short-term

inflow) (Head, 951-954).      Again, this information did not seem to make it to Argentine

policy makers.

        Argentina‟s devaluation policy was indiscriminate to banks which may still be

solvent and those which were insolvent.     Head advocated the adoption of international

banking standard and encouraged central banks, commercial banks, and governments to

join in to restructure domestic banking law. This included a tough policy for insolvent

banks which in some countries, including Argentina, are allowed to stay open and “bleed

[depositors] dry of all the…money.” (Head, 953)

        When trouble started to appear in Argentina the political situation was so bad that

banks had no one to work with on creating a law.        Like the previous years, no one was

working on laws or any other sort of policies to maintain the economy.        Argentina‟s

“leaders” were to busy riding the political carousel.     In most part, the lack of regulation

and structure in banking and capital markets can be attributed to Menem‟s continual

neglect to create policies that complemented the currency board, or liberalization in

general.   On the other hand, when economic fortunes were grim in Brazil their

                                             30
politicians reacted to the possibility of devaluation.

       The Genna and Hiroi article talked about Brazil‟s devaluation of the real, and its

effect upon Argentina. This was not the only thing Brazil did though, and it would be

unwise to think that simple devaluation will be followed by an economic upturn. Brazil,

like Argentina, consists of many provinces (26) and municipalities (5,500). The Brazilian

budget is also at the mercy of the provincial budgets, as they show up as one statistic as

in Argentina (de Albuquerque, 165, Guira, 486).

       On top of Brazil‟s devaluation they increased taxes, cut spending, and drastically

reformed the country‟s tax code and civil servant system (de Albuquerque, 2000, Guira,

2001). Pretty much, everything that post-East Asian Financial Crisis literature was

advocating, Brazil was initiating. Brazil, while addressing these issues, also provided “the

political will to educate their citizentry on the need to absorb short-term pain to ensure

long-term gain.” (Guira, 492) Hand-in-hand with the IMF, Brazil went through

devaluation. The IMF‟s cooperation and assistance was buoyed by an already existing

cooperative arrangement to clean up Brazil‟s banking law. Before devaluation Brazil took

part in adopting the Basle Twenty-Five Principles for Effective Banking, along with

preparation to start selling state-owned banks (Guira, 504).

       In short, it seems Brazil was preparing to devalue, and their need to devalue

appeared a little earlier than expected, but the reforms were underway already. They

were building the economic structures that the 21st Century international economy

demanded. That means political in-roads had been developed, and therefore Brazil held

the country in harmony through some very tough reforms. Brazil‟s system favored action

                                              31
to bail out the economy, while Argentina‟s lack of a banking system favored action to bail

out the government.    For example, the nearly 12 billion dollars in loans and commercial

bank debt attributed to the Argentine government looks a lot better divided by 1.4.

       Banking reform also tackles the “moral hazard” question (Head, 962-963). If a

bank is aware of the conditions that it becomes liquidated, restructured, or propped under,

it no doubt effects their actions. Argentina is a tricky situation because it seems the lack

of banking law led “moral hazard” to favor the government (insolvent banks benefited as

well), but usually it is the other way around. In the end, the lack of banking law is bad for

its effects in deteriorating investors‟ confidence, and immoral characters (abound in both

developed and developing countries) can maneuver their way to the beneficial side of

“moral hazard” if the rules are not defined. Governments must define the terms and

therefore eliminate uncertainty and “moral hazard” altogether.

       The fates of Brazil and Argentina seem to diverge somewhere in the mid-1990‟s.

Brazil‟s attitude was something along the lines of: If we have to devalue, we have to

devalue. To mediate the costs adjustments must take place. Therefore, devaluation will

still be able to retain capital inflows due to the fact the system is sound and fair.

       Argentina simply took the attitude: If we have to devalue, something went

horribly wrong, so we won‟t have to devalue. Adjustments were never in mind. Domingo

Cavallo and the Argentine political elite thought the currency board, unregulated markets,

the promise of capital mobility, and making statements to keep investor confidence was

the key to maintaining capital inflows. In their context, devaluation was not a possibility.

The impossibility was not an economic reality, it was a political reality. Judging from

                                              32
Cavallo‟s paper, by the time the international community was adjusting its previous

beliefs, Argentina was cementing its faith in the old model. It truly became Argentina

against the international community. While Brazil‟s leadership was working with the

IMF Argentina‟s leadership was bickering with it--- worst of all, in a public economic

forum.


 Concluding on the Collapse and Its Implications for Development in the 21st Century

         What are the lessons from Argentina? It‟s time for everyone to withdraw from

their comfortable positions in economic philosophies. Development theorists all across

the spectrum will only continue to spur rigid and inefficient environments that will lead

to economic disaster. It‟s a wake up call to populations, politicians, bankers, and all

policy makers alike: You‟re not creating policy and indexing its „soundness‟ to outdated

philosophies. The rules of capital are the index of proper and improper economic policy.

In the international economy, to think that the rules of capital are stagnant, and that

numbers that meant one thing 20 years ago (or even 5) will symbolize the same thing in

the present is foolish, outdated, and a recipe for economic collapse. It is about structures

over everything else. Structures have transcended philosophy on its way becoming

capital„s main attraction. Again, where capital once looked for a home with an

environment built on a philosophy, it now searches for a home with an environment built

on structures. As Argentina showed, an economy built on philosophy has no safety, while

an economy built on structure can only far as fall as its structures allow it.

         But, this is not the sole purpose of this paper. The purpose of this paper, then,


                                              33
was to display this idea through Argentina‟s Economic Collapse. The proper economic

structures are created by political structures and development will only fail without

political harmony, responsibility, and function. Political harmony should not be taken as

political hegemony. It means politicians are trusted by the people, to the point that

political factions are beneficial in creating policy, not detrimental. By responsibility it is

meant that economic policy is not a political tool.    Carlos Menem compromised the

basic foundations of the Argentine state in order to hold power for 10 years. This is an

attitude that ran through Argentina‟s political system in the 1990‟s. Menem‟s style

(political irresponsibility) was caused by a lack of alliances between Menem and other

political parties and the people (political disharmony). The confluence of these two

factors is a recipe for political dysfunction. It is a paradigm that defines the Argentine

Economic Crisis: Liberalization was irresponsible, because without harmony, the

necessary reforms to accompany it were not going to come due to political dysfunction.

This only added rigidity to the economy.

       Rigid systems produce rigid results. Hence, Argentina experienced the polarizing

effects of meteoric economic boom and depressing economic collapse. If they created the

flexible safety net (like Brazil) to brace the fall of the boom then the consequences of

devaluation and recession would not have been as horrific. In reality, these reforms were

impossible in Argentina though. A politician is as good as his first step it seems, or at

least the political environment has constructed a pathos in which politicians feel better

hedged by “going for broke” then trying to explain the necessity of short-term sacrifice

and conflicting reforms.    The power structure, from the federal to provincial level,

                                              34
illustrates this. The fracture of government structure and patronage within each level of

power means that someone will always scratch the populations‟ itch at the expense of

stable and long lasting reform.

       The crisis also begs investors to be responsible, in the sense that they need to pay

attention to politics. Not until the election of 1999 did investor confidence really start to

plummet. In hindsight, this economy never stood a chance in the political environment.

To flood an economy with investment and then remove your investment due to factors

that analysis could have foreseen is immoral and irresponsible.

       The market is beginning to react to this problem. The Eurasia Group, one of the

most successful political risk consulting groups in the world, saw its profits rise $7

million dollars from 2001 to 2002. In May of 2003, they were projecting a possible 100%

increase in profits from 2002, which would leave them with $30 million by the end of

2003 if predicted correctly. A 2000 Business Week article touted the group‟s growth to

15 full-time employees. There are currently more than 15 people on the advisory board

and as of May 2003 there were 520 employees affiliated in Eurasia Group‟s network. Not

to mention the company has been expanding through mergers and acquisitions of smaller

political risk consulting companies.

       The results of investing in a political structure, along with an economic structure

are yet to be revealed. But the facts point towards 21st Century capital decisions as being

something more than an economic decision, but a political decision as well. The

international economy has tied these two factors closer together than ever before. When

economic calculations become political calculations then the politics of instability take

                                              35
root, and Argentina showed the devastation that could occur when politics dominates the

union of these two spheres.




                                           36
Works Cited

Barraclough, Colin. (2002, August 19). “That Sinking Feeling”. Newsweek Atlantic
Edition 28-30. Retrieved from LexisNexis.

Blake, Charles H. (1998) “Economic Reform and Democratization in Argentina and
Uruguay: The Tortoise and the Hare Revisited?”. Journal of Interamerican Studies and
World Affairs, Vol. 40, No. 3 1-26.

Cavallo, Domingo F. and Cottani, Joaquin A. (1997). “Argentina‟s Convertibility Plan
and the IMF”. The American Economic Review, Vol. 87, No.2, 17-22

Corrales, Javier. (2002) “The Politics of Argentina‟s Meltdown” World Policy Journal,
Vol. XIX, No.3, Fall 2002 Retrieved from:
http://www.worldpolicy.org/journal/articles/wpj02-3/corrales.html

De Albuquerque, Roberto Chacon (2000) “Legal Responses to the Fiscal Crisis in
Brazil”. St. Louis-Warsaw Transatlantic Law Journal, St. Louis University School of
Law. 163-173

The Economist (2002, August 10). “Argentina‟s Bottomless Pit”. Retrieved from
LexisNexis

The Economist (2003, April 5). “Poised for Growth”. Retrieved from LexisNexis

The Economist (2003, May 22). “The new Bull-Market”. Retrieved from LexisNexis

Edwards, Sebastian. (2002) “The Argentine Debt Crisis of 2001-2002: A Chronology
of Some Key Policy Issues”. Retrieved from
http://www.anderson.ucla.edu/faculty/sebastian. edwards/Chronology.pdf

Faiola, Anthony. (1998, 22 July) “Argentine President Drops Plan to Run Again”
Washington Post A26. Retrieved from LexisNexis

Gallo, Andres, Stegmann, Juan Pablo, and Steagall, Jeffery W. (2006). “The Role of
Political Institutions in the Resolution of Economic Crises: The Case of Argentina
2001–05”, Oxford Development Studies, Vol. 34, No.2, June 2006. 193-214.

