Publicité
Chapter 13A monopolistically competitive market is characterized.docx
Chapter 13A monopolistically competitive market is characterized.docx
Chapter 13A monopolistically competitive market is characterized.docx
Chapter 13A monopolistically competitive market is characterized.docx
Publicité
Chapter 13A monopolistically competitive market is characterized.docx
Chapter 13A monopolistically competitive market is characterized.docx
Chapter 13A monopolistically competitive market is characterized.docx
Chapter 13A monopolistically competitive market is characterized.docx
Chapter 13A monopolistically competitive market is characterized.docx
Publicité
Chapter 13A monopolistically competitive market is characterized.docx
Prochain SlideShare
Chap07Chap07
Chargement dans ... 3
1 sur 10
Publicité

Contenu connexe

Plus de keturahhazelhurst(20)

Publicité

Chapter 13A monopolistically competitive market is characterized.docx

  1. Chapter 13 A monopolistically competitive market is characterized by: · many buyers and sellers, · differentiated products, and · easy entry and exit. The monopolistically competitive market is similar to perfect competition in that there are many buyers and sellers who can enter or leave the market easily in response to economic profits or losses. A monopolistically competitive firm, though, is similar to a monopoly in that it produces a product that is different from that produced by all other firms in the market. The restaurant market in New York City provides a good example of a monopolistically competitive market. Each restaurant has its own recipes, decor, ambiance, etc. but also must compete with many other similar restaurants. Because each firm produces a differentiated product, it won't lose all of its customers if it raises its prices. Thus, a monopolistically competitive firm faces a downward sloping demand curve for its product. As noted in Chapters 8 and 10, whenever a firm faces a downward sloping demand curve, its marginal revenue curve lies below its demand curve. The diagram below illustrates the relationship that exists between a monopolistically competitive firm's demand and marginal revenue curves. While the diagram above seems similar to the demand and marginal revenue curves facing a monopolist, there is a critical difference. In a monopolistically competitive market, the number of firms changes as firms enter or leave the industry. When new firms enter the market, the customers are spread over a larger number of firms and the demand for each firm's product declines. An increase in the number of firms also tends to result in an increase in the elasticity of demand for each firm's products (since demand is more elastic when more substitutes
  2. are available). The diagram below illustrates the shift in a typical firm's demand curve that occurs when additional firms enter a monopolistically competitive market. Short-run and long-run equilibrium in monopolistically competitive markets Let's examine the determination of short-run equilibrium in a monopolistically competitive output market. The diagram below illustrates a possible short-run equilibrium for a typical firm in a monopolistically competitive market. As with any profit-maximizing firm, a monopolistically competitive firm maximizes its profits by producing at a level of output at which MR = MC. In the diagram below, this occurs at an output level of Qo. The price is determined by the amount that customers are willing to pay to buy Qo units of output. In the example below, the demand curve indicates that a price of Po will be charged when Qo units of output are sold. In a monopoly industry, economics profits could persist indefinitely due to the existence of barriers to entry. In a monopolistically competitive industry, however, the existence of economic profits results in the entry of additional firms into the industry. As additional firms enter, the demand for each firm's product will fall and become more elastic. This reduction in demand, though, results in a reduction in the level of economic profit received by a typical firm. Entry into the market continues until a typical firm receives zero economic profits. This possibility is illustrated in the diagram below. The diagram above depicts a monopolistically competitive firm in a state of long-run equilibrium. This firm maximizes its profit by producing an output level of Q'. The equilibrium price is P'. Since the price equals average total cost at this level of output, a typical firm receives a level of economic profit equal to zero. This long-run equilibrium situation is often referred to as a "tangency equilibrium" since the demand curve is tangent
  3. to the ATC curve at the profit-maximizing level of output. In the short run, a monopolistically competitive firm may receive economic losses in the short run. This possibility is illustrated in the diagram below. While each firm will continue operations in the short run, firms will leave the industry in the long run. As firms leave, the demand curves facing the remaining firms will shift to the right and become less elastic. (To see this, note that when firms leave the industry, the remaining firms will receive some of the customers that used to purchase the commodity at the firms that have left the industry.) Exit from the industry will continue until economic profits again equal zero (as illustrated in the diagram below). Monopolistic competition vs. perfect competition As noted in Chapter 10, perfectly competitive markets result in economic efficiency since P = MC and firms produce at the minimum level of ATC. The diagram below compares price and output levels for perfectly competitive and monopolistically competitive firms. As this diagram suggests, a perfectly competitive firm produces output at a price (P pc ) that is less than the price that would be charged by a monopolistically competitive firm (P mc ). A perfectly competitive firm will also produce a larger quantity of output (Q pc ) than would be produced by a monopolistically competitive firm (Q mc ). Because monopolistically competitive firms produce at a level of cost that exceeds the minimum level of ATC, they are less
