SlideShare une entreprise Scribd logo
1  sur  31
Télécharger pour lire hors ligne
Jameson 1
Shifting the Understanding of Revolving
Door Lobbyists
John Jameson
University of Massachusetts Amherst
Abstract: The revolving door, defined as the exchange of personnel between a
regulator and the regulated industry, is both under-studied and engulfed in excessive
speculation. To combat this, I constructed a database of the revolving door connections
held by in-house lobbyists active in four unique sectors of the economy: finance, energy,
pharmaceuticals, and telecommunications. After constructing revolving door ratios for
each lobbyist, I compare different levels of revolving door “contamination” across
sectors. I also compare the contaminated ratios of the top 20 organizations and the
smaller remaining organizations from each sector. Larger organizations have more
resources at their disposal to attract top talent. Therefore, large organizations should be
more contaminated than small organizations, as the connections gained from the
revolving door are highly sought after by the firms and organizations that hire lobbyists.
Yet my findings show that the larger firms are not more contaminated than the smaller
firms, which indicates that our current understanding of the revolving door lacks
necessary complexity. Upon examining the common sources of contamination for each
sector, I am able to conclude that organizations do not blindly seek lobbyists with any
revolving door connections, but instead favor lobbyists with connections in areas
deemed key to a sector’s prosperity.
Jameson 2
Introduction
The revolving door, or the exchange of workers between a regulated industry and
its regulator, is an under-studied yet widely discussed phenomenon of modern
regulatory policymaking. News outlets1
and political pundits denigrate the revolving door
as another tool to be used by corporations to get their way. Some cite it as an example
of a wealthy ruling elite that can travel freely between corporate boardrooms and
regulatory agencies. And yet others insist that the revolving door facilitates better
policymaking by including private sector expertise into the debate over complicated
regulations. Some blame the revolving door for facilitating a lax regulatory climate that
lead to the 2008 global financial crisis, stating that the revolving door runs rampant
among lawmakers. Without further study, the revolving door will remain ambiguous and
misunderstood. This project seeks to fill in portions of our knowledge about the revolving
door and add to the existing literature. I examine the revolving door as it pertains to
lobbyists; I have constructed a database containing employment history data on over
three thousand lobbyists, which I will use to examine the scope of revolving door
contamination as it relates to lobbyists and certain sectors of the economy. I will add
nuance to our understanding of how revolving door connections are valued, and by
whom they are valued. This paper will begin with an examination of the existing
literature on the revolving door, and will then proceed to a description of the ins and outs
of my data. I will then present my findings before finally stating conclusions drawn from
the data.
Background Literature
In 1979, Gormley (Gormley 1979) performed the first in-depth examination of the
revolving door. He studied the impact of private sector working experience on regulators
at the United States Federal Communications Commission (henceforth the FCC). To
1 1
The New York Times, for example, features stories on the revolving door so often
that they have created a category for it on a section of their website:
http://dealbook.nytimes.com/category/series/revolving-door/
2
This may at first seem counter-intuitive but Gormley considered the “broadcast
Jameson 3
test the revolving door hypothesis, Gormley gathered non-unanimous voting data on
rule creation, rule changes, notices of inquiries, and other decisions from FCC
commissioners from 1974 to 1976. His information is accurate – he gathered them from
the minutes of FCC meetings. In that two-year period, there was no turnover of
commissioners; Gormley also gathered the occupational history of all seven FCC
commissioners, so he could determine who had worked in the industry (broadcasting)
and who had not. To test the effect of the revolving door, he applied bloc analysis and
Guttman scaling. Bloc analysis tests for voting blocs, the theory being that former
broadcasters would be like-minded and therefore vote concurrently. Guttman scaling
requires Gormley to characterize votes as having a political direction (whether the vote
is pro- or anti-broadcasting); this allows him to test the effect of individual values held by
commissioners, and attribute voting patterns to characteristics like political party
affiliation (Republican or Democrat) or previous employment within the regulated
industry. Using all of the votes undertaken at the FCC, the results from the bloc analysis
do not confirm the revolving door hypothesis. In other words, the two commissioners
who were former broadcasters did not tend to vote in a bloc on all issues put to a vote at
the FCC. But, the results change when the scope is narrowed by using only the votes
that apply specifically to broadcasting, showing that the two revolving door FCC
commissioners form a voting bloc with two other (non revolving door) FCC
commissioners. In fact, each revolving door commissioner voted more similarly with a
non revolving door commissioner than they did with each other. Therefore, according to
Gormley, this outcome partially supports the revolving door hypothesis. Yet the inclusion
of two additional (non revolving door) commissioners in the voting bloc suggests that
there may be other factors influencing regulator votes other than the revolving door.
Support for the revolving door does not stop there: using Guttman scaling, Gormley
found that the two former broadcasters to be more likely to support the broadcasting
industry’s position than other commissioners. Applying Guttman scaling forced Gormley
to Identify three subsets of votes where the position of the broadcasting industry was
clear: broadcast license renewals, broadcast program content regulation, and cable
television. A commissioner was considered “pro-broadcasting” if their vote coincided
Jameson 4
with the wishes of the broadcasting industry within the three subsets. Specifically, a
commissioner was pro-broadcasting if they: 1) voted to support the renewal of an
organization’s license in spite of complaints or abuses, 2) voted to loosen program
content restriction and regulation, and 3) voted in a direction that was unfavorable to the
cable television industry or to a specific cable operator2
. In all three areas, the two FCC
commissioners that were former broadcasters were more likely to support the
broadcasting industry’s position, thus providing support for the revolving door
hypothesis. Yet Gormley notes two points: the former broadcasters only narrowly
supported broadcasting against cable television (53.2% of the time), and the differences
between the “pro” commissioners and the rest of the commissioners are enhanced by
the fact that Gormley is only counting non-unanimous votes. Additionally, he found that
party identification predicted vote behavior better than occupational background3
.
Nonetheless, this does not detract from Gormley’s revolving door findings: it has been
long established that political party affiliations play a role in regulatory policymaking, but
the impact of prior employment is less known. The main takeaway from Gormley’s
research is that the revolving door has some kind of effect on regulation, as work history
in broadcasting caused FCC commissioners to be more accepting of the interests of the
industry but the full effects are ambiguous, as other factors like political party also have
a strong effect on support for broadcasting industry positions.
Cohen (Cohen 1986) advances Gormley’s FCC revolving door work further by
expanding the dataset and including more nuanced measures of the effect of the
revolving door. He expanded the dataset beyond two years by gathering voting records
on non-unanimous FCC votes from 1955 to 1974, which included votes from 28
commissioners (increased from Gormley’s seven). Mirroring Gormley, Cohen also
considered all votes as a decision that did or did not support the broadcasting industry
position. Cohen moves one step beyond Gormley by gathering more in-depth data on
2
This may at first seem counter-intuitive but Gormley considered the “broadcast
industry” to be just organizations transmitting via radio, whose direct competitor would
therefore be cable television.
3
Republican commissioners were much more likely than Democratic commissioners to
support the broadcasting industry in all three aforementioned areas.
Jameson 5
specific characteristics about each commissioner, including both pre- and post-FCC
employment data instead of just pre-FCC employment data. This new data coupled with
his larger sample of commissioners allowed him to include controls to better understand
the factors that affect a regulator’s support of the broadcasting industry. Cohen
recognizes that there are two sides of the revolving door: the “entrance” side and the
“exit” side. On the one hand, the “entrance” side suggests that regulators that come
from the regulated industry are more likely to support that industry as a regulator.
According to Cohen, the “exit” side suggests, on the other hand, that the lure of a
lucrative job in the industry after spending time as a regulator will lead the regulator to
support the industry4
. Cohen designed his study based on his database containing
2,064 votes from 20-year period. From this set, he randomly sampled 10 votes from
each year to compare, which allows for more complete and even assessment of
commissioner behavior as the earlier years had fewer votes than the later years. Similar
to Gormley, Cohen scored the votes of each commissioner on a binary scale: 1
representing industry support, 0 representing nonsupport. He also maintains Gormley’s
scoring criteria: pro-broadcasting votes support license renewal, loosen content
restrictions, and go against the cable industry. Cohen once again expands on Gormley’s
data by collecting pre- and post-employment data from the FCC, the Who’s Who series,
and The New York Times. Cohen creates four hypotheses total, which are broken
evenly into two types: temporal and revolving door. Cohen’s four hypotheses (from p.
693-695):
Hypothesis 1: FCC Commissioners previously employed in the regulated
industry will be more supportive of the broadcast industry.
Hypothesis 2: In their first year, FCC commissioners with industry experience
will support the broadcast industry more than those without industry experience,
but by the second year, the difference in industry support will narrow
4
It is worth noting that Cohen cites a lack of empirical support for the exit hypothesis –
Eckert (Eckert 1981) reports that only 20% of regulators find direct employment in the
regulated industry and Quirk (Quirk 2014) finds (via interviews) that regulators do not
feel like their level of support will affect their chances at a job in the industry.
Jameson 6
Hypothesis 3: Regulators employed in the regulated industry after their term in
office ends will be more supportive of the regulated industry while in office than
those who do not secure such employment.
Hypothesis 4: In a commissioner’s last year on a regulatory body, the
commissioner’s support for the regulated industry will increase.
Cohen’s “entrance” hypothesis results are clear: regulator prior experience plays a role
in industry support, thus confirming the revolving door hypothesis. Commissioners with
prior experience in the broadcasting industry are 14% more supportive of the industry
than commissioners without that experience. Also, post-FCC broadcast employment
impacts commissioner support of industry, but in the opposite direction that Cohen
would lead one to assume: commissioners that secure industry jobs post-FCC are less
supportive (more stringent) of the industry during their term than commissioners who do
not secure industry jobs. Further, commissioners in their last year of employment at the
FCC seem to posture to increase their attractiveness to the industry: final year
commissioners increased their industry support by 11%. Strangely, the final year
posturing effect is more pronounced for those hired by the industry than those who are