Genna, Gaspare M. and Hiroi, Taeko (2005). “The Effects of Unequal Size: The Costs
and Benefits of Unilateral Action in the Development of MERCOSUR”, Journal of
Developing Societies, Vol. 21, 337-355


                                           37
Guira, Jorge M. (2001). “Preventing and Containing International Financial Crisis:   The
Case of Brazil”. Law and Business Review of the Americas, Fall 2001, 481-506

Head, John W. (1999). “The Global Implications of the Asian Financial Crisis:
Banking, Economic Integration, and Crisis Management in the New Century”. William
Mitchell Law Review, Vol. 25, 939-963

Hornbeck, J.F. (2002, January 31). “The Argentine Financial Crisis:   A Chronology of
Events”. Congressional Research Service Report for Congress.

Hudson, Peter (1999). “Menem‟s Argentina: An Economic Miracle or Quick Fix?”. The
Washington Quarterly, Autumn 1999, 175-180

Hudson, Peter and Margolis, Mac. (2001, July 23) “Argentina‟s Pain”. Newsweek. 24-27
Retrieved from LexisNexis

Latin Finance. (2002, November) “Frontnotes”, 6. Retrieved from LexisNexis

Lloyd’s List. (2001, July 5). “Argentina reaches breaking point”. 7-9. Retrieved from
LexisNexis.

Makuc, Adrian Jorge. (2002). “Argentina‟s Efforts at Financial Recovery and Impacts of
the Crisis on MERCOSUR and FTAA Talks”. Florida Journal of International Law, Fall
2002, Vol.15, 69-79

Rezk, Ernesto. (2002, April 10) “Fiscal Federalism in Argentina” Retrieved from
http://www.forumfed.org/en/libdocs/FedMerco02/116-FEME0206-ar-Rezk.pdf

Rezk, Ernesto. (2000, November 21) “Federalism and Decentralization Under
Convertibility: Lessons from the Argentine Experience”. Retrieved from
http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/seminar/2000/fiscal/rezk.pdf

Salmon, Felix (2003, March) “An Uneasy Recovery”. Euromoney. Retrieved from
LexisNexis.

Taylor, Robert. (1998, June 1) “Argentina: Sounds Like a Slowdown: Argentina‟s
explosive economy survived the Asian Financial Crisis, but there are signs that the
worrying rates of growth has begun to slow”. The Banker, Vol. 148, No. 868. Retrieved
from LexisNexis

Teubal, Miguel (2004). “The Rise and Collapse of Neoliberalism in Argentina: The Role
of Economic Groups”, Journal of Developing Societies, Vol. 20. 173-188


                                           38
Woodruff, David (2005). “Boom, Gloom, Doom: Balance Sheets, Monetary
Fragmentation, and the Politics of Financial Crisis in Argentina and Russia”, Politics &
Society, Vol. 33 3-45




                                            39

Contenu connexe

Tendances

Institutions shocks growth_june ukraine_final
Institutions shocks growth_june ukraine_finalInstitutions shocks growth_june ukraine_final
Institutions shocks growth_june ukraine_finalindrih
 
October 2011 - Recycling: Who pays for it?
October 2011 - Recycling: Who pays for it?October 2011 - Recycling: Who pays for it?
October 2011 - Recycling: Who pays for it?FGV Brazil
 
In defense of rational economic planning
In defense of rational economic planningIn defense of rational economic planning
In defense of rational economic planningFernando Alcoforado
 
Amph 0410 2
Amph 0410 2Amph 0410 2
Amph 0410 2boylanj
 
Social essay 2
Social essay 2Social essay 2
Social essay 2LoganShaw
 
Development thinking
Development thinkingDevelopment thinking
Development thinkingSoe Myint Swe
 
The Tequila Crisis
The Tequila CrisisThe Tequila Crisis
The Tequila CrisisStacey Troup
 
Zimbabwe monetary policy
Zimbabwe monetary policyZimbabwe monetary policy
Zimbabwe monetary policySABC News
 
Argentina Paper Final Paper PDF
Argentina Paper Final Paper PDFArgentina Paper Final Paper PDF
Argentina Paper Final Paper PDFCody Etlin
 
The Brazilian Economy - Recycling: Who pays for it? - october 2011
The Brazilian Economy - Recycling: Who pays for it? - october 2011The Brazilian Economy - Recycling: Who pays for it? - october 2011
The Brazilian Economy - Recycling: Who pays for it? - october 2011Wigliani Notícias
 
Economic Growth and Inequality: The New Post-Washington Consensus, September ...
Economic Growth and Inequality: The New Post-Washington Consensus, September ...Economic Growth and Inequality: The New Post-Washington Consensus, September ...
Economic Growth and Inequality: The New Post-Washington Consensus, September ...Africa Cheetah Run
 
La Historia Del Consenso De Washington Por John Williamson
La Historia Del Consenso De Washington Por John  WilliamsonLa Historia Del Consenso De Washington Por John  Williamson
La Historia Del Consenso De Washington Por John Williamsonneiracar
 
Position paper economics
Position paper economicsPosition paper economics
Position paper economicsKimRodney
 
The U.S Government Involvement in the Economy
The U.S Government Involvement in the EconomyThe U.S Government Involvement in the Economy
The U.S Government Involvement in the EconomyJerome Torossian
 
Masters Dissertation
Masters DissertationMasters Dissertation
Masters DissertationROBERTO BENTO
 
Empirical Analysis of Fiscal Dominance and the Conduct of Monetary Policy in ...
Empirical Analysis of Fiscal Dominance and the Conduct of Monetary Policy in ...Empirical Analysis of Fiscal Dominance and the Conduct of Monetary Policy in ...
Empirical Analysis of Fiscal Dominance and the Conduct of Monetary Policy in ...AJHSSR Journal
 

Tendances (20)

Institutions shocks growth_june ukraine_final
Institutions shocks growth_june ukraine_finalInstitutions shocks growth_june ukraine_final
Institutions shocks growth_june ukraine_final
 
October 2011 - Recycling: Who pays for it?
October 2011 - Recycling: Who pays for it?October 2011 - Recycling: Who pays for it?
October 2011 - Recycling: Who pays for it?
 
In defense of rational economic planning
In defense of rational economic planningIn defense of rational economic planning
In defense of rational economic planning
 
The power of macroeconomics part 1
The power of macroeconomics  part 1The power of macroeconomics  part 1
The power of macroeconomics part 1
 
C Rises And Newzealand Economy
C Rises And Newzealand EconomyC Rises And Newzealand Economy
C Rises And Newzealand Economy
 
D Angelo Final Paper
D Angelo Final PaperD Angelo Final Paper
D Angelo Final Paper
 
Amph 0410 2
Amph 0410 2Amph 0410 2
Amph 0410 2
 
Social essay 2
Social essay 2Social essay 2
Social essay 2
 
Development thinking
Development thinkingDevelopment thinking
Development thinking
 
The Tequila Crisis
The Tequila CrisisThe Tequila Crisis
The Tequila Crisis
 
Zimbabwe monetary policy
Zimbabwe monetary policyZimbabwe monetary policy
Zimbabwe monetary policy
 
Argentina Paper Final Paper PDF
Argentina Paper Final Paper PDFArgentina Paper Final Paper PDF
Argentina Paper Final Paper PDF
 
FDC Bi-Monthly Economic and Business Update. October 26, 2016
FDC Bi-Monthly Economic and Business Update. October 26, 2016FDC Bi-Monthly Economic and Business Update. October 26, 2016
FDC Bi-Monthly Economic and Business Update. October 26, 2016
 
The Brazilian Economy - Recycling: Who pays for it? - october 2011
The Brazilian Economy - Recycling: Who pays for it? - october 2011The Brazilian Economy - Recycling: Who pays for it? - october 2011
The Brazilian Economy - Recycling: Who pays for it? - october 2011
 
Economic Growth and Inequality: The New Post-Washington Consensus, September ...
Economic Growth and Inequality: The New Post-Washington Consensus, September ...Economic Growth and Inequality: The New Post-Washington Consensus, September ...
Economic Growth and Inequality: The New Post-Washington Consensus, September ...
 
La Historia Del Consenso De Washington Por John Williamson
La Historia Del Consenso De Washington Por John  WilliamsonLa Historia Del Consenso De Washington Por John  Williamson
La Historia Del Consenso De Washington Por John Williamson
 
Position paper economics
Position paper economicsPosition paper economics
Position paper economics
 
The U.S Government Involvement in the Economy
The U.S Government Involvement in the EconomyThe U.S Government Involvement in the Economy
The U.S Government Involvement in the Economy
 
Masters Dissertation
Masters DissertationMasters Dissertation
Masters Dissertation
 
Empirical Analysis of Fiscal Dominance and the Conduct of Monetary Policy in ...
Empirical Analysis of Fiscal Dominance and the Conduct of Monetary Policy in ...Empirical Analysis of Fiscal Dominance and the Conduct of Monetary Policy in ...
Empirical Analysis of Fiscal Dominance and the Conduct of Monetary Policy in ...
 