  4. efficient than perfectly competitive firms. This efficiency loss, however, is a cost that society must bear if it wishes to have differentiated products. One of the costs of having variety in restaurants, clothing, most types of prepared foods, etc., is that average production costs will be higher than they would be if a homogenous product were produced. It should be noted, though, that the larger the number of firms in the market, the more elastic will be the demand for each firm's product. As the number of firms grows very large, the demand curve facing a monopolistically competitive firm will approach the perfectly elastic demand curve that is faced by a perfectly competitive firm. In such a situation, the efficiency cost of product differentiation will be relatively small. In the short run, monopolistically competitive firms may receive economic profits by successfully differentiating their product. Successful product differentiation, however, will soon be copied by other firms. It is expected that such profits will disappear in the long run. Advertising campaigns may raise the profits of a firm in this industry in the short run, but will successful advertising campaigns will lead to similar efforts by other firms in the industry. As your text notes, monopolistically competitive firms in the same industry often locate near each other in communities as a result of their attempts to appeal to the median customer in a geographic region. This is why we often see car dealerships and fast-food restaurants locating near each other on a particular street. Outline I.Oligopoly: An oligopoly is a market structure in which there are very few sellers. Each seller knows the other sellers will react to its changes in prices and quantities. An oligopoly market structure can exist for either a homogeneous or a differentiated product. A. Characteristics of Oligopoly
  5. 1.Small Number of Firms: An oligopoly exists when the few top firms account for an overwhelming percentage of total industry output. 2.Interdependence: This is also called strategic dependence, which is a situation in which one firm’s actions with respect to output, price, quality, advertising, and related changes may be strategically countered by one or more other firms in the industry. Such dependence can only exist when there are a few major firms in an industry. B. Why Oligopoly Occurs 1.Economies of Scale: The strongest reason that has been offered for the existence of oligopoly is economies of scale. Economies of scale are defined as a production situation in which a doubling of output results in less than a doubling of total costs. The firm’s average total cost curve will slope downward as it produces more and more output. Average total cost can be reduced by continuing to expand the scale of operation. 2.Barriers to Entry: These barriers include legal barriers, such as patents, and control and ownership over critical supplies. 3.Oligopoly by Merger: A merger is the joining of two of more firms under a single ownership or control. There are two types of mergers. A horizontal merger involves firms producing or selling a similar product. A vertical merger occurs when one firm merges with another from which it purchases an input or to which it sells an output. II.Measuring Industry Concentration A.Concentration Ratio: The percentage of all sales contributed by the leading four or leading eight firms in an industry: sometimes called the industry concentration ratio. The concept of an industry is necessarily arbitrary. As a consequence, concentration ratios rise as we narrow the definition of an industry and fall as we broaden it. (See Table 26-1 and Table 26-2.) B. The Herfindahl-Hirschman Index: 1. Limitation of the Centration Ratio: Concentration ratios
  6. fail to reflect differences in the relative sizes of firms within an industry. (See Table 26-3.) 2. Defining and Computing the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index: The sum of the squared percentage sales shares of all firms in an industry. (See Table 26-3.) III.Strategic Behavior and Game Theory: When there are relatively few firms in an industry, each reacts to the price, quantity, quality, and new product innovations that the others undertake. Each oligopolist has a reaction function, which is the manner in which one oligopolist reacts to a change in price (or output or quality) of another oligopolist. Game theory is the analytical framework in which two or more individuals, companies, or nations compete for certain payoffs that depend on the strategy that the others employ. The plans made by these individuals are known as game strategies. A. Some Basic Notions about Game Theory: Games can be cooperative or noncooperative. They are classified by whether the payoffs are negative, zero, or positive. A cooperative game is one in which players explicitly collude to make themselves better off. With firms, it involves companies colluding in order to make higher than competitive rates of return. A noncooperative game is a game in which players neither collude nor negotiate in any way. Applied to firms, it is a situation in which there are few firms and each firm has some ability to change price. A zero-sum game is a game in which one player’s losses are exactly offset by the other player’s gains. A negative- sum game is a game in which both players are worse off at the end of the game. A positive-sum game is a game in which both players are better off at the end of the game. 1.Strategies in Noncooperative Games: A strategy is any rule that is used to make a choice, e.g., always pick heads. The goal is to devise a dominant strategy. A dominant strategy will yield the highest benefit for the player using it. These strategies are generally successful no matter what actions other players take. B.The Prisoner’s Dilemma: An example of game theory in which two people involved in a bank robbery are caught.