not: those who would go on to get hired were supportive 63.9% of the time in their final
year, whereas those who did not go on to get hired were supportive 51.9% of the time.
These last two findings paint a strange picture: for a regulator to be an ideal candidate
for hire by the industry, they should spend almost their entire career against the
industry, except the last year where they should begin to support the industry more.
Using the variables based on the aforementioned hypotheses, Cohen finds that only
three variables are statistically significant: pre-FCC industry employment, post-FCC
industry employment, and last year on the FCC. He then makes his results more
rigorous by including controls for other explanations for his outcomes. He controls for
political party, geographically linked ideology, presidential impacts, and congressional
impacts, and finds that including the control variables changes the outcome of
significant variables. The significant variables now include: post-FCC employment, last
Jameson 7
year on the FCC, and the party of the appointing president.5
This is a large shift – the
pre-FCC employment variable is replaced entirely by the presidential party variable
because Democratic presidents in the dataset did not appoint a single commissioner
with previous broadcast experience. The main takeaway from Cohen’s study is that
more studies of the revolving door are needed in other areas in order to make broad
statements about regulatory agency decision-making. The revolving door may not have
an extremely large influence on FCC decisions, but this conclusion is far from the idea
that the revolving door is irrelevant or inapplicable to regulatory policymaking. It is
possible that the FCC is uniquely influenced by presidential appointments (the control
variable that replaced the “entrance” revolving door variable), as the selection of FCC
commissioners is not a politically salient issue when compared to selection of Federal
Reserve Chairmen or the heads of other major regulatory agencies.
The Revolving Door is often cited as a mechanism that influences lawmaking and
regulatory policymaking. Some, like Baker (Baker 2010), contend that the revolving door
increases the influence of private sector actors, which leads to regulatory capture (when
combined with other factors). Baker emphasizes his notion of regulatory capture in the
through four causal mechanisms: lobbying, the degree of political salience, institutional
design/revolving doors, and intellectual capture. In financial regulation, Baker points to
the revolving door between private banks like Goldman Sachs to regulatory agencies,
like the United States Treasury (the Treasury) or the Federal Reserve Bank of the
United States (the Fed). Baker specifically mentions the presence of a “Wall Street –
Washington” corridor, referring to the frequent movement of executives back and fourth
between the two areas. This exchange of workers, according to Baker, can have a
colonizing effect on regulatory agencies and can provide dysfunctional incentive
structures for regulators. Baker cites a piece by Makkai and Braithwaite (Makkai and
Braithwaite 1992) who contend that regulators are encouraged to pass industry-friendly
regulations through implicit promises of future careers in the industry, but support for
that idea in general is shaky at best as shown in part by the aforementioned piece by
5
‘Conservative coalition’ vote success in the House is also statistically significant, but
Cohen states that, “This result may be spurious” (p. 703).
Jameson 8
Cohen. Baker cites Johnson’s (Johnson 2009) work detailing how the flow of
professionals from the public to private sector allows for the formation of a belief
system. This belief system idea, sometimes referred to as financialization, contends that
what is good for Wall Street will also be good for the US (like large financial institutions
and freer capital markets) which according to Baker, causes overly lenient regulations.
Baker’s piece is useful insofar that it succinctly summarizes possible reasons for
concern surrounding the revolving door.
Blanes i Vidal, Draca, and Fons-Rosen (Vidal, Draca, and Fons-Rosen 2012)
study the impact of the revolving door on the careers of congressional staffers turned
lobbyists. They note the direct connection between revenue production from former
staffers and the politicians for whom they previously served – they find that on average,
lobbyists connected to a US senator suffers a 24% drop in generated revenue when
their previous employer leaves the Senate. This effect is stronger for lobbyists who
previously served under a congressman on an important committee6
. Blanes i Vidal et
al. note that the connection between revenue generation and a lobbyist’s former boss is
stronger for those that served in the Senate – being connected to a serving senator is
associated with 23% higher revenue, whereas connection to a serving representative is
only associated with 9% higher revenue generation. There is also evidence that ex-
staffers are less likely to work in the lobbying industry after their connected senators exit
Congress – being connected to a serving senator is associated with 27% higher
likelihood of working as a lobbyist. Blanes i Vidal et al. provide crucial empirical
evidence of the value of personal (revolving door) connections in the lobbying industry.
These personal connections allow the lobbyists with them to be more effective (as they
are generating more revenue) when certain politicians are in power. This piece of
information is crucial to understanding how the revolving door works for financial
regulation.
McKay (McKay 2012) examines the role of money in lobbying and influencing
policy outcomes. She wants to know how money affects policymaking – does more
6
Vidal et al. consider the Senate Finance and Appropriations Committee and House
Ways and Means Committee important congressional committees.
Jameson 9
money mean more lobbying success? Specifically, do wealthier groups achieve more
lobbying success than less wealthy groups? To answer this question, McKay combines
data on lobbyist resources and policy outcomes with existing data from interviews with
lobbyists conducted from 1977-1982. She finds that financial wealth has little to do with
a group’s policy success; what is far more important, is how the group spends the
money. Spending money on increasing lobbying intensity (measured via more time
spent in Washington DC, more lobbyists working on an issue, etc.) is correlated with
greater lobbying success. She also states that experienced lobbyists with prior
connections are a factor in more successful lobbying – these connections and
experience can be acquired through the revolving door. But greater financial wealth
does not always lead to greater lobbying intensity. The main takeaway from McKay,
with respect to studying the revolving door, is that money alone does not buy lobbying
success, but how money is spent does affect a group’s ability to influence policy.
Reading in between the lines, McKay insinuates that spending money to increase
lobbying intensity for lobbyists with experience and connections on Capitol Hill
(revolving door lobbyists) is the best way to affect policy change.
The revolving door does not only impact regulations – the private sector is also
affected by the revolving door. Shive and Forster (Shive and Forster 2013) study these
private sector impacts. They compile a dataset of regulators from any of the six financial
regulatory institutions: the Federal Reserve (Fed), the Securities and Exchange
Commission (SEC), the Financial Industry Regulatory Authority (FINRA), the
Commodity Futures Trading Commission (CFTC), the Office of the Comptroller of the
Currency (OCC), and the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC). Shive and
Forster focus on regulators that leave their institution through the revolving door to work
at a private firm. Their findings are crucial: firms that hire revolving door regulators see a
positive 0.9% return on hiring announcement day, and their stock volatility is 5% lower
in the quarter following the revolving door hire. Financial firms are also twice as likely to
hire a regulator from the body that directly regulates it. In other words, private firms
become more profitable and more stable when they hire a revolving door regulator, and
these firms seek out workers that previously regulated them. Shive and Forster find that
Jameson 10
the most consistent determinant of hire by a financial firm is the revolving-door
employee’s length of employment at the regulator – in other words, more experienced
and presumably connected regulators are more desirable to firms. This information is
crucial to our understanding of the revolving door: it establishes quantifiable ways in
which private firms benefit from the revolving door.
Research Methods
The data for this project was compiled from the subscription-based online
lobbying database lobbyists.info7
. The website contains information on over 28,000
federal lobbyists, over 2,400 lobbying firms, and over 12,000 corporations and
associations. The data can be accessed in a number of ways: one can search for
lobbyists by bill or bill sponsor, by legislative area, or by the industry in which a lobbyist
is active. The lobbyist information in the database is segregated; when one searches for
lobbyists by the aforementioned methods, the results only include in-house lobbyists,
not lobbyists employed by lobbying firms. There is an option for searching for lobbying
firm lobbyists, but it is separate from the main searches. I gathered the lobbying data
manually8
, so the project moved slowly. I gathered the lobbyists’ name, the organization
that he or she lobbied on behalf of, the sector they were found in, and their professional
employment experience (if listed). Lobbyists.info is not a comprehensive source for
employment history – there are many lobbyists that list their name and organization
only. In the interest of brevity, I could not gather background information on every single
lobbyist in the database. I reduced the size of the sample in two ways: first, I only
gathered data on in-house lobbyists, and second I only searched for lobbyists active in
one of four sectors of the economy. The four sectors are: finance, energy,
pharmaceuticals, and telecommunications. I am mainly interested in financial sector
7
www.lobbyists.info
8
I would enter the data displayed on the website into a separate excel spreadsheet
organization-by-organization, lobbyist-by-lobbyist.
Jameson 11
lobbyists, but in order for my study to be broadly applicable and to accurately represent
the greater lobbying industry, additional and diverse sectors are required. These four
sectors are distinct, representing different sections of the economy, although they share
certain features. The energy industry, like the financial industry, is important to the
health and functioning of the rest of the larger economy, as economic productivity
requires both capital and energy. The pharmaceutical industry, like the financial
industry, is very seriously complex. The science behind cutting-edge medicines and
research is beyond the scope of the average person, similar to the complexity and scale
of modern financial instruments and derivatives. The telecommunications industry is
similar to finance in that it generates an enormous amount of revenue, yet it is
concentrated in a relatively small number of firms9
. These similarities will allow me to
draw relative conclusions about revolving door lobbyists across sectors.
It is important to acknowledge both the strengths and limitations of my data. The
lobbyists.info website allows one to search for industry-specific lobbyists based on a
large number of vague, pre-defined search terms. Please see Figure 1 for a description
of the search terms used in this study with their corresponding sector.
9
According to the US Census Bureau, in 1992 roughly the top 7% of cable and
broadcasting companies (ranked by revenue) were responsible for over 70% of the
sector’s total revenue (United States Census Bureau 1992). The story is similar for
finance: the top 1.8% of Securities Industry companies are responsible for over 58% of
the sector’s total revenue (United States Census Bureau 1992).
Jameson 12
Figure 1 – Sector Search Terms
When the website is queried using these sector keywords, only organizations and
associations are returned as results. Therefore, it is important to stress that my data
only contains information on in-house lobbyists, not lobbying firms. Each