Similaire à The Politics of Economic Instability in the 21st Century: Argentina and the Dissipation of an Economic Miracle

Macro project argentina crisis
Macro project  argentina crisisMacro project  argentina crisis
Macro project argentina crisisSwati Lal
 
Argentine​ ​Economic​ ​Crisis​ ​1998-2002 Abstract .docx
Argentine​ ​Economic​ ​Crisis​ ​1998-2002 Abstract .docxArgentine​ ​Economic​ ​Crisis​ ​1998-2002 Abstract .docx
Argentine​ ​Economic​ ​Crisis​ ​1998-2002 Abstract .docxjustine1simpson78276
 
AnsA) When financial markets stood on the verge of collapse in th.pdf
AnsA) When financial markets stood on the verge of collapse in th.pdfAnsA) When financial markets stood on the verge of collapse in th.pdf
AnsA) When financial markets stood on the verge of collapse in th.pdfsutharbharat59
 
Revista de Economia Política 30 (1), 2010 3The 2008 finan.docx
Revista de Economia Política  30 (1), 2010 3The 2008 finan.docxRevista de Economia Política  30 (1), 2010 3The 2008 finan.docx
Revista de Economia Política 30 (1), 2010 3The 2008 finan.docxronak56
 
Economic Development Paper
Economic Development PaperEconomic Development Paper
Economic Development PaperSaumya Sudhir
 
World economy towards the depression in 2015
World economy towards the depression in 2015World economy towards the depression in 2015
World economy towards the depression in 2015Fernando Alcoforado
 
Research Paper on the Economic Impact of the Catolonia Crisis
Research Paper on the Economic Impact of the Catolonia CrisisResearch Paper on the Economic Impact of the Catolonia Crisis
Research Paper on the Economic Impact of the Catolonia CrisisMadlin Deignan
 
The collapse of neoliberal globalization
The collapse of neoliberal globalizationThe collapse of neoliberal globalization
The collapse of neoliberal globalizationFernando Alcoforado
 
Political economy of asian financial crisis
Political economy of asian financial crisisPolitical economy of asian financial crisis
Political economy of asian financial crisisguitarefolle
 
Pincus, J.; Ramli, R. (1998). Indonesia from showcase to basket case. Cambrid...
Pincus, J.; Ramli, R. (1998). Indonesia from showcase to basket case. Cambrid...Pincus, J.; Ramli, R. (1998). Indonesia from showcase to basket case. Cambrid...
Pincus, J.; Ramli, R. (1998). Indonesia from showcase to basket case. Cambrid...hamdinur2
 
Global recession towards world economic depression
Global recession towards world economic depressionGlobal recession towards world economic depression
Global recession towards world economic depressionFernando Alcoforado
 
LA Seminar - Argentina Debt Crises - David Dingus
LA Seminar - Argentina Debt Crises - David DingusLA Seminar - Argentina Debt Crises - David Dingus
LA Seminar - Argentina Debt Crises - David DingusDavid J Dingus
 

Similaire à The Politics of Economic Instability in the 21st Century: Argentina and the Dissipation of an Economic Miracle (16)

Macro project argentina crisis
Macro project  argentina crisisMacro project  argentina crisis
Macro project argentina crisis
 
Argentine​ ​Economic​ ​Crisis​ ​1998-2002 Abstract .docx
Argentine​ ​Economic​ ​Crisis​ ​1998-2002 Abstract .docxArgentine​ ​Economic​ ​Crisis​ ​1998-2002 Abstract .docx
Argentine​ ​Economic​ ​Crisis​ ​1998-2002 Abstract .docx
 
AnsA) When financial markets stood on the verge of collapse in th.pdf
AnsA) When financial markets stood on the verge of collapse in th.pdfAnsA) When financial markets stood on the verge of collapse in th.pdf
AnsA) When financial markets stood on the verge of collapse in th.pdf
 
Revista de Economia Política 30 (1), 2010 3The 2008 finan.docx
Revista de Economia Política  30 (1), 2010 3The 2008 finan.docxRevista de Economia Política  30 (1), 2010 3The 2008 finan.docx
Revista de Economia Política 30 (1), 2010 3The 2008 finan.docx
 
Economic Development Paper
Economic Development PaperEconomic Development Paper
Economic Development Paper
 
World economy towards the depression in 2015
World economy towards the depression in 2015World economy towards the depression in 2015
World economy towards the depression in 2015
 
Research Paper on the Economic Impact of the Catolonia Crisis
Research Paper on the Economic Impact of the Catolonia CrisisResearch Paper on the Economic Impact of the Catolonia Crisis
Research Paper on the Economic Impact of the Catolonia Crisis
 
The collapse of neoliberal globalization
The collapse of neoliberal globalizationThe collapse of neoliberal globalization
The collapse of neoliberal globalization
 
Political economy of asian financial crisis
Political economy of asian financial crisisPolitical economy of asian financial crisis
Political economy of asian financial crisis
 
Pincus, J.; Ramli, R. (1998). Indonesia from showcase to basket case. Cambrid...
Pincus, J.; Ramli, R. (1998). Indonesia from showcase to basket case. Cambrid...Pincus, J.; Ramli, R. (1998). Indonesia from showcase to basket case. Cambrid...
Pincus, J.; Ramli, R. (1998). Indonesia from showcase to basket case. Cambrid...
 
Global recession towards world economic depression
Global recession towards world economic depressionGlobal recession towards world economic depression
Global recession towards world economic depression
 
LA Seminar - Argentina Debt Crises - David Dingus
LA Seminar - Argentina Debt Crises - David DingusLA Seminar - Argentina Debt Crises - David Dingus
LA Seminar - Argentina Debt Crises - David Dingus
 
World economy toward bankruptcy
World economy toward bankruptcyWorld economy toward bankruptcy
World economy toward bankruptcy
 
Economic Crisis
Economic CrisisEconomic Crisis
Economic Crisis
 
Essay About Economy
Essay About EconomyEssay About Economy
Essay About Economy
 
Essay About Economy
Essay About EconomyEssay About Economy
Essay About Economy
 

The Politics of Economic Instability in the 21st Century: Argentina and the Dissipation of an Economic Miracle