  7. 1. The Structure of the Prisoner’s Dilemma: The payoff matrix shows two possibilities for each of the two prisoners: “confess” and “don’t confess.” (See Figure 26-1.) 2. The Predicted Prisoner’s Dilemma Outcomes: To confess is a dominant strategy for each of the two prisoners. This is a dilemma because the prisoners know that both of them will be better off if nether confesses. (See Figure 26-1.) C.Applying Game Theory to Pricing Strategies: An example of the use of game theory is presented. (See Figure 26-2.) D.Opportunistic Behavior: Actions that ignore possible long-run benefits of cooperation and focus solely on short-run gains. This kind of behavior can be contrasted to tit-for-tat strategic behavior when repeat transactions are likely. Here, a player will behave well as long as others do likewise. IV.The Cooperative Game: A Collusive Cartel: This section looks at why firms collude to increase prices, how they work to do so, and what they have to do to be successful. A.Collusive Production and Pricing and the Seeds of a Cartel’s Undoing: Firms in an industry must collude if they decide to form a cartel so that they can achieve the same outcome as a monopoly and increase their profits above a competitive level. 1. Collusive Price and Output Determination by Firms in a Cartel: To operate a profit-maximizing cartel, member firms must be willing and able to set up and maintain an arrangement for coordinating overall cartel production at a common price. Then they can share the maximized profits. (See Figure 26-3.) a. The Pre-Cartel, Noncoordinated Market: In the absence of collusion among firms, the market clearing price in the long-run equilibrium equals the firm’s minimum average total cost. (See Figure 26-3 (a).) b. Boosting Economic Profits via a Collusive Cartel Price: If firms in the market form a joint cartel enterprise, they coordinate their production and regard the sum of their marginal costs as the overall marginal cost of the cartel. All firms will agree to charge the price at which the market marginal revenue
  8. equals the cartel’s overall marginal cost. (See Figure 26-3 (b).) c.Profit-Maximizing Collusion Requires Reducing Total Production: The cartel production is lower than output under perfect competition. Firms thereby will raise its economic profits from zero under perfect competition to a positive amount. (See Figure 26-3.) 2. The Temptation to Cheat on a Cartel Agreement: Any one member of the cartel can increase its total own revenues and profits by lowering price slightly as long as all of the other firms in the cartel honor their agreement to reduce production. B. Enforcing a Cartel Agreement: There are four conditions that make it more likely that firms will be able to coordinate their efforts to restrain output successfully and deter cheating. 1. A Small Number of Firms in the Industry: The smaller the number of firms in the industry, the easier it is to prevent cheating. 2. Relatively Undifferentiated Products: If the cartel members sell a homogeneous or nearly homogeneous product, it is easier for them to agree on how much each firm should reduce production. 3.Easily Observable Prices: If the terms of industry transactions are publically available, cartel members can more readily observe a firm’s efforts to cheat. 4. Little Variations in Prices: Stable demand and cost conditions help a cartel form and continue to operate effectively. C.Why Cartel Agreements Usually Break Down: Most cartels usually do not last for more than 10 years. Monopoly profits attract new entrants to the industry, and price falls. In addition, downturns in overall economic activity cause the cartel’s demand and thus the demand for all member firms to decrease. This increases the incentive to cheat on the cartel agreement. V.Network Effects and Two-Sided Markets: A network effect is a situation in which a consumer’s willingness to purchase a good or service is influenced by how many others also buy or
  9. have bought the item. A.Network Effects and Market Feedback: Industries in which network effects are important can experience sudden surges in growth as well as significant and sudden reversals. 1.Positive Market Feedback: A tendency for a good or service to come into favor with additional consumers because other consumers have chosen to buy them. 2. Negative Market Feedback: A tendency for a good or service to fall out of favor with more consumers because other consumers have stopped purchasing the item. B.Network Effects and Industry Concentration: In an industry that produces and sells products subject to network effects, oligopoly is likely to emerge. The reason is that in an industry that sells differentiated products subject to network effects, when the products of a few firms catch on, these will capture the bulk of the sales of the industry. C. Two-Sided Markets, Network Effects, and Oligopoly: A two-sided market is a market in which an intermediary firm provides services that link groups of producers and consumers. 1.Types of Two-Sided Markets: In a two-sided market, the intermediary firm is a platform and the groups of producers and consumers are end users. (See Figure 26-4.) a.Audience Seeking Markets: Media platforms link advertisers to audiences. b. Matchmaking Markets: Platform firms, such as real estate agents and online dating firms, bring end users together. c. Transaction-based Markets: Banks, credit- and debit-card companies are platforms that finalize transactions between retailers and card holders. d. Shared-Input Markets: Groups of end users utilize a key input obtained from a platform. 2.Network Effects in Two-Sided Markets: Network effects are a common feature of two-sided markets. Groups of end users benefit from the network effects in different types of two-sided markets. 3.Two-Sided Oligopolistic Pricing: Oligopoly is the most
  10. common industry structure in two-sided markets with network effects. In these markets, a few firms are often able to capture most of the payoffs associated with market feedback. In a two- sided market, platform firms that set prices must consider group differences in network effects. In some two-sided markets, platform firms maximize profits by charging an explicit price of zero or even negative prices, or subsidies, for one group of end users. D. Comparing Market Structures: Market structures are compared in Table 26-4.
Publicité