organization/association had workers listed in one of two separate tabs: in-house
government relations personnel and other key personnel. I gathered my lobbyist info
from the in-house government relations personnel tab only – the “other key personnel”
tab listed people in leadership positions like CEO, CFO, CLO, etc. who are obviously
not involved in the day to day activities of lobbyists and are therefore outside the scope
of this project. On my first round of data gathering I only collected information on
lobbyists that had background data – I did not gather information (names, organizations,
sector, etc.) on lobbyists without professional working experience listed on
lobbyists.info. But information on the lobbyists without listed working experience is
important also – it weights the data I was able to gather on lobbyists with background
information and allows for a more complete picture of the revolving door lobbyists’
universe. Thankfully, lobbyists.info has a bulk download feature that will gather the
Finance Energy Pharmaceuticals Telecommunications
Banking/credit-&-
finance/savings-&-
loan Energy
Pharmaceutical-
Industry
Telecommunications/Inter
net/Cable
Banking/finance/inv
estments
Energy/elect
ricity Pharmacology
Investments/securit
ies-industry Coal
Gas
Gasoline
Nuclear-
Energy
Petroleum-
Industry
Fuels-see-
coal,-gas,-oil,-
petroleum
Jameson 13
names and organizations of lobbyists listed by sector. Working backgrounds are not
included in the bulk download, but they are not needed in my case because I have the
working history of every lobbyist listed in the sectors already. However, bulk
downloading is not a perfect solution: it is impossible to differentiate which “tab”
someone belongs to (the “in-house government relations personnel” or the “other key
personnel” tab) when a bulk download is performed. In the bulk download spreadsheet
there is a binary variable representing the Lobbying Disclosure Act (LDA) – a “Y”
signifies that the information provided for that lobbyist was gleaned from an LDA, and an
“N” signifies that the information provided was gotten from elsewhere. The Lobbying
Disclosure Act mandates that lobbyists provide their contact information, their client’s
contact information, and a statement about the general issue area that they will be
lobbying on to the Clerk of the House of Representatives and the Secretary of the
Senate. The LDA is mandatory for all in-house lobbying efforts costing more than
$12,500 per economic quarter, therefore most people with a “Y” in the LDA column are
also listed on the lobbyists.info site under the “in-house government relations personnel”
tab. But unfortunately, not everyone listed under the “in-house government relations
personnel” tab disclosed his or her information via an LDA. It is impossible to tell how
the lobbyists.info site categorizes someone as a lobbyist who did not disclose their
information via an LDA. This makes it impossible for me to get the optimal sample of
people: only lobbyists, or those listed as “in-house government relations personnel”.
This is less than preferred, but is not excessively detrimental to the validity of my data.
In order to account for these differences, I deploy sector-based measures of the
revolving door using three different “weighting” groups of lobbyists: 1) just the lobbyists
that had background information (the “information group”), 2) the same as the first group
with the addition of all bulk downloaded lobbyists that disclosed via an LDA (the “LDA
group”), and 3) all personnel listed on the lobbyists.info site which includes non-
lobbyists from the “other key personnel” tab (the “all group). I also compare revolving
door contamination measures of the top 20 largest firms (ranked by their number of in-
house lobbyists) against the rest of the sector across all three weighting groups. It is
worth noting that my data does not capture the comprehensive working background of
Jameson 14
every currently active lobbyist – the lobbyists.info site, and therefore also my data, is
reliant upon the disclosure of lobbyist data via LDAs, interviews, or public online
profiles10
. Obviously, it would be best if my data included the background of every active
lobbyist, but that is currently unfeasible and unrealistic.
This study focuses on the revolving door, or the exchange of professionals
between the regulated industry and their regulator. Therefore, the working history of the
3,544 lobbyists in my data is not useful in the raw – certain jobs represent
“contamination” via the revolving door, and certain jobs do not. In order for the data to
reflect that, I must categorize some jobs as representing “contamination”. First, I coded
the job of every lobbyist into one of the following broad categories (please see Figure 2).
Figure 2 – Coding Categories
10
LinkedIn profiles were common. Also, many organizations have small bios of their
executive level staff on their websites – usually including a picture and professional
working experience.
House Senate International Judicial
Gov't4Agency Interest4Group Military Political4Party
Firm Lobbyist PR4Firm State4Gov't
Campaign Consulting University White4House
Other
Jameson 15
Then, I coded each category into one of two groups: private sector or public sector.
After that, I broke down the public sector jobs further, many of which are in the following
categories: State Gov’t, the White House, Gov’t Agency, Senate, or House. In order to
establish a measure of revolving door “contamination”, I coded each job as directly
relevant to one of my four sectors, if applicable. A job is directly relevant to a sector if it
had regulatory power over that sector. Lobbyists that have worked these jobs are
considered “contaminated” by the revolving door. The State Gov’t jobs11
are irrelevant
for the purposes of a federal lobbyist, as none of these jobs are directly germane to one
of the four sectors. Therefore, no State Gov’t jobs are considered contaminated. Many
of the White House positions are also too general to classify as relevant to finance,
energy, pharmaceuticals, or telecommunications12
. The remaining jobs in the House of
Representatives, the Senate, and Government Agencies were all coded with respect to
the four sectors. Specifically, if a government agency were a regulator responsible for
one of the four industries (like the Securities and Exchange Commission and finance), it
would be coded as contaminated for that industry. Many lobbyists were previously
staffers for elected officials in the Senate and House – I treated these jobs as
contaminated if the elected official held a position on a committee relevant to the
industry that the staffer would later go on to lobby in. For example, if a staffer’s
congressperson is a member of the House Financial Services committee, that staffer
would be revolving door “contaminated” for the financial sector. Please see Figure 3 for
an explanation of how each committee was coded, and why they were coded that way.
11
These consisted almost entirely of tenure in state legislatures.
12
Many had vague titles like “Senior White House Staff” or “Senior White House
Legislative Correspondent”
Jameson 16
Figure 3 – Congressional Committee Coding
Committee Coded(As Justification
House&Committee&on&Energy&and&
Commerce
Pharma,&Energy,&
Telecom
Jurisdiction&over&the&EPA,&FDA,&and&FCC.&Not&
coded&as&finance,&although&they&do&have&
jurisdiction&over&the&FTC
House&Committee&on&Financial&Services Finance Oversees&the&Fed,&Treasury,&and&SEC
House&Judiciary&Subcommittee&on&
Courts,&Intellectual&Property&and&the&
Internet Telecom
Given&administration&of&information&
technology&matters&&&the&internet
House&Subcommittee&on&Energy&and&
Water&Development,&and&Related&
Agencies Energy
Has&jurisdiction&over&the&budget&for&the&US&
Department&of&Energy.
House&Transportation&Subcommittee&on&
Water&Resources&and&Environment Energy Jurisdiction&over&the&EPA
House&Ways&and&Means&Subcommittee&
on&Health Pharma
Jurisdiction&over&programs&providing&
payments&for&health&care&and&related&things
House&Committee&on&Natural&Resources Energy Jurisdiction&over&energy&agencies
Senate&Appropriations&Subcommittee&on&
Agriculture,&Rural&Development,&Food&
and&Drug&Administration,&and&Related&
Agencies Pharma Jurisdiction&over&the&FDA
Senate&Appropriations&Subcommittee&on&
Energy&and&Water&Development Energy Jurisdiction&over&the&Department&of&Energy
Senate&Appropriations&Subcommittee&on&
Energy&and&Water&Development Energy
Responsible&for&funding&the&Department&of&
Energy,&oversees&the&Nuclear&Regulatory&
Commission
Senate&Appropriations&Subcommittee&on&
Financial&Services&and&General&
Government Finance,&Telecom
Jurisdiction&over&the&discretionary&spending&of&
the&Treasury&Department,&along&with&
oversight&on&the&FDIC,&and&the&FCC
Senate&Commerce&Subcommittee&on&
Communications,&Technology,&
Innovation,&and&the&Internet Telecom
Legislative&oversight&of&communications&
(telephones,&internet,&etc.)
Senate&Committee&on&Agriculture,&
Nutrition,&and&Forestry Pharma
Has&jurisdiction&over&matters&relating&to&
nutrition&and&health
Senate&Committee&on&Banking,&Housing,&
and&Urban&Affairs Finance
Jursidiction&over&matters&related&to&banks&and&
banking
Senate&Committee&on&Commerce,&
Science,&and&Transportation Telecom Legislative&oversight&of&communications
Senate&Committee&on&Energy&and&
Natural&Resources Energy Jurisdiction&over&energy&agencies
Senate&Committee&on&Health,&Education,&
Labor&and&Pensions Pharma
Jurisdiction&over&public&health,&biomedical&
research,&etc.
Senate&Environment&and&Public&Works&
Subcommittee&on&Oversight Energy Jurisdiction&over&the&EPA
Senate&Finance&Committee Finance SelfRexplanatory
Senate&Finance&Subcommittee&on&
Energy,&Natural&Resources,&and&
Infrastructure Energy,&Finance Responsible&for&energy&and&finance&policies
Senate&Finance&Subcommittee&on&Health&
Care Pharma Has&jurisdiction&over&health&care&
Senate&Subcommittee&on&Energy,&
Science,&and&Technology Energy
Has&jurisdiction&over&renewable&energy&
programs&and&energy&efficiency&programs
House&Appropriations&Subcommittee&on&
Labor,&Health&and&Human&Services,&
Education,&and&Related&Agencies Pharma
Jurisdiction&of&the&Department&of&Health&and&
Human&Services
House&Committee&on&Science,&Space&and&
Technology Energy Jurisdiction&over&the&EPA,&DEP,&etc.
Jameson 17
Once every job has been coded, I am able to construct ratios of an individual’s
“contaminated” jobs to their “clean”13
jobs, along with the ratio of non-contaminated
public sector jobs to contaminated jobs for each individual. The “contaminated to clean”
ratio is a good approximation of the revolving door as it compares all the available
information on a lobbyist’s jobs to their number of contaminated jobs. A higher ratio here
suggests a greater presence of the revolving door in a sector. The ratio of public sector
jobs to contaminated jobs, when aggregated by sector, shows how often a lobbyist
works contaminated public sector jobs. A higher number here indicates that connected
regulation-related workers will tend to move directly to become lobbyists at a higher
rate; they may be more affected by the pull of the “exit” side of the revolving door as
discussed by Gormley and Cohen, as they waste less time in non-revolving-door-
relevant public jobs before becoming a lobbyist. Individual level ratios are aggregated
and sorted by sector, and are compared using the three weighting groups mentioned
earlier (the “information” group, the “LDA” group, and the “all” group).
Findings
My data includes the professional working background of 3,546 lobbyists. There
are also 2,320 lobbyists that have disclosed via an LDA, and a total of 13,221 people in
my database including the bulk downloaded “other key personnel”. All of these lobbyists
come from one of 1,613 organizations. Please see Figure 4 for a sector-specific
breakdown of the number of lobbyists and organizations in each group, and Figures 5
and 6 for a graphical representation of the organizations per sector and the rate of listed
previous employment per sector.
Figure 4 – Sector Breakdown of various Lobbyist groups
Information
Group14
LDA Group All Group Organizations
13
A “clean” job is one that is not contaminated or related to the revolving door.
14
These are the lobbyists that I was able to find information on in the lobbyists.info
database.
Jameson 18
Finance 793 749 4924 634
Energy 1460 883 4944 619
Pharmaceuticals 713 411 1713 161
Telecommunications 580 277 1640 199
Figure 5 – Sector Breakdown of all organizations in data
Organization	
  Breakdown	
  