  • 1. The Politics of Economic Instability in the 21st Century: Argentina and the Dissipation of an Economic Miracle Christopher Rinaldi POL 95W -- Senior Capstone Seminar Thesis Paper Professor Caroline Arnold This paper was written in 2008 for a capstone seminar course to complete my political science major at CUNY Brooklyn College. Introduction In 1998, following the East Asian Financial Crisis and Russian Fiscal Crisis, the economies of Latin America were confronted with the possibility of economic crises of their own. A decade later the result of this confrontation seems to favor the resilient economies of Latin America. This would be true, except for the case of Argentina, which overshadows the achievements of their neighbors in avoiding economic disaster. Not only was Argentina overcome by an economic crisis, but the Argentine economy was overcome, wholly, leading to a complete economic collapse. The central question that this paper aims to answer is: Why did Argentina‟s economic crisis devolve into utter economic collapse? I argue that, at first, Argentina‟s reaction to the crisis was deficient and inefficient. The government failed to make change in monetary policies to ease the shocks of devaluing their severely overvalued dollar. They maintained the currency board, pegging the value of the Argentine peso to the US dollar, therefore encouraging 1
  • 2. capital flight out of the country, since the peso could be easily converted to the safer US dollar currency of equal value. The manner of their privatization programs (Structural Adjustment Programs) was extremely laissez-faire. This included a lack of regulatory boards, tax reforms, budgetary reforms, and any necessary reform policies that should accompany liberalization. Adequate policy to address the enormous public debt and the possibility of bank insolvency was lacking as well. This left Argentina unprepared to maintain any ground underneath their economy. Problems with fiscal responsibility at the provincial level were never dealt with in any capacity by either federal or provincial governments. By this, it is meant that during Argentina's economic boom until their economic collapse, the government never made any reform that tackled the problem of maintaining spending limits. This was compounded with a poor tax collection system which, as well, never received any effective reform initiatives. All of these deficiencies displayed an economy built on a bubble defenseless to the prodding international economy and economic shocks. This fragile economy was a product of unstable politics and the Argentine government's reaction to the crisis they faced, yet again, was produced by unstable politics. In sum, the faults of Argentina‟s economy and their economic recovery efforts trace their roots to a political structure in which political actors find no calculation worth making besides political ones. From the federal to provincial level all issues, including economic issues, are political issues. The Argentine collapse is important to understand because it tells us something about the new international economy and the shifting rules of capital. Capital, today, has 2
  • 3. an abundance of investment options compared to the Cold War period before the dissolution of the Soviet Union. No longer is capital so single-minded to allocate itself based on economic philosophies. In an environment in which almost every country is liberalizing to some extent, and joining the international economy, capital‟s options expand, and even sitting on capital in the short-term may be better than rash investments, for the simple fact that if profits are missed in one country today, there will be another country tomorrow. The consequences of this is that capital demands security in structures, not philosophy. Therefore, the most liberal economy should be subject to stronger scrutiny. Structures are the new magnetizing force for capital. In a time when “hot money” and disruptive capital flows can drive the economy down, capital flees towards gains, but also safety. A country which can‟t accommodate capital‟s ever growing (and changing) wants and needs is doomed for failure. But to think that economic structures are not a product of political structures, or to write this off as unimportant, is consistent with philosophies which speak of the market as if it is natural and pre-existing. Humanity built the market and humanity built its structures. Where there is conflict in humanity (politics) there will be a conflict in the structures (economics). This conflict defines Argentina from 1991-2002, and it explains the country‟s economic collapse. Other scholars present varying explanations of the Argentine economic crisis including: the unilateral action of Brazil in fixing their economic woes; IMF-style development policy and privatization, and the formation of a small economic power bloc of large domestic and international business interests that controlled capital and insisted 3
  • 4. on the maintenance of the currency board at the sake of Argentina‟s economy. These will be considered against my hypothesis. I intend to focus on Argentina‟s economic collapse as an illustration of the necessity to have a political system which allows for dexterity in economic policy and a separation of that policy from political calculations. It is not an argument about state‟s and their involvement with the economy, so much as it is an argument about states and their ability to allow their economies to successfully react to and interact with the international economy. Before undertaking my argument and taking on other explanations of the crisis, I will lay out a brief history of the Argentine economy. This begins with the economic rise in the first-half of the 1990‟s along with introduction of the fixed currency board. It ends in 2002, after three years of deep recession leading to economic collapse. Following this, I will analyze and address alternative explanations of the Argentine financial crisis. Finally, I will provide empirical support for my argument that the politics of Argentina created an environment opposed to sustainable and competitive economic development. A History of Argentina: 1991-20021 At the beginning of the 1990‟s Argentina faced a dire problem of hyperinflation. (Gallo et al, 2004, 196). When President Carlos Menem took office in 1991 this would quickly change. He and his political ally, economic minister Domingo Cavallo, undertook an IMF style austerity plan to revive the stagnant Argentine economy. At the center of 1 All statistics in this section are taken from Gallo et al, Table 1: Economic Indicators, pg197. 4
  • 5. this plan was the creation of a convertible currency board which pegged the Argentine peso to the US dollar. In other words, 1 peso equaled 1 dollar. The currency board was paired with privatization efforts, and soon the Argentine economy was well on its way to development. The economy grew at a meteoric rate of 31.5% from 1991-1994. In 1995 the Mexican economic crisis caused shocks throughout the world, but particularly in Latin America. Argentina saw economic recession after its quick boom. The currency board, now fixed as law due to the iron-fisted President Menem, remained in place (Gallo et al, 196). This seemed to be no problem though, as the Argentine economy grew an astounding 13.6% in 1996 and 1997, including a 8.1% rate of growth in 1997. 1998 and 1999, by contrast, witnessed rates of growth, but below 4% for each year. Still, more troubling, in 1999 GDP per capita declined at 4.3% in a year which the GDP grew 3.4%. At this point, pessimism about the economy might have been helpful to the extent it could have prompted reform. Unfortunately, both a critical eye and critical action were not present in Argentina. Argentina saw the national budget deficit continually grow. As the government tried to reel in its spending, the politics of pandering, particularly at the provincial level, continued to contribute to a growing government debt. This debt continued to put downward pressure on an Argentine peso that was already overvalued, and this would be a precipitant of the crisis. Growth plummeted after 2000: GDP declined -.7% in 2000 which was followed over the next two years by a further 15.3% decline in GDP. In 2003 the economy grew 5
  • 6. 8.8%, mostly due to the fact it had already reached its floor. There are many factors to consider when assessing what happened to cause, both in its creation and extent, the Argentine economic crisis, but only one reason it led to the ruins of an “economic miracle”. Therefore, many hypotheses serve as attractive answers to the question, but only one can account for deep-seated problems that cause economic collapse--- that is political instability. The Argentine economic collapse was accompanied by social strain and social unrest. The crisis serves to display what economic prescriptions are needed to avoid doom, but it also serves as a reminder that economic collapse equates to social collapse. Macroeconomic troubles are not confined to paper, but instead are a build up of individual, human troubles. Just as economic troubles are representative of the individual struggles of people in society, they are also symbolic of the struggles in the politics of a country. In the end, an economy is only as stable as its government and political institutions. The economy will not have more dexterity than the political institutions that regulate it; economic growth will not outpace the growth of leadership, and although good politics may be able to fix an irresponsible market, a market, responsible or not, can not fix the irresponsible politics which created it. Literature Review Privatization Hypothesis The first, and most basic, explanation of the Argentine economic collapse points to economic factors. This explanation posits that privatization and economic reforms in 6
  • 7. peripheral countries, such as Argentina, are bound to fail. In the vein of dependency theory, it claims that international financial institutions such as the IMF, governments of the west (core countries), and multi-national companies, push privatization in an attempt to advance their economic interests at the expense of developing countries. In this view Argentina is seen as an economic pawn that serves the interests of more powerful interests. “The Rise and Collapse of Neoliberalism in Argentina: The Role of Economic Groups”, by Miguel Teubal, criticizes the post-ISI liberalization policies adopted by Argentina beginning in the mid-1970‟s for these very reasons. Teubal claims that economic liberalization created societal tension by eroding an old system in which large business interests co-mingled with small and mid-sized businesses (Teubal, 174). Under the structural adjustment policy (SAP), adopted through the 1990's by President Carlos Menem, large economic conglomerates, both national and transnational, came to dominate the adjustment process. Therefore, the process favored large enterprise and involved a tighter concentration of capital among them. In the late-1980‟s Argentina was facing hyperinflation in their currency. Argentina‟s showdown with hyperinflation is seen by Teubal as the perfect environment to introduce the currency board (181-185). Menem and Cavallo fixed the value of Argentina‟s peso to the US dollar and the problem of inflation was solved. According to Teubal, it also provided a solid footing to enhance the privatization processes by "limiting... the central bank to... an exchange broker" and "eliminating all government discretionality [over] monetary and foreign exchange policy." (Teubal, 181) Therefore, as industry privatized, foreign interests would be attracted by a strong currency, 7
  • 8. prompting more international mobility for their capital earned in Argentina. As the process became enhanced, the welfare of the Argentine majority became neglected. Without proper instruments to guard against capital flight and the “[exclusion of] the institutionalization of efficient regulatory boards, which in the First World are an essential part of most privatization programs”, the Argentine economy was fundamentally flawed (Teubal, 181). Since the Argentinian peso was pegged 1:1 with the dollar, it was a simple decision to exchange pesos into dollars, put those dollars in a foreign account, and therefore cash-out at the overvalued rate opposed to the undervalued rate that lied inevitably ahead. Large enterprise, both foreign and domestic, could do this easily though their transnational financial service companies, while draining the money supply of the Argentine nation and their banks. On the other hand, the Argentine people were vulnerable to be hit the hardest from the crisis. Their only protection was a government which had spent the last quarter of a century deconstructing itself (Teubal, 186-187). Teubal‟s analysis touches on many problems, such as how SAP left the people of Argentina without a hope in the worst of times. He portrays the idea that the classes which controlled capital used Argentina as a sponge for their debts, while acting as a vacuum for capital produced within Argentina. The Argentine people were the most effected and during this privatization process they saw their interests abandoned. Regional Hypothesis A developing international economy means more economic integration, particularly at the regional level. In the Americas, regional economic integration 8
  • 9. highlights itself in the organization MERCOSUR and the trade pact NAFTA. The former, MERCOSUR, is of concern. It is a South American trade association with four full members, including Argentina and Brazil (Genna and Hiroi, 337). As mentioned prior, financial hardship faced many countries approaching the new century, and Brazil‟s economy demanded policy adjustment to be saved. “The Effects of Unequal Size: The Costs and Benefits of Unilateral Action in the Development of MERCOSUR”, by Gaspare M. Genna and Taeko Hiroi, explains the role of Brazil as the largest member of MERCOSUR, and the effect that this has upon smaller member states of MERCOSUR. Genna and Hiroi, explaining the crisis through a liberal viewpoint, argue that Brazil finds itself in a unique role in MERCOSUR as its largest and most wealthy member. Due to their status, Brazil becomes the country that all of the other MERCOSUR members will look to in times of crisis or despair. Brazil will be expected absorb shocks and fix problems (Genna and Hiroi, 338). The authors contend that a study of Brazilian policy displays that their active engagement in regional crises is necessary for smaller states to work through their crises. If they act unilaterally, as they did when they faced a currency crisis in 1999, the smaller neighboring economies can be directly affected due to their integrated position with Brazil. As they note, “Much of the existing political economy literature on free trade and regional integration argues that successful trade liberalization and economic integration requires a regional preponderant power that acts as a core provider of collective goods for member states.” (Genna and Hiroi, 338) 9
  • 10. Once Brazil was able to devalue their way through their crisis and return to its feet, the Argentine economy was at its knees. Instead of focusing only on itself, Brazil‟s policymakers were able to concern themselves with the current situation in Argentina, which was about to devalue their peso. This time, Brazil actively pursued trade and credit policies that would ease the burden on the Argentine economy. When President Duhalde was ready to devalue the Argentine peso in 2002, he sought Brazilian assistance. The communications between the countries resulted in lower tariffs for Argentine exporters, while a reciprocal credit accord gave the central banks of Argentina and Brazil the right and responsibility to exchange exporter‟s currency received for domestic currency. As well, Brazil became a mouthpiece for Argentina on the international level, lobbying the IMF, US government, the World Bank, and other important financial institutions to help Argentina. (Genna and Hiroi, 347-349) In order to support their speech, “the Brazilian National Bank of Economic and Social Development opened a line of credit for Brazilian foreign direct investment in Argentina.” (Genna and Hiroi, 351) Genna and Hiroi study a key aspect of the Argentine Financial Crisis. Over the last decade of the 20th Century, Argentina had become part of MERCOSUR. As the new century neared, MERCOSUR remained a young institution in which member states contracted in policies that attempted to evolve towards integration and coordination, but were not yet there. The effects that Brazil‟s devaluation would have on Argentina‟s economy were not considered because for Brazil, “their primary concern may not be on the effect that their actions will have on regional partners but the effect on their domestic constituencies.” (Genna and Hiroi, 338) 10
  • 11. Capital Relations Hypothesis David Woodruff„s study, “Boom, Gloom, Doom: Balance Sheets, Monetary Fragmentation, and the Politics of Financial Crisis in Argentina and Russia”, offers an alternative explanation to the Argentine financial crisis. Woodruff sees the problem in Argentina‟s economy lying directly with the fixed currency board and the capital relations that built around it. First, Woodruff contends that currency boards have three phases. The first is boom, or large economic growth. The second is gloom, or slowdown from such large economic growth. The third, and final phase, is doom, or the collapse of the economic growth which was heralded in the „boom‟ phase. (Woodruff, 4) As well, the study views capital from an “institutional-sociological” point of view. This view allows for an explanation of the impact the currency board had on the majority of capital interests (Woodruff, 6). This is combined with an analysis of business interests and actions which define the purpose of business action and interests as relating solely to the balance sheet of a business (Woodruff, 9-10). Woodruff maintains that when these two perspectives are used the Argentine maintenance of the currency board, and therefore their economic collapse, can be explained. Argentine banks and utility companies, the largest capital interests, mannered their balance sheets to assume liabilities and assets in dollars. When the peso could no longer keep up with the dollar, in terms of value, these businesses were so entrenched, that they were better off “gambling for resurrection”, as opposed to disbanding the currency board itself, which would have to be done in due time anyway. Woodruff terms 11
  • 12. these interests “go-for-brokers” whom will be willing to issue any number of “costly signals” of their commitment to maintaining the peg, since these signals will in fact add nothing to their costs in the event the peg fails” (Woodruff, 30) These “go-for-brokers”, representing a majority of the capital that created the boom in Argentina, lost their chance to cut their losses (lobby for a repeal of the currency board) in the gloom, and became willing to fight for their position until all the money available from all sources had dried up, and the doom turned into an inevitable retraction of the currency board. The other group that represented Argentine capital interests is the “good fighters”. This group tried to cut their losses and support the currency board, although they are not all-in, and become aware that devaluation may be the best option at a certain point. Eventually, this group will reach the point where they maximize their cover of dollar denominated asset liability. At this point, peso devaluation will help them cover remaining liabilities more than maintaining convertibility (Woodruff, 31-32). Argentine provinces began issuing their own surrogate pesos which “by the end of the year…had been issued to almost a quarter of the volume of pesos.” (Woodruff, 28) A monetary surrogate is a form of capital that is not legally recognized. For example, in Russia, Woodruff points out (24-25) that the electric companies used to accept metal from metal companies to compensate for missed electric payments by the metal companies. But surrogates appeared only in 2001 and in much more restricted form (I.e., no bartering) in Argentina (Woodruff, 27-28). They only served to speed up the devaluation process so much as they were looked upon as actual notes that could service payment in provinces. 12
  • 13. The lack of monetary surrogates, Woodruff argues, also points to the large international interests in the Argentine economy. Utilities and financial interests derived mobile capital from Argentina due to the 1:1 fixed ratio of the peso and the dollar. They could not accept surrogates for a value that was fixed so high on their balance sheets (Woodruff, 23-24). Woodruff leaves little to question about the phases of boom, doom, and gloom involving the implementation and maintenance of currency boards. But, what if the currency board is enacted and repealed in gloom times, before doom onsets? What if it is repealed at the beginning of a crisis? Take the Brazilian case, for example. His analysis gives one possible answer to a puzzling question concerning the Argentine financial crisis, which is why did the currency board remain intact so long? He says that powerful capital interests viewed the currency board as essential to maintaining their balance sheets. Political Hypothesis “The Role of Political Institutions in the Resolution of Economic Crises: The Case of Argentina 2001–05”, by Andres Gallo, Juan Pablo Stegmann, and Jeffery W. Steagall, frame Argentina‟s economic woes as a result of political instability. The country, since hyperinflation that struck at the end of the 1980‟s, has been dominated by corrupt political rule that is inefficient. Corruption and inefficiency can also be credited to an unresolved federalism, which has led to a lack of coordination on economic issues between Argentine provinces and the federal government. The study identifies that, “At the root of Argentina‟s economic problems lies an irresolvable conflict between the 13
  • 14. nation‟s federal and provincial political powers.” (Gallo et al, 195) Beginning with President Menem, and his insistence on the creation of the currency board and IMF-style development, political instability is indexed. Menem used tactics such as manipulation of the Supreme Court, which led him to rule through “executive decrees” and to undermine legitimate legal institutions. Menem‟s policies advanced development, but a development built on a false foundation of political unity on economic issues (Gallo et al, 196). The provincial authorities, at odds with Menem‟s reforms, undermined them with rogue spending on enhancing budgets, and eventually with the production of monetary surrogates, as Woodruff noted. But unlike Woodruff‟s hypothesis, which says that this was due to an exhaustion of the benefits of the currency board, Gallo finds the cause of this occurrence in the exhaustion of political outlets to form economic policy (Gallo et al, 198-201). When devaluation was finally on the brink the political in situation in Argentina was at the height of its fracture. The country faced the difficult task of devaluation, and had no mechanisms in place that could ensure a fair and efficient devaluation (Gallo et al 201-202). At this point the extent and impact of the poor political structures of Argentina bared itself to the world and the Argentine nation. Policies that continued into the economic collapse were ill-fated due to their lost nature and their inherent failure to actually deal with the problem. Instead, they dealt with the political power‟s problems. The corralito on deposits harmed the depositor, as their deposits fell victim to devaluation. A series of measures that attacked bondholders of 14
  • 15. Argentine debt, bank depositors, and banks themselves persisted due to the government‟s drive to fix their own budget at the expense of private property rights (Gallo et al 201,208). The attempt to close the budget deficit was a political and self-interested calculation done to remain in power and not to benefit the Argentine economy or population. The government continues in this vein. Long-term resolutions to solve the federal-provincial power and revenue sharing and revenue sharing problems, along with banking reform, remain untouched due to the lack of political coordination. Successful debt restructuring is also hindered by the retarded political system, and as long as this continues, the Argentine people can expect to slowly pay off the first great economic crash of the 21st Century (Gallo et al 208-210). Empirical Review Gallo‟s argument, the political hypothesis, explains many of the problems that the other scholars mentioned have explored. It seems that: a) privatization is not the problem, but the politics of Argentine privatization is; b) Brazilian unilateral action in the context of MERCOSUR had an effect on Argentina, but it is nothing that could have not been avoided by unilateral action of Argentina, and c) a small power bloc controlling exchange rate policy, whether true or not, does not answer the main question, why is there a concentrated power bloc controlling these decisions? The answer is an unstable political system. Below I aim to detail a political system filled with corruption, incomplete reforms, fragmentation, and incompetence, leaving no room in between for sound economic policy and development. Also, keep in mind, politics is important because it 15