Finance	
  
Energy	
  
Pharma	
  
Telecom	
  
Jameson 19
Figure 6 – Sector Breakdown of Lobbyists with listed work experience
It is evident that both the financial sector and the energy sector are quite large,
containing more lobbyists and more organizations than the pharmaceutical sector and
the telecommunications sector. Financial lobbyists disclosed their information via an
LDA at a much higher rate than lobbyists from any other sector. Also, there is less
“noise” in the pharmaceuticals and telecommunications groups – there are fewer
organizations and lobbyists listed yet they have a higher proportion of employment
history data. This implies that there are more non-revolving-door-relevant organizations
and lobbyists in finance and energy. Non-relevant organizations and lobbyists indicate
smaller organizations, which must contract out 100% of their lobbying, as they can not
afford in-house lobbyists. These smaller organizations are a function of the nature of the
finance and energy sectors compared against the telecommunications and
pharmaceutical sectors: there are many small banks or local utility providers, yet there
are very few small drug manufacturers or Internet providers.
Raw figures are interesting, but they are not the point of this study. There are two
revolving door contamination variables representing two different ratios: the first is a
Previous	
  Employment	
  Information	
  
Finance	
  
Energy	
  
Pharma	
  
Telecom	
  
Jameson 20
ratio of contaminated jobs to non-contaminated jobs15
, and the second is a ratio of
contaminated jobs to public sector jobs. These ratios change depending on which of the
three weighting groups is used. Examining the ratios for only the lobbyists with
employment history listed neglects the varying size of each sector. In order to account
for this, I have ratios calculated for each of my three groups – the information group, the
LDA group, and the all group. The LDA group partially represents the total amount of
lobbyists in each sector. Representation is partial because lobbyists.info lists some
people as lobbyists even though they have not disclosed their information with an LDA.
Lobbyists.info does not divulge how they determine that these non-LDA people are in
fact lobbyists. The all group fixes the gap in the LDA group by including everyone, even
lobbyists that did not disclose with an LDA. Unfortunately, the all group also contains
many non-lobbying related personnel, which will distort results for sectors with more
organizations (finance, energy). The top 20 group controls for the distortion of sectors
due to their size, as only the 20 largest organizations from each sector are included. As
you can see in Figure 7, there is a wide distribution in the number of lobbyists per
organizations, so the top 20 groups are distinct from the rest.
15
Non-contaminated jobs are both private sector jobs and public sector jobs that are not
related to the sector that a lobbyist currently works in.
Jameson 21
Figure 7 – Distribution of the # of lobbyists per sector
Larger organizations should have more revolving door contamination than the smaller
organizations outside of the top 20. As Vidal et al. have shown lobbyists with personal
connections gained from revolving doors are more valuable than unconnected lobbyists.
These lobbyists are paid higher salaries for their services, which is something that
larger organizations are more able to afford than many smaller firms. Larger firms will
also be able to recruit lobbyists more effectively, due to their size and the notion that
better paying jobs at these organizations are more prestigious. Additionally, many
smaller firms contract out their lobbying to lobbying firms, which reduces their
contamination ratios in my data. Please see Figure 8 for a table containing the top 20
organizations in each sector.
05000500
0 20 40 60 80 0 20 40 60 80
Energy Finance
Pharma Telecom
Frequency
(sum) kount
Graphs by sector
Jameson 22
Figure 8 – Top 20 Organizations/Associations
The contaminated ratios for the lobbyists in the “information” group are highest
for the financial sector. Please see Figure 9 for a graph representing the contamination
ratios for the lobbyists with professional working experiences listed in my data. The blue
variable, “contaminatedtoclean”, represents the ratio of contaminated revolving door
jobs to all “clean” jobs, or all private jobs and public jobs not directly relevant to the area
Finance Energy Pharmaceuticals Telecommunications
Accenture
American+Fuel+&+Petrochemical+
Manufacturers Abbott+Laboratories
Association+of+Public+Television+
Stations
American+Bankers+Association American+Petroleum+Institute
American+Society+of+
Consultant+Pharmacists AT&T+Corporation
American+Council+of+Life+Insurers+(ACLI)
American+Public+Power+
Association Amgen+Inc. AT&T+Services,+Inc.
American+Institute+of+Certified+Public+
Accountants BAE+Systems+Inc.
AstraZeneca+Pharmaceuticals,+
LP BAE+Systems+Inc.
Center+on+Budget+and+Policy+Priorities
Biotechnology+Industry+
Organization+(BIO)
Biotechnology+Industry+
Organization+(BIO) CenturyLink
Citigroup,+Inc. Chevron+U.S.A.,+Inc.
BristolLMyers+Squibb+
Company Cisco+Systems+Inc.
Cornerstone+Credit+Union+League Edison+Electric+Institute
Consumer+Healthcare+
Products+Association Comcast+Corporation
Ernst+&+Young+LLP Exelon+Corporation
E.I.+du+Pont+de+Nemours+&+
Company+(DuPont) CTIA+L+The+Wireless+Association
Independent+Community+Bankers+of+
America Exxon+Mobil+Corporation Eli+Lilly+and+Company eBay+Inc.
J.+P.+Morgan+Chase+and+Company General+Electric+Company Express+Scripts,+Inc.
Information+Technology+
Industry+Council
KPMG+LLP Intel+Corporation GlaxoSmithKline Interactive+Advertising+Bureau
Mortgage+Bankers+Association+of+
America
International+Business+Machines+
Corporation+(IBM)
Healthcare+Distribution+
Management+Association
Internet+Corporation+for+
Assigned+Names+and+Numbers+
(ICANN)
National+Association+of+Federal+Credit+
Unions
National+Electrical+Contractors+
Association
Johnson+&+Johnson+Services,+
Inc. Internet+Society
National+Association+of+Real+Estate+
Investment+Trusts+(NAREIT)
National+Electrical+Manufacturers+
Association Merck+&+Company
National+Cable+&+
Telecommunications+
Association
PNC+Financial+Services+Group,+Inc.
National+Rural+Electric+
Cooperative+Association
National+Association+of+Chain+
Drug+Stores
National+Telecommunications+
Cooperative+Association
PriceWaterhouseCoopers Northrop+Grumman+Corporation
National+Community+
Pharmacists+Association Qualcomm+Incorporated
Securities+Industry+and+Financial+
Markets+Association+(SIFMA) Nuclear+Energy+Institute Novo+Nordisk,+Inc. Sprint+Nextel+Corporation
Textron+Inc.
Raytheon+Applied+Signal+
Technology,+Inc. Pfizer+Inc. TLMobile+USA
The+Financial+Services+Roundtable Shell+Oil+Company
Pharmaceutical+Research+and+
Manufacturers+of+America+
(PhRMA)
United+Technologies+
Corporation
Wells+Fargo+&+Company Southern+Company Procter+&+Gamble+Company Verizon+Communications
Jameson 23
in which a lobbyist is active. The red variable, “contaminatedratio”, represents the ratio
of contaminated public sector jobs to non-contaminated public sector jobs.
Figure 9 – Contamination including just lobbyists with working history listed
When comparing lobbying data disclosed by sector, finance has the highest levels of
revolving door contamination measured against all jobs and public sector jobs, though
the energy sector and the pharmaceutical sector are not far behind. Using this group,
there is little differentiation between the 20 largest firms and the rest of the industry for
all sectors – the bulk of the energy industry is slightly less contaminated than the top
firms, and the same goes for the pharmaceutical industry albeit to a slightly lesser
degree. This is surprising because the top firms should be able to attract more for the
lobbyists that have revolving door connections than the smaller firms can with higher
salaries and prestige, yet that is not supported by the data. The gap between the
contamination variables for the bulk of the pharmaceutical industry is strange – a low
0.05.1.15
Energy Finance Pharma Telecom Energy Finance Pharma Telecom
Everyone Else 20 Largest Firms
mean of contaminatedtoclean mean of contaminatedratio
Graphs by top20
Jameson 24
“contaminatedratio” measure yet relatively high “contaminatedtoclean” measure
indicates that lobbyists for smaller pharmaceutical firms are less likely to work in non-
contaminated public sector jobs when compared to their “top 20” counterparts.
These ratios differ when you include more than just lobbyists with listed
professional work experience. When all lobbyists that have filed an LDA are included in
the study, the financial sector appears much less contaminated. Please see Figure 10
for a graph representing the contaminated ratios for each sector including lobbyists
without background information that have filed an LDA.
Figure 10 – Contamination including LDA lobbyists
The reduction of revolving door contamination in finance is surprising, as is the
continued prominence of contamination in the pharmaceutical industry. Again, it is odd
that the top 20 firms are, for the most part, less contaminated than the rest of their
respective sectors.
0.05.1.15
Energy Finance Pharma Telecom Energy Finance Pharma Telecom
Everyone Else 20 Largest Firms
mean of contaminatedtoclean mean of contaminatedratio
Graphs by top20
Jameson 25