  • 16. creates economic structures. Today, these structures are more important than ever. The Politics of Carlos Menem When Carlos Menem was elected into office he was faced with the political nightmare of hyperinflation. As talked about before, he solved this problem by implementing economic adjustment reforms based around the currency board. But, the currency board and economic liberalization was not universally accepted in Argentina. While some politicians and citizens supported the liberalization reforms, others were against them and believed that solving the problem of hyperinflation required something other than the currency board and liberalizing the economy. Moreover, Menem faced a Supreme Court that was hostile to his new economic reforms. Therefore, Menem had to answer two evident questions to reform Argentina‟s economy: 1) how can enough political support be garnered to pass economic reforms?, and 2) how can these reforms be maintained through judicial support? In essence, Menem needed to devise a plan to suppress a majority of political representation and tarnish Argentina‟s judicial integrity, or reverse a long history of legal precedent which restricted liberal economic policies. First, concerning the issue of the judiciary, Menem saw his best option as compromising judicial integrity. Menem, very early on, “packed” the Supreme Court with loyal judges by expanding the court itself. Other government auditing and prosecuting institutions were compromised by Menem‟s attempt to consolidate political and legal power in support of his economic reforms (Blake, 7-8). The consequence of the forceful consolidation was that Argentina‟s economy was 16
  • 17. built on a legal system backed by a political machine. By 1995, Menem‟s reforms and political style were falling out of favor and he was lacking credibility with the Argentine population. 1995 also marked Menem‟s second term, which was only allowed after a generous legal alteration to the electoral rules (Blake, 8). He won re-election and continued to erode national confidence in democratic institutions. While he was internationally praised, he was nationally disdained. His popularity in 1995 was nearly equal to that of his predecessor, Raul Alfonsin, whom led the country during hyperinflation (Blake, 17-18). Still, no one considered what would happen to the economy when the only politician supporting the economic structure ceased being a politician. Secondly, there is the issue of passing these reforms through the legislative process. How did Menem do this? Well, he often did not. When he came into office he was granted the utilitarian political tool of economic disaster. The country‟s dire economic situation swayed Congress to grant Menem powers “equivalent to a blank check, as Congress authorized the president to enact economic reforms through executive orders.” (Blake, 7) Menem, the Peronist candidate, was also given the benefit of a friendly Chamber of Deputies (congress) filled with other Peronist politicians, who found their self in power, like Menem, due to the country‟s dire economic situation. Menem leveraged his force with a poor economic situation, a competitive political unit in Congress, and a compromising of the Argentine legal system. Charles H. Blake, in the paragraph below, details Menem‟s political force in the early years: As a result, early privatization measures and other key reforms were implemented with minimal 17
  • 18. congressional oversight. The legislature established the Comision Bicameral de la Reforma del Estado (CBRE), a congressional commission to monitor the privatization process. The CBRE could request that the executive branch justify its plans, but had no power to stop a sale. Interestingly enough, when the time came to vote for the State Reform Law, the Chamber of Deputies lacked the prescribed quorum. To bypass the problem, the Peronist leadership apparently brought into the voting session several congressional employees, who voted in support of the measure. (7) Soon enough, Argentina‟s economic reform included a currency board. The pegging of the Argentine peso to the US dollar finally eliminated inflation, but it came with other consequences. The system propelled a rigid economy that took away the possibility of nearly all monetary adjustments for the future. It also presents a more attractive environment for foreign investment, as the currency‟s value becomes backed by US dollars, and therefore comes with the security of the US dollar. Not to mention, the peg was a political strength too--- the times of inflation were over. But, were the causes of inflation really dealt with? Sub-national Politics in Argentina The politics of Argentina‟s provinces and nature of Argentine federalism are important in an analysis of the country in any topic or at any level. In any federal system the distribution of power and revenue are important, but in Argentina it is even more important due to the important and dependent, but not harmonious, relationship which defines the co-existence between the provincial and federal governments. There are 24 provinces in Argentina, containing 1,100 municipalities (Rezk, 2002). While they each have ample taxing powers, most taxation is done by the federal government. This money is then distributed to each province based on population. This tax arrangement is referred to as “co-participation” in Argentina (Edwards, 2002). In 18
  • 19. 2001 the provinces drew 52.7% of their revenues from this federal sharing program (Rezk, 2002). In addition to a bulk of their revenue flowing from the federal to state level, budget performance numbers flow the opposite way (Remmer and Wibbles, 430). Therefore, a province, technically, never has a budget surplus or deficit, because this will be reflected in the Argentine federal government budget. Also, party politics change at this level. Smaller parties, not involved in federal politics, are important in politics at the provincial level. A handful of them can either oust a national party, or in some provinces, the national party or provincial party may come to solely dominate provincial politics (Remmer and Wibbels, 429). Sub-national Politics in the Context of National Economic Adjustment Although Menem first pushed his economic reforms, at some point fiscal and administrative reform would be needed to ensure economic success. Argentina came into the 1990‟s with a large budget deficit. Addressing the deficit was put on hold temporarily by a restructuring of debt resulting in the issuances of Brady bonds to cover the country‟s debt (Cavallo and Cottani, 18). But, reforming the country‟s fiscal prudence was essential to economic success. A country which converts to a currency board can not have its reserves threatened because the reserves are what back the currency (Blake, 8). Beating back the budget deficit was not something that could be dealt with through economic adjustment on the national level. It involved policy changes that the national government had to initiate and carry through. The provincial level is where the spending takes place, as “the federal government has been collecting more than 80% of 19
  • 20. public revenues and retaining 55%”. The other 25%, or 5% of GDP, makes it ways into provincial coffers (Remmer and Wibbels, 430). The “co-participation” law unevenly distributes money to provinces. The distribution, despite being based on population, doesn‟t even out per capita. The result is this: small provinces (ex. Santa Cruz), in terms of population, are left with a large amount of revenue, while the larger (ex. Buenos Aires) provinces are given a small amount revenue in account of its large population (Remmer and Wibbels, 435). As Karen Remmer and Erik Wibbels point out (432), the situation of a large budget in a small province facilitates political patronage networks. “Public sector employment figures reflect the divergence in national and provincial policies. After increasing approximately 25% between 1983 and 1990, the number of civil servants in the national public administration was cut dramatically from 835,485 in 1990 to 190,414 in 1994. At the provincial level, the trend was diametrically the opposite. After expanding 40% between 1983 and 1990, provincial public sector employment may be estimated to have increased by an additional 77% between 1990 and 1995, a period marked by one of the most intense stabilization efforts in Argentine history.” From 1984-1985 to 19952 provincial revenues grew, overall, at a rate of 67.6%, while their expenditures grew at a rate of 71.2%. Revenues from co-participation and their own taxes grew 130.1% and 82.4% respectively. Still, in this scenario only three provinces, including Buenos Aires, kept their budgets out of the red by the end of 1995. 2 The statistics following within the paragraph are all taken from Remmer and Wibbels, Table 2: Revenues of the Argentine Province, 1984/1985-1995 (Constant 1995 US Dollars), pg 431 20
  • 21. Combined, the provincial governments ran a deficit of $3,275,000,0003 pesos in 1995 alone. With “salaries [absorbing] roughly 60% of current revenues” (Remmer and Wibbels, 436), the Argentine provinces used the co-participation fund as a civil servant fund. Between 1991 and 1994, the provinces raised their payroll 41%, meanwhile, overall spending spiked 38.9% between 1991 and 1995 (Remmer and Wibbels, 438-439). Therefore, some of Miguel Teubal‟s grievances about the government‟s social expenditures find a stronger link to patronage networks and corruption, opposed to privatization. This is, again, important for several reasons. The point is that not only were the provinces adding to a deficit, but they were doing it at the expense of the currency board. Menem, with his political career tied to the boards success, did not attack the problems of the provinces. He either supported the spending or was trying to win political favor, as displayed when ,“Under the auspices of [the] stabilization program, these [co-participation] arrangements were renegotiated in 1992 and 1993, when the number and percentage of taxes subject to co-participation were lowered in exchange for federal agreement to a minimal contribution of 8.9 million pesos, which represented a 50% increase over the amount received by the provinces in 1990.” (Remmer and Wibbels, 430) The problem of the provinces was not solely shown in the budget deficit. The effect it had upon the budget deficit caused a reaction. The Argentine national government compensated for overspending with under spending. “The success of 3 Table 3: Provincial Operating Balances, 1991-1995 (millions of pesos), pg 438, 21
  • 22. Argentine adjustment effort of the early 1990s was thus achieved through policies of over-adjustment at the national level that compensated for public sector expansion and financial fragilities at the provincial level”(Remmer and Wibbels, 432), meaning the government continued in its privatization efforts, without funding it with proper regulation and oversight. On the eve of Menem‟s departure in 1999 Peter Hudson (1999) wrote “a reduction in local costs will demand that Menem‟s successor pays urgent attention to tasks left undone: a major restructuring of the tax system to stamp out evasion, lowering of taxes on employment, a reduction in public-utilities tariffs, and a reorganization of inefficient government spending.” (180) Economics as Politics and Vice Versa: Maintaining ‘The Peg’ So far some of the problems with the currency board have been explored. In this section, I will talk about them more, but first, here‟s a list of the problems the currency board causes: 1) Low exports due to the relative high price of manufacturing 2) High percentage of import consumption due to monetary strength 3) The currency board can not manage high budget deficits 4) Small domestic manufacturing sector (see (1)), low real wages due to high monetary value, and high unemployment for the same reason. The currency board is a reasonable tool, in the sense in can begin to ignite investor confidence by securing a currency and it can remove a population from the perils of inflation. But, an environment like the one described above does not facilitate the Remmer and Wibbels (2000) 22
  • 23. currency board as a permanent feature. Much of the literature on Argentina‟s economic reforms refers to Menem and Cavallo‟s reforms as „shock therapy‟. This term itself points to the temporality and care which these reforms necessitate. The problem is that Menem and Cavallo found themselves and their reputations, for the former nationally and the latter internationally, on the line with the success of the currency board. They hailed it as the be-all-end-all of economic reforms. Not even the IMF encouraged and supported these reforms (Cavallo and Cottani, 19). Matter of fact, they discouraged these reforms. Cavallo lived up to his reputation as a bellicose public figure with a brazen attack on the IMF and floating exchange rates in his paper “Argentina‟s Convertibility Plan and the IMF”, written with Joaquin A. Cottani, and presented at the Hundred and Fourth Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association in 1997. Cavallo‟s conclusions about the currency board are questionable and almost delusional. He emphasizes the need for consistent, rule-based economic policy. This of course, is provided by the currency board. On the other hand, discretionary, or floating currency value, is portrayed as a political tool (Cavallo and Cottani, 19-20). He goes on to speak of reform by a “democratic government, with no extraordinary foreign assistance.” This reform, backed by the currency board, is responsible for “improvements in technology and management” at the microeconomic level. The former claim is misleading and the latter claim, even if true, does not speak to the fact that these improvements were all for naught. What Cavallo forgets to mention is that the “improvements in technology and management” manifest themselves as debt in 23