These measures change once again when all available data is used. Please see
Figure 11 for the average contaminated ratios of each sector when including data on
both lobbyists and “other key personnel”.
Figure 11 – Contamination including all data
This is the only group where the 20 largest firms are all more contaminated than the rest
of the industry, but these results are misleading. The lobbyists.info database includes
organizations that contract their lobbying out to lobbyist firms, but information on the
revolving door contamination of lobbying firms is not included here. There are numerous
organizations that do this contracting, most of which are smaller. These small firms
contract out their lobbying because they are not large enough to afford in house
lobbyists; therefore, all that is listed for these companies in the database is “other key
personnel”. There are many of these small firms who list “other key personnel” with zero
chance of having a revolving door lobbyist because they do not have any lobbyists on
0.02.04.06
Energy Finance Pharma Telecom Energy Finance Pharma Telecom
Everyone Else 20 Largest Firms
mean of contaminatedtoclean mean of contaminatedratio
Graphs by top20
Jameson 26
staff at all. When these “other key personnel” are included, their lack of working history
data artificially deflates the average contaminated ratios for each sector.
The sources for revolving door contamination are the House, the Senate, and
various government regulatory agencies. Each sector has a differing amount of
contamination from each source. These sources matter – they reveal a sector’s
preferences, as top firms will want as many revolving door lobbyists as possible from
the sources that they intend to lobby. Please see Figure 12 for a graph of contamination
from the House, Figure 13 for a graph of contamination from the Senate, and Figure 14
for a graph of contamination from an agency, all weighted by the “all” group.
Figure 12 – Contamination from House (All)
0.1.2.3
Energy Finance Pharma Telecom Energy Finance Pharma Telecom
Everyone Else 20 Largest Firms
mean of contaminatedtoclean mean of contaminatedratio
Graphs by top20
Jameson 27
Figure 13 – Contamination from Senate (All)
Figure 14 – Contamination from Agency (all)
0.1.2.3.4
Energy Finance Pharma Telecom Energy Finance Pharma Telecom
Everyone Else 20 Largest Firms
mean of contaminatedtoclean mean of contaminatedratio
Graphs by top20
0.2.4.6
Energy Finance Pharma Telecom Energy Finance Pharma Telecom
Everyone Else 20 Largest Firms
mean of contaminatedtoclean mean of contaminatedratio
Graphs by top20
Jameson 28
The differences in these three graphs are striking. First, it is interesting to note that
these are the only graphs where the red “contaminatedratio” variable is sometimes
larger than the blue “contaminatedtoclean” variable. These larger red bars indicate that
lobbyists from the Senate or a regulatory agency spend little time in other public sector
jobs. More importantly, this data shows the differing sector preferences for revolving
door contamination. Top financial firms place a premium on former government
regulators, yet top energy related organizations have seemingly no interest in former
regulators. Top pharmaceutical organizations clearly covet lobbyists with backgrounds
in the Senate, while top energy firms desire connections in the House.
Conclusion
The data presented in this study holds crucial implications for our understanding
of the revolving door. There is no doubt that legislative revolving door lobbyists are
valued for their connections and that this value is expressed as higher salaries paid by
organizations for lobbyists with those connections (Vidal, Draca, and Fons-Rosen
2012). But this is an incomplete description; organizations do not desire just any
revolving door connections. My data, which includes legislative as well as other
sources of revolving door contamination, supports a more nuanced understanding of
the dynamics of the revolving door. If organizations valued all revolving door
connections equally, then the data would show that the top 20 firms in each sector are
much more contaminated by the revolving door than the smaller firms, as the top firms
are better able to recruit these lobbyists with higher salaries, better benefits, and a
sense of prestige. My data shows that quite often, smaller firms have the same or a
greater amount of revolving door contamination. In addition, my data shows that a
sector’s demand for revolving door connections is not broad and unfocused, as is often
conjectured. There is overwhelming demand from top financial organizations for
regulatory agency-based revolving door connections, whereas there is very little
demand for the same types of connections from top energy companies. Understanding
this variation is important – we should not think of all revolving door connections as
equal, as clearly firms do not. Top financial firms value agency-based revolving door
Jameson 29
connections because their regulatory agencies are simultaneously powerful and
collegial. On one hand, agencies like the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC)
and the Federal Reserve (Fed) wield great power over the financial sector, yet they
also seek input from the industry when creating new laws16
. Conversely, Congress
rarely passes financial laws as they are too complex and they are more wary of being
seen as too friendly towards bankers. Even the Dodd-Frank Act, Congress’s hallmark
piece of financial legislation, focused on changes to be undertaken by regulatory
agencies17
. Therefore it makes sense that top financial firms would prefer agency
connections: the agencies play the largest role in shaping their regulatory environment
and they provide opportunity for influence. The case for the energy sector is completely
opposite: the EPA is notorious for butting heads with their industry, even as some
critics complain that the agency no longer has teeth. In addition, Congress can, and
does, pass standalone energy related legislation18
. Why would the energy sector
bother trying to influence an ineffective, uncooperative agency when they could spend
that time and money lobbying Congress, which is both effective and open to influence?
Wide, generalized conclusions about the revolving door understate the variation in
revolving door demand from various organizations in different sectors of the economy.
In order to further expand our knowledge of the revolving door, future research
could focus on the relationship between a firm or organization’s level of lobbying
success and their level of revolving door contamination. Do larger firms need more
revolving door connections to be successful, or do they just have them because they
are able to get them? Are smaller firms more effective at lobbying than larger firms if
16
For example, the SEC actually invites people and organizations to comment on
proposed rule changes. You can submit comments very easily, right on their website:
https://www.sec.gov/rules/submitcomments.htm
17
Congress delegated changes to be made to the agencies instead of directly making
changes themselves – why waste time lobbying Congress then if the agencies will be
the ones to implement the final rules?
18
Examples: H.R. 527(113th
) is a passed bill finalizing the privatization of the Federal
helium reserve, H.R. 678(113th
) authorized many federal facilities for hydropower
development, and H.R. 5057(113th
) provided exemptions for certain power supplies
from efficiency standards.
Jameson 30
they both have similar revolving door contamination levels? Qualitative research on
firm or organization’s attitudes towards the revolving door would also be fascinating. Do
top financial organizations internally acknowledge that they target agency-related
revolving door lobbyists? Finally, further study is required on lobbyists that are
members of lobbying firms, which are not included at all in my data or analysis.
Jameson 31
Bibliography
Baker, Andrew. 2010. “Restraining Regulatory Capture? Anglo-America, Crisis Politics
and Trajectories of Change in Global Financial Governance.” International Affairs
86 (3): 647–63.
Cohen, Jeffrey E. 1986. “The Dynamics of the ‘Revolving Door’ on the FCC.” American
Journal of Political Science 30 (4): 689–708.
Eckert, Ross D. 1981. “Life Cycle of Regulatory Commissioners, The.” JL & Econ. 24:
113.
Gormley, William T. 1979. “A Test of the Revolving Door Hypothesis at the FCC.”
American Journal of Political Science 23 (4): 665–83.
Johnson, Simon. 2009. “The Quiet Coup.” The Atlantic 52: 1.
Makkai, Toni, and John Braithwaite. 1992. “In and out of the Revolving Door: Making
Sense of Regulatory Capture.” Journal of Public Policy 12 (1): 61–78.
McKay, Amy. 2012. “Buying Policy? The Effects of Lobbyists’ Resources on Their Policy
Success.” Political Research Quarterly 65 (4): 908–23.
Quirk, Paul J. 2014. Industry Influence in Federal Regulatory Agencies. Princeton
University Press.
Shive, Sophie, and Margaret Forster. 2013. “The Revolving Door for Financial
Regulators.” SSRN Working Paper Series, November.
doi:http://dx.doi.org.silk.library.umass.edu/10.2139/ssrn.2348968.
United States Census Bureau. 1992. Economic Census. Section 483, Broadcasting and
Cable Services. United States Census Bureau.
Vidal, Jordi Blanes I, Mirko Draca, and Christian Fons-Rosen. 2012. “Revolving Door
Lobbyists.” The American Economic Review 102 (7): 3731–48.
doi:10.1257/aer.102.7.3731.

Contenu connexe

Tendances

What the new UK Bribery Act 2010 means for US companies
What the new UK Bribery Act 2010 means for US companiesWhat the new UK Bribery Act 2010 means for US companies
What the new UK Bribery Act 2010 means for US companiesMatt Stone
 
Fines, Leniency, Rewards and Organized Crime: Evidence from Antitrust Experiment
Fines, Leniency, Rewards and Organized Crime: Evidence from Antitrust ExperimentFines, Leniency, Rewards and Organized Crime: Evidence from Antitrust Experiment
Fines, Leniency, Rewards and Organized Crime: Evidence from Antitrust ExperimentStockholm Institute of Transition Economics
 
Xamin it on legitimacy
Xamin it on legitimacyXamin it on legitimacy
Xamin it on legitimacypjvicary
 
Top 10 Inbound And Outbound Calling Compliance Issues
Top 10 Inbound And Outbound Calling Compliance IssuesTop 10 Inbound And Outbound Calling Compliance Issues
Top 10 Inbound And Outbound Calling Compliance IssuesRyan Thurman
 
The Legality of Call Recording
The Legality of Call RecordingThe Legality of Call Recording
The Legality of Call RecordingShoreTel
 
Bark & Co Solicitors London: Deferred Prosecution Agreements
Bark & Co Solicitors London: Deferred Prosecution AgreementsBark & Co Solicitors London: Deferred Prosecution Agreements
Bark & Co Solicitors London: Deferred Prosecution Agreementschesleayearly
 
Election Night Viewing Guide
Election Night Viewing GuideElection Night Viewing Guide
Election Night Viewing GuideDaniel Berman
 
Corporate Money In Politics
Corporate Money In PoliticsCorporate Money In Politics
Corporate Money In PoliticsMatthew Pipes
 
Tax Rates Research Paper
Tax Rates Research PaperTax Rates Research Paper
Tax Rates Research PaperGor Sargsyan
 
Fox news fair and balanced we report. you decide. you decide
Fox news fair and balanced we report. you decide. you decideFox news fair and balanced we report. you decide. you decide
Fox news fair and balanced we report. you decide. you decideAlexander Decker
 
Sample MLA research paper
Sample MLA research paper Sample MLA research paper
Sample MLA research paper Wendy Scruggs
 

Tendances (16)

What the new UK Bribery Act 2010 means for US companies
What the new UK Bribery Act 2010 means for US companiesWhat the new UK Bribery Act 2010 means for US companies
What the new UK Bribery Act 2010 means for US companies
 
Fines, Leniency, Rewards and Organized Crime: Evidence from Antitrust Experiment
Fines, Leniency, Rewards and Organized Crime: Evidence from Antitrust ExperimentFines, Leniency, Rewards and Organized Crime: Evidence from Antitrust Experiment
Fines, Leniency, Rewards and Organized Crime: Evidence from Antitrust Experiment
 
Xamin it on legitimacy
Xamin it on legitimacyXamin it on legitimacy
Xamin it on legitimacy
 
Leniency, Asymmetric Punishment and Corruption: Evidence from China
Leniency, Asymmetric Punishment and Corruption: Evidence from ChinaLeniency, Asymmetric Punishment and Corruption: Evidence from China
Leniency, Asymmetric Punishment and Corruption: Evidence from China
 
Top 10 Inbound And Outbound Calling Compliance Issues
Top 10 Inbound And Outbound Calling Compliance IssuesTop 10 Inbound And Outbound Calling Compliance Issues
Top 10 Inbound And Outbound Calling Compliance Issues
 
The Legality of Call Recording
The Legality of Call RecordingThe Legality of Call Recording
The Legality of Call Recording
 