  • 24. a failing economy. Exports remained dismally below the levels of the region (See (1) above) and “the supply-side shocks” were not enough to offset import consumption with domestic consumption. As Cavallo continues to read from his personal economic history book the words become more surreal. He speaks of “Argentina‟s outstanding use of IMF credit” which goes against much of the conclusions in the literature on the issue. Many people tend to point to the IMF as lending and advising in a manner that caused Argentina‟s downfall. According to Domingo Cavallo the IMF was certainly in conflict with Argentina, but not as the consensus believes. “Nevertheless, differences of opinion have existed in matters of economic policy between the Argentine authorities and the IMF staff since the beginning of the Convertibility Plan”, he says, “the IMF never believed in the currency board as a long-term arrangement.” He also reveals that many of the tax cuts initiated in Argentina were not supported by the IMF and they were blatantly discouraged (Cavallo and Cottani, 19). David Woodruff‟s paradigm of “go-for-brokers”, “unwinders“, and “good fighters” seems correct, but not in his context. The political players in Argentina were looking at their balance sheets. The political balance sheet is denominated in something far more intangible than dollars and can not explain how society shapes around economic policy, but instead how politics shapes around economic policy. The Election of 1999 and the Revolving Presidency: Inheriting A Political and Economic Nightmare 24
  • 25. The election of 1999 marked the end of Carlos Menem‟s reign as President. There was talk of him, that March, attempting to run for a third time. This would be done through bypassing electoral law through a popular referendum. The previous July, of 1998, saw Menem announce that he would not seek to maneuver his way into a third term, but something seemed to spark a change of heart. The fickle Menem, in July of 1999, explicitly dropped his bid for a third term, most likely resulting from party pressure and the possible embarrassment of being beaten by Eduardo Duhalde in the Peronist‟s run-off elections. The election of 1999 also marked the beginning of the end for Argentina‟s “economic miracle”. The ensuing three years would see three presidents, in addition to one “provisional president for 48 hours”. These three years saw: additional loans from the international community; an initial run of the banks; the re-introduction of Domingo Cavallo as Minister of the Economy; the issuance of “provincial bonds…to pay public salaries”; various debt swaps; a debt moratorium; a final run on the banks leading to devaluation; rising unemployment, and social unrest (Hornbeck, 2002). As capital fled the country and provincial bonds were used to service salaries the inevitable devaluation and its economic and social consequences continued to deteriorate. As spoken of before, devaluation is a process that should have occurred sometime near the beginning of Menem‟s second term, before overvaluation of the peso was locked in and problematic. The campaign of 1999 was not a pretty one as well and added to the burden on the Argentine economy. Eduardo Duhalde and Fernando De La Rua provided 25
  • 26. populist rhetoric and economic evaluations which hurt investor confidence. Cavallo railed each of the candidates for their behavior on the campaign trail, in his typically blunt fashion. Still, despite the two candidate perceived disagreement with the policies of the 1990‟s, the winner, Fernando De La Rua, maintained these same policies. When they proved especially difficult to manage, De La Rua turned to Cavallo himself to fix the economy (Makuc, 73). The disaster of maintaining a pegged currency in Russia was available as evidence, while Brazil at this time was going through a devaluation process of there own. Why then, was there such faith in the currency board in Argentina? Even more, why from an administration that ran a campaign presenting policies opposed to the currency board? One reason, as discussed prior, is that the strength of the political benefit of enacting the currency board in Argentina would have produced the exact opposite political effect with equal strength when the currency board was retracted. The economic institutions, political institutions, and legal institutions were all built around the currency board and loyalty to Carlos Menem. Although the following thought is not supported by empirical facts, it doesn‟t seem presumptuous to assume Argentina may not have possessed the human capital to devalue. In the end, the populist rhetoric in the 1999 campaign was political pandering and served no other purpose than to hurt everyone‟s confidence in the system. The patience of the citizens is also in question concerning devaluation. President de la Rua, or none of his successors, had the political clout to devalue. Adrian Makuc, national director of foreign trade policy in Argentina beginning in 1998, said in 2002, 26
  • 27. while still in his official position: “Politicians are not credible in Argentina. When somebody comes to the podium and talks as a politician in Argentina, nobody believes him.” (Makuc, 73) By the time Duhalde devalued in 2002, there was little chance there wouldn‟t be social unrest. The social unrest was justified by the plight of the Argentine population, but, although it could never be measured exactly, the Argentine people‟s history of protest in the face of fiscal reform made devaluing an unattractive option in 2002 and prior. Still, in no way do I mean to indict the people of Argentina, because politicians are supposed to be leaders, and therefore devaluation should have been worked out in the face unpopular sentiment. The Argentine population‟s short patience for tough reforms is not only justified by their economic realities, but also by the trust issue introduced by Makuc. Distrust of Argentine politicians is quite reasonable in reference to history and the present. Carlos Menem‟s regime became known for corruption which the politician was able to brush off despite the fact the corruption did exist. Despite the “official” ability to survive, in reality it tarnished his reputation and planted the seeds of distrust in society (Blake, 8). Secondly, De La Rua followed by continuing to provide a safe haven for corruption. The situation was so bad that his Vice President Carlos Alvarez resigned due to De La Rua‟s inability and inaction in weeding out corruption from the government (Hornbeck, CRS-3). Finally, to portray how bad the economic situation was concerning politics, look at the events of power succession following de la Rua‟s resignation according to a Congressional Report (Hornbeck 2002): 27
  • 28. December 20: President de la Rua resigns in the wake of continued rioting... December 21: …Senate President Ramon Puerta is named provisional president for 48 hours December 23: Congress appoints San Luis Governor Adolfo Rodriguez Saa as interim president until elections in March 2002. December 30: President Rodriguez Saa resigns after continued rioting…Senate leader Puerta resigns to avoid second appointment as interim president… (CRS-4) Essentially, no politician wanted to get their hands dirty with this devaluation. After less than a week in presidency Rodriguez Saa, from his house in San Luis province, away from the capital, gave an unsympathetic resignation to the Argentine people (Makuc, 2002): “…„Well, I‟m resigning.‟ He said „I am giving here to the armed forces officer that is with me, my letter of resignation to take to the national capital.‟ That was original. He went there, secluded himself in his province like a big landlord and just told the thirty-seven million Argentinians, „You can do whatever you want.‟ ” (74) Less than a week later Eduardo Duhalde, leader of the new Peronist party (Menem‟s coalition representing the old Peronist bloc), officially ended the currency board on January 6, 2002, after being appointed President (Hornbeck, CRS-5). At this point the economy, society, the banking system, and practically all major areas of Argentine life were dealt the long overdue, and therefore powerful, blow of devaluation. This was the economic „shock therapy‟ that Domingo Cavallo could be proud of. Duhalde‟s devaluation made every US $1 equal to 1.4 pesos concerning loans. Concerning deposits, there was an even 1:1 swap from what was a US dollar to the now properly, and extremely low, valued peso. This made matters worse by hurting confidence in the banking system and hurt depositors as well (Gallo et al 201,208). Overall, Duhalde‟s policies weren‟t received well in “Menem‟s Court”, so at the expense of legal integrity, again, the court was unpacked and re-packed to push through 28
  • 29. Duhalde‟s reform. The new Peronist political machine has followed Duhalde‟s presidency with the chosen successor Nestor Kirchner and in the name of democracy Kirchner‟s wife, Cristina Elisabet Fernández Wilhem de Kirchner, followed in line and is currently serving as President. Banking and Monetary Policy in the 21st Century: Brazil and Argentina Compared Argentina‟s banking system is the final issue in the analysis of the crisis. Argentina had no foundation for banking law, including a lack of policy concerning insolvent banks. As evidenced by a 2003 Economist article, Argentina, one year after devaluation, had yet to sort out the problems within their banking system. Again, dealing with banks would open up political vulnerabilities. Despite the generally optimistic Economist article, it ends on the same note that this paper is based upon: “Mr. Duhalde will indeed leave Argentina in a much better state than he found it--but he is also bequeathing many unpopular decisions to his successor.” (Economist, 2003) Social unrest in Argentina began in 2001 when the first hold on bank deposits took place. The following corralito of 2002 worsened the social upheaval. This need for freezing bank withdrawals and the uneven devaluation also highlighted the lack of rules, regulations, and structure in the banking system and economy as a whole. It also displayed the lack of regulation and planning to monitor banks and their operating abilities. Therefore, weather the devaluation ended up favoring depositors or borrowers was arbitrary without the guidance of law. The government, being a prolific borrower, constructed a devaluation policy favoring borrowers. In reality each side should have 29
  • 30. sacrificed in a fair devaluation. In 1999 John W. Head thought that the East Asian Financial Crisis would teach countries and supranational organizations lessons about banking standards in the international economy, which would be “the silver lining to the dark cloud of the Asian financial crisis.” In the case of Argentina, he was wrong. Head‟s other “silver linings” was the crisis‟s ability to display the need for central bank independence and policies that would thwart disruptive capital flows (for example, Chile heavily taxes short-term inflow) (Head, 951-954). Again, this information did not seem to make it to Argentine policy makers. Argentina‟s devaluation policy was indiscriminate to banks which may still be solvent and those which were insolvent. Head advocated the adoption of international banking standard and encouraged central banks, commercial banks, and governments to join in to restructure domestic banking law. This included a tough policy for insolvent banks which in some countries, including Argentina, are allowed to stay open and “bleed [depositors] dry of all the…money.” (Head, 953) When trouble started to appear in Argentina the political situation was so bad that banks had no one to work with on creating a law. Like the previous years, no one was working on laws or any other sort of policies to maintain the economy. Argentina‟s “leaders” were to busy riding the political carousel. In most part, the lack of regulation and structure in banking and capital markets can be attributed to Menem‟s continual neglect to create policies that complemented the currency board, or liberalization in general. On the other hand, when economic fortunes were grim in Brazil their 30