Bark & Co Solicitors London: Deferred Prosecution Agreements
Bark & Co Solicitors London: Deferred Prosecution AgreementsBark & Co Solicitors London: Deferred Prosecution Agreements
Bark & Co Solicitors London: Deferred Prosecution Agreements
 
Election Night Viewing Guide
Election Night Viewing GuideElection Night Viewing Guide
Election Night Viewing Guide
 
Keegan Law
Keegan LawKeegan Law
Keegan Law
 
The EU Leniency Programme and Recidivism
The EU Leniency Programme and RecidivismThe EU Leniency Programme and Recidivism
The EU Leniency Programme and Recidivism
 
Corporate Money In Politics
Corporate Money In PoliticsCorporate Money In Politics
Corporate Money In Politics
 
Competition policy and productivity growth: An empirical assessment
Competition policy and productivity growth: An empirical assessmentCompetition policy and productivity growth: An empirical assessment
Competition policy and productivity growth: An empirical assessment
 
Tax Rates Research Paper
Tax Rates Research PaperTax Rates Research Paper
Tax Rates Research Paper
 
Fox news fair and balanced we report. you decide. you decide
Fox news fair and balanced we report. you decide. you decideFox news fair and balanced we report. you decide. you decide
Fox news fair and balanced we report. you decide. you decide
 
Sample MLA research paper
Sample MLA research paper Sample MLA research paper
Sample MLA research paper
 
Trust, Salience and Deterrence
Trust, Salience and DeterrenceTrust, Salience and Deterrence
Trust, Salience and Deterrence
 

En vedette

Algodon Group Corporate Brochure - email
Algodon Group Corporate Brochure - emailAlgodon Group Corporate Brochure - email
Algodon Group Corporate Brochure - emailGregory Gassoso
 
What is just and moral in international politics
What is just and moral in international politicsWhat is just and moral in international politics
What is just and moral in international politicsDaria Globenko
 

En vedette (7)

Algodon Group Corporate Brochure - email
Algodon Group Corporate Brochure - emailAlgodon Group Corporate Brochure - email
Algodon Group Corporate Brochure - email
 
Bemutató1
Bemutató1Bemutató1
Bemutató1
 
Paz a la calle
Paz a la callePaz a la calle
Paz a la calle
 
LA PLAZA SE PREPARA
LA PLAZA SE PREPARALA PLAZA SE PREPARA
LA PLAZA SE PREPARA
 
Reunión inicio familias
Reunión inicio familiasReunión inicio familias
Reunión inicio familias
 
What is just and moral in international politics
What is just and moral in international politicsWhat is just and moral in international politics
What is just and moral in international politics
 
Pychei
PycheiPychei
Pychei
 

Similaire à Shifting the Understanding of Lobbyist Revolving Doors

The Public's Knowledge of Broadcast and Non-Broadcast Network Indecency Regul...
The Public's Knowledge of Broadcast and Non-Broadcast Network Indecency Regul...The Public's Knowledge of Broadcast and Non-Broadcast Network Indecency Regul...
The Public's Knowledge of Broadcast and Non-Broadcast Network Indecency Regul...Kurt Rempe
 
Lobbying Stakeholder Analysis/ENGL 202 project 4
Lobbying Stakeholder Analysis/ENGL 202 project 4Lobbying Stakeholder Analysis/ENGL 202 project 4
Lobbying Stakeholder Analysis/ENGL 202 project 4Jonah Baker
 
Week 1 - AssignmentFinal Research Paper OutlineFor this week’s ass.docx
Week 1 - AssignmentFinal Research Paper OutlineFor this week’s ass.docxWeek 1 - AssignmentFinal Research Paper OutlineFor this week’s ass.docx
Week 1 - AssignmentFinal Research Paper OutlineFor this week’s ass.docxcelenarouzie
 
The Wrong Way to Reinvent Media, Part II: Broadcast Spectrum Taxes to Subsidi...
The Wrong Way to Reinvent Media, Part II: Broadcast Spectrum Taxes to Subsidi...The Wrong Way to Reinvent Media, Part II: Broadcast Spectrum Taxes to Subsidi...
The Wrong Way to Reinvent Media, Part II: Broadcast Spectrum Taxes to Subsidi...knightcomm
 
Privacy_Issues_Overview
Privacy_Issues_OverviewPrivacy_Issues_Overview
Privacy_Issues_OverviewBrian Berger
 
Privacy issues overview
Privacy issues overviewPrivacy issues overview
Privacy issues overviewBrian Berger
 
08.01.13 Antitrust Source article
08.01.13 Antitrust Source article08.01.13 Antitrust Source article
08.01.13 Antitrust Source articleAnant Raut
 
Fcc open internet proceeding michael horney
Fcc open internet proceeding michael horneyFcc open internet proceeding michael horney
Fcc open internet proceeding michael horneyMichael Horney
 
273PRODUCING DEMOCRATIC VIBRANCY^K. Sabeel Rahman.docx
273PRODUCING DEMOCRATIC VIBRANCY^K. Sabeel Rahman.docx273PRODUCING DEMOCRATIC VIBRANCY^K. Sabeel Rahman.docx
273PRODUCING DEMOCRATIC VIBRANCY^K. Sabeel Rahman.docxvickeryr87
 
273PRODUCING DEMOCRATIC VIBRANCY^K. Sabeel Rahman.docx
273PRODUCING DEMOCRATIC VIBRANCY^K. Sabeel Rahman.docx273PRODUCING DEMOCRATIC VIBRANCY^K. Sabeel Rahman.docx
273PRODUCING DEMOCRATIC VIBRANCY^K. Sabeel Rahman.docxlorainedeserre
 
Civil justice at_the_crossroads
Civil justice at_the_crossroadsCivil justice at_the_crossroads
Civil justice at_the_crossroadssdlawjohnnyz
 
Article, Limitations On The FTCs Investigation Of The Business Of Insurance, ...
Article, Limitations On The FTCs Investigation Of The Business Of Insurance, ...Article, Limitations On The FTCs Investigation Of The Business Of Insurance, ...
Article, Limitations On The FTCs Investigation Of The Business Of Insurance, ...waretc
 
Delivered by Publishin.docx
Delivered by Publishin.docxDelivered by Publishin.docx
Delivered by Publishin.docxcargillfilberto
 
Bynum, Cindy. Thesis Final
Bynum, Cindy. Thesis FinalBynum, Cindy. Thesis Final
Bynum, Cindy. Thesis FinalCynthia Bynum
 
Bynum, Cindy. Thesis Final
Bynum, Cindy. Thesis FinalBynum, Cindy. Thesis Final
Bynum, Cindy. Thesis FinalCynthia Bynum
 
The FixHow Citizens Unitedchanged politics, in 7charts.docx
The FixHow Citizens Unitedchanged politics, in 7charts.docxThe FixHow Citizens Unitedchanged politics, in 7charts.docx
The FixHow Citizens Unitedchanged politics, in 7charts.docxoreo10
 
Scanned by CamScannerScanned by CamScannerChapte.docx
Scanned by CamScannerScanned by CamScannerChapte.docxScanned by CamScannerScanned by CamScannerChapte.docx
Scanned by CamScannerScanned by CamScannerChapte.docxtodd331
 
Citizens United v. Federal Election CommissionFor more than 100 .docx
Citizens United v. Federal Election CommissionFor more than 100 .docxCitizens United v. Federal Election CommissionFor more than 100 .docx
Citizens United v. Federal Election CommissionFor more than 100 .docxmonicafrancis71118
 

Similaire à Shifting the Understanding of Lobbyist Revolving Doors (20)

The Public's Knowledge of Broadcast and Non-Broadcast Network Indecency Regul...
The Public's Knowledge of Broadcast and Non-Broadcast Network Indecency Regul...The Public's Knowledge of Broadcast and Non-Broadcast Network Indecency Regul...
The Public's Knowledge of Broadcast and Non-Broadcast Network Indecency Regul...
 
Lobbying Stakeholder Analysis/ENGL 202 project 4
Lobbying Stakeholder Analysis/ENGL 202 project 4Lobbying Stakeholder Analysis/ENGL 202 project 4
Lobbying Stakeholder Analysis/ENGL 202 project 4
 
Week 1 - AssignmentFinal Research Paper OutlineFor this week’s ass.docx
Week 1 - AssignmentFinal Research Paper OutlineFor this week’s ass.docxWeek 1 - AssignmentFinal Research Paper OutlineFor this week’s ass.docx
Week 1 - AssignmentFinal Research Paper OutlineFor this week’s ass.docx
 
The Wrong Way to Reinvent Media, Part II: Broadcast Spectrum Taxes to Subsidi...
The Wrong Way to Reinvent Media, Part II: Broadcast Spectrum Taxes to Subsidi...The Wrong Way to Reinvent Media, Part II: Broadcast Spectrum Taxes to Subsidi...
The Wrong Way to Reinvent Media, Part II: Broadcast Spectrum Taxes to Subsidi...
 