  • 31. politicians reacted to the possibility of devaluation. The Genna and Hiroi article talked about Brazil‟s devaluation of the real, and its effect upon Argentina. This was not the only thing Brazil did though, and it would be unwise to think that simple devaluation will be followed by an economic upturn. Brazil, like Argentina, consists of many provinces (26) and municipalities (5,500). The Brazilian budget is also at the mercy of the provincial budgets, as they show up as one statistic as in Argentina (de Albuquerque, 165, Guira, 486). On top of Brazil‟s devaluation they increased taxes, cut spending, and drastically reformed the country‟s tax code and civil servant system (de Albuquerque, 2000, Guira, 2001). Pretty much, everything that post-East Asian Financial Crisis literature was advocating, Brazil was initiating. Brazil, while addressing these issues, also provided “the political will to educate their citizentry on the need to absorb short-term pain to ensure long-term gain.” (Guira, 492) Hand-in-hand with the IMF, Brazil went through devaluation. The IMF‟s cooperation and assistance was buoyed by an already existing cooperative arrangement to clean up Brazil‟s banking law. Before devaluation Brazil took part in adopting the Basle Twenty-Five Principles for Effective Banking, along with preparation to start selling state-owned banks (Guira, 504). In short, it seems Brazil was preparing to devalue, and their need to devalue appeared a little earlier than expected, but the reforms were underway already. They were building the economic structures that the 21st Century international economy demanded. That means political in-roads had been developed, and therefore Brazil held the country in harmony through some very tough reforms. Brazil‟s system favored action 31
  • 32. to bail out the economy, while Argentina‟s lack of a banking system favored action to bail out the government. For example, the nearly 12 billion dollars in loans and commercial bank debt attributed to the Argentine government looks a lot better divided by 1.4. Banking reform also tackles the “moral hazard” question (Head, 962-963). If a bank is aware of the conditions that it becomes liquidated, restructured, or propped under, it no doubt effects their actions. Argentina is a tricky situation because it seems the lack of banking law led “moral hazard” to favor the government (insolvent banks benefited as well), but usually it is the other way around. In the end, the lack of banking law is bad for its effects in deteriorating investors‟ confidence, and immoral characters (abound in both developed and developing countries) can maneuver their way to the beneficial side of “moral hazard” if the rules are not defined. Governments must define the terms and therefore eliminate uncertainty and “moral hazard” altogether. The fates of Brazil and Argentina seem to diverge somewhere in the mid-1990‟s. Brazil‟s attitude was something along the lines of: If we have to devalue, we have to devalue. To mediate the costs adjustments must take place. Therefore, devaluation will still be able to retain capital inflows due to the fact the system is sound and fair. Argentina simply took the attitude: If we have to devalue, something went horribly wrong, so we won‟t have to devalue. Adjustments were never in mind. Domingo Cavallo and the Argentine political elite thought the currency board, unregulated markets, the promise of capital mobility, and making statements to keep investor confidence was the key to maintaining capital inflows. In their context, devaluation was not a possibility. The impossibility was not an economic reality, it was a political reality. Judging from 32
  • 33. Cavallo‟s paper, by the time the international community was adjusting its previous beliefs, Argentina was cementing its faith in the old model. It truly became Argentina against the international community. While Brazil‟s leadership was working with the IMF Argentina‟s leadership was bickering with it--- worst of all, in a public economic forum. Concluding on the Collapse and Its Implications for Development in the 21st Century What are the lessons from Argentina? It‟s time for everyone to withdraw from their comfortable positions in economic philosophies. Development theorists all across the spectrum will only continue to spur rigid and inefficient environments that will lead to economic disaster. It‟s a wake up call to populations, politicians, bankers, and all policy makers alike: You‟re not creating policy and indexing its „soundness‟ to outdated philosophies. The rules of capital are the index of proper and improper economic policy. In the international economy, to think that the rules of capital are stagnant, and that numbers that meant one thing 20 years ago (or even 5) will symbolize the same thing in the present is foolish, outdated, and a recipe for economic collapse. It is about structures over everything else. Structures have transcended philosophy on its way becoming capital„s main attraction. Again, where capital once looked for a home with an environment built on a philosophy, it now searches for a home with an environment built on structures. As Argentina showed, an economy built on philosophy has no safety, while an economy built on structure can only far as fall as its structures allow it. But, this is not the sole purpose of this paper. The purpose of this paper, then, 33
  • 34. was to display this idea through Argentina‟s Economic Collapse. The proper economic structures are created by political structures and development will only fail without political harmony, responsibility, and function. Political harmony should not be taken as political hegemony. It means politicians are trusted by the people, to the point that political factions are beneficial in creating policy, not detrimental. By responsibility it is meant that economic policy is not a political tool. Carlos Menem compromised the basic foundations of the Argentine state in order to hold power for 10 years. This is an attitude that ran through Argentina‟s political system in the 1990‟s. Menem‟s style (political irresponsibility) was caused by a lack of alliances between Menem and other political parties and the people (political disharmony). The confluence of these two factors is a recipe for political dysfunction. It is a paradigm that defines the Argentine Economic Crisis: Liberalization was irresponsible, because without harmony, the necessary reforms to accompany it were not going to come due to political dysfunction. This only added rigidity to the economy. Rigid systems produce rigid results. Hence, Argentina experienced the polarizing effects of meteoric economic boom and depressing economic collapse. If they created the flexible safety net (like Brazil) to brace the fall of the boom then the consequences of devaluation and recession would not have been as horrific. In reality, these reforms were impossible in Argentina though. A politician is as good as his first step it seems, or at least the political environment has constructed a pathos in which politicians feel better hedged by “going for broke” then trying to explain the necessity of short-term sacrifice and conflicting reforms. The power structure, from the federal to provincial level, 34
  • 35. illustrates this. The fracture of government structure and patronage within each level of power means that someone will always scratch the populations‟ itch at the expense of stable and long lasting reform. The crisis also begs investors to be responsible, in the sense that they need to pay attention to politics. Not until the election of 1999 did investor confidence really start to plummet. In hindsight, this economy never stood a chance in the political environment. To flood an economy with investment and then remove your investment due to factors that analysis could have foreseen is immoral and irresponsible. The market is beginning to react to this problem. The Eurasia Group, one of the most successful political risk consulting groups in the world, saw its profits rise $7 million dollars from 2001 to 2002. In May of 2003, they were projecting a possible 100% increase in profits from 2002, which would leave them with $30 million by the end of 2003 if predicted correctly. A 2000 Business Week article touted the group‟s growth to 15 full-time employees. There are currently more than 15 people on the advisory board and as of May 2003 there were 520 employees affiliated in Eurasia Group‟s network. Not to mention the company has been expanding through mergers and acquisitions of smaller political risk consulting companies. The results of investing in a political structure, along with an economic structure are yet to be revealed. But the facts point towards 21st Century capital decisions as being something more than an economic decision, but a political decision as well. The international economy has tied these two factors closer together than ever before. When economic calculations become political calculations then the politics of instability take 35
  • 36. root, and Argentina showed the devastation that could occur when politics dominates the union of these two spheres. 36
  • 37. Works Cited Barraclough, Colin. (2002, August 19). “That Sinking Feeling”. Newsweek Atlantic Edition 28-30. Retrieved from LexisNexis. Blake, Charles H. (1998) “Economic Reform and Democratization in Argentina and Uruguay: The Tortoise and the Hare Revisited?”. Journal of Interamerican Studies and World Affairs, Vol. 40, No. 3 1-26. Cavallo, Domingo F. and Cottani, Joaquin A. (1997). “Argentina‟s Convertibility Plan and the IMF”. The American Economic Review, Vol. 87, No.2, 17-22 Corrales, Javier. (2002) “The Politics of Argentina‟s Meltdown” World Policy Journal, Vol. XIX, No.3, Fall 2002 Retrieved from: http://www.worldpolicy.org/journal/articles/wpj02-3/corrales.html De Albuquerque, Roberto Chacon (2000) “Legal Responses to the Fiscal Crisis in Brazil”. St. Louis-Warsaw Transatlantic Law Journal, St. Louis University School of Law. 163-173 The Economist (2002, August 10). “Argentina‟s Bottomless Pit”. Retrieved from LexisNexis The Economist (2003, April 5). “Poised for Growth”. Retrieved from LexisNexis The Economist (2003, May 22). “The new Bull-Market”. Retrieved from LexisNexis Edwards, Sebastian. (2002) “The Argentine Debt Crisis of 2001-2002: A Chronology of Some Key Policy Issues”. Retrieved from http://www.anderson.ucla.edu/faculty/sebastian. edwards/Chronology.pdf Faiola, Anthony. (1998, 22 July) “Argentine President Drops Plan to Run Again” Washington Post A26. Retrieved from LexisNexis Gallo, Andres, Stegmann, Juan Pablo, and Steagall, Jeffery W. (2006). “The Role of Political Institutions in the Resolution of Economic Crises: The Case of Argentina 2001–05”, Oxford Development Studies, Vol. 34, No.2, June 2006. 193-214. Genna, Gaspare M. and Hiroi, Taeko (2005). “The Effects of Unequal Size: The Costs and Benefits of Unilateral Action in the Development of MERCOSUR”, Journal of Developing Societies, Vol. 21, 337-355 37
  • 38. Guira, Jorge M. (2001). “Preventing and Containing International Financial Crisis: The Case of Brazil”. Law and Business Review of the Americas, Fall 2001, 481-506 Head, John W. (1999). “The Global Implications of the Asian Financial Crisis: Banking, Economic Integration, and Crisis Management in the New Century”. William Mitchell Law Review, Vol. 25, 939-963 Hornbeck, J.F. (2002, January 31). “The Argentine Financial Crisis: A Chronology of Events”. Congressional Research Service Report for Congress. Hudson, Peter (1999). “Menem‟s Argentina: An Economic Miracle or Quick Fix?”. The Washington Quarterly, Autumn 1999, 175-180 Hudson, Peter and Margolis, Mac. (2001, July 23) “Argentina‟s Pain”. Newsweek. 24-27 Retrieved from LexisNexis Latin Finance. (2002, November) “Frontnotes”, 6. Retrieved from LexisNexis Lloyd’s List. (2001, July 5). “Argentina reaches breaking point”. 7-9. Retrieved from LexisNexis. Makuc, Adrian Jorge. (2002). “Argentina‟s Efforts at Financial Recovery and Impacts of the Crisis on MERCOSUR and FTAA Talks”. Florida Journal of International Law, Fall 2002, Vol.15, 69-79 Rezk, Ernesto. (2002, April 10) “Fiscal Federalism in Argentina” Retrieved from http://www.forumfed.org/en/libdocs/FedMerco02/116-FEME0206-ar-Rezk.pdf Rezk, Ernesto. (2000, November 21) “Federalism and Decentralization Under Convertibility: Lessons from the Argentine Experience”. Retrieved from http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/seminar/2000/fiscal/rezk.pdf Salmon, Felix (2003, March) “An Uneasy Recovery”. Euromoney. Retrieved from LexisNexis. Taylor, Robert. (1998, June 1) “Argentina: Sounds Like a Slowdown: Argentina‟s explosive economy survived the Asian Financial Crisis, but there are signs that the worrying rates of growth has begun to slow”. The Banker, Vol. 148, No. 868. Retrieved from LexisNexis Teubal, Miguel (2004). “The Rise and Collapse of Neoliberalism in Argentina: The Role of Economic Groups”, Journal of Developing Societies, Vol. 20. 173-188 38
  • 39. Woodruff, David (2005). “Boom, Gloom, Doom: Balance Sheets, Monetary Fragmentation, and the Politics of Financial Crisis in Argentina and Russia”, Politics & Society, Vol. 33 3-45 39