Citizens United v FEC
Citizens United v FECCitizens United v FEC
Citizens United v FEC
 
Privacy_Issues_Overview
Privacy_Issues_OverviewPrivacy_Issues_Overview
Privacy_Issues_Overview
 
Privacy issues overview
Privacy issues overviewPrivacy issues overview
Privacy issues overview
 
08.01.13 Antitrust Source article
08.01.13 Antitrust Source article08.01.13 Antitrust Source article
08.01.13 Antitrust Source article
 
Fcc open internet proceeding michael horney
Fcc open internet proceeding michael horneyFcc open internet proceeding michael horney
Fcc open internet proceeding michael horney
 
273PRODUCING DEMOCRATIC VIBRANCY^K. Sabeel Rahman.docx
273PRODUCING DEMOCRATIC VIBRANCY^K. Sabeel Rahman.docx273PRODUCING DEMOCRATIC VIBRANCY^K. Sabeel Rahman.docx
273PRODUCING DEMOCRATIC VIBRANCY^K. Sabeel Rahman.docx
 
273PRODUCING DEMOCRATIC VIBRANCY^K. Sabeel Rahman.docx
273PRODUCING DEMOCRATIC VIBRANCY^K. Sabeel Rahman.docx273PRODUCING DEMOCRATIC VIBRANCY^K. Sabeel Rahman.docx
273PRODUCING DEMOCRATIC VIBRANCY^K. Sabeel Rahman.docx
 
Civil justice at_the_crossroads
Civil justice at_the_crossroadsCivil justice at_the_crossroads
Civil justice at_the_crossroads
 
Article, Limitations On The FTCs Investigation Of The Business Of Insurance, ...
Article, Limitations On The FTCs Investigation Of The Business Of Insurance, ...Article, Limitations On The FTCs Investigation Of The Business Of Insurance, ...
Article, Limitations On The FTCs Investigation Of The Business Of Insurance, ...
 
Delivered by Publishin.docx
Delivered by Publishin.docxDelivered by Publishin.docx
Delivered by Publishin.docx
 
Bynum, Cindy. Thesis Final
Bynum, Cindy. Thesis FinalBynum, Cindy. Thesis Final
Bynum, Cindy. Thesis Final
 
Bynum, Cindy. Thesis Final
Bynum, Cindy. Thesis FinalBynum, Cindy. Thesis Final
Bynum, Cindy. Thesis Final
 
Civil justice system reforms in england and wales
Civil justice system reforms in england and walesCivil justice system reforms in england and wales
Civil justice system reforms in england and wales
 
The FixHow Citizens Unitedchanged politics, in 7charts.docx
The FixHow Citizens Unitedchanged politics, in 7charts.docxThe FixHow Citizens Unitedchanged politics, in 7charts.docx
The FixHow Citizens Unitedchanged politics, in 7charts.docx
 
Scanned by CamScannerScanned by CamScannerChapte.docx
Scanned by CamScannerScanned by CamScannerChapte.docxScanned by CamScannerScanned by CamScannerChapte.docx
Scanned by CamScannerScanned by CamScannerChapte.docx
 
Citizens United v. Federal Election CommissionFor more than 100 .docx
Citizens United v. Federal Election CommissionFor more than 100 .docxCitizens United v. Federal Election CommissionFor more than 100 .docx
Citizens United v. Federal Election CommissionFor more than 100 .docx
 

Shifting the Understanding of Lobbyist Revolving Doors

  • 1. Jameson 1 Shifting the Understanding of Revolving Door Lobbyists John Jameson University of Massachusetts Amherst Abstract: The revolving door, defined as the exchange of personnel between a regulator and the regulated industry, is both under-studied and engulfed in excessive speculation. To combat this, I constructed a database of the revolving door connections held by in-house lobbyists active in four unique sectors of the economy: finance, energy, pharmaceuticals, and telecommunications. After constructing revolving door ratios for each lobbyist, I compare different levels of revolving door “contamination” across sectors. I also compare the contaminated ratios of the top 20 organizations and the smaller remaining organizations from each sector. Larger organizations have more resources at their disposal to attract top talent. Therefore, large organizations should be more contaminated than small organizations, as the connections gained from the revolving door are highly sought after by the firms and organizations that hire lobbyists. Yet my findings show that the larger firms are not more contaminated than the smaller firms, which indicates that our current understanding of the revolving door lacks necessary complexity. Upon examining the common sources of contamination for each sector, I am able to conclude that organizations do not blindly seek lobbyists with any revolving door connections, but instead favor lobbyists with connections in areas deemed key to a sector’s prosperity.
  • 2. Jameson 2 Introduction The revolving door, or the exchange of workers between a regulated industry and its regulator, is an under-studied yet widely discussed phenomenon of modern regulatory policymaking. News outlets1 and political pundits denigrate the revolving door as another tool to be used by corporations to get their way. Some cite it as an example of a wealthy ruling elite that can travel freely between corporate boardrooms and regulatory agencies. And yet others insist that the revolving door facilitates better policymaking by including private sector expertise into the debate over complicated regulations. Some blame the revolving door for facilitating a lax regulatory climate that lead to the 2008 global financial crisis, stating that the revolving door runs rampant among lawmakers. Without further study, the revolving door will remain ambiguous and misunderstood. This project seeks to fill in portions of our knowledge about the revolving door and add to the existing literature. I examine the revolving door as it pertains to lobbyists; I have constructed a database containing employment history data on over three thousand lobbyists, which I will use to examine the scope of revolving door contamination as it relates to lobbyists and certain sectors of the economy. I will add nuance to our understanding of how revolving door connections are valued, and by whom they are valued. This paper will begin with an examination of the existing literature on the revolving door, and will then proceed to a description of the ins and outs of my data. I will then present my findings before finally stating conclusions drawn from the data. Background Literature In 1979, Gormley (Gormley 1979) performed the first in-depth examination of the revolving door. He studied the impact of private sector working experience on regulators at the United States Federal Communications Commission (henceforth the FCC). To 1 1 The New York Times, for example, features stories on the revolving door so often that they have created a category for it on a section of their website: http://dealbook.nytimes.com/category/series/revolving-door/ 2 This may at first seem counter-intuitive but Gormley considered the “broadcast
  • 3. Jameson 3 test the revolving door hypothesis, Gormley gathered non-unanimous voting data on rule creation, rule changes, notices of inquiries, and other decisions from FCC commissioners from 1974 to 1976. His information is accurate – he gathered them from the minutes of FCC meetings. In that two-year period, there was no turnover of commissioners; Gormley also gathered the occupational history of all seven FCC commissioners, so he could determine who had worked in the industry (broadcasting) and who had not. To test the effect of the revolving door, he applied bloc analysis and Guttman scaling. Bloc analysis tests for voting blocs, the theory being that former broadcasters would be like-minded and therefore vote concurrently. Guttman scaling requires Gormley to characterize votes as having a political direction (whether the vote is pro- or anti-broadcasting); this allows him to test the effect of individual values held by commissioners, and attribute voting patterns to characteristics like political party affiliation (Republican or Democrat) or previous employment within the regulated industry. Using all of the votes undertaken at the FCC, the results from the bloc analysis do not confirm the revolving door hypothesis. In other words, the two commissioners who were former broadcasters did not tend to vote in a bloc on all issues put to a vote at the FCC. But, the results change when the scope is narrowed by using only the votes that apply specifically to broadcasting, showing that the two revolving door FCC commissioners form a voting bloc with two other (non revolving door) FCC commissioners. In fact, each revolving door commissioner voted more similarly with a non revolving door commissioner than they did with each other. Therefore, according to Gormley, this outcome partially supports the revolving door hypothesis. Yet the inclusion of two additional (non revolving door) commissioners in the voting bloc suggests that there may be other factors influencing regulator votes other than the revolving door. Support for the revolving door does not stop there: using Guttman scaling, Gormley found that the two former broadcasters to be more likely to support the broadcasting industry’s position than other commissioners. Applying Guttman scaling forced Gormley to Identify three subsets of votes where the position of the broadcasting industry was clear: broadcast license renewals, broadcast program content regulation, and cable television. A commissioner was considered “pro-broadcasting” if their vote coincided
  • 4. Jameson 4 with the wishes of the broadcasting industry within the three subsets. Specifically, a commissioner was pro-broadcasting if they: 1) voted to support the renewal of an organization’s license in spite of complaints or abuses, 2) voted to loosen program content restriction and regulation, and 3) voted in a direction that was unfavorable to the cable television industry or to a specific cable operator2 . In all three areas, the two FCC commissioners that were former broadcasters were more likely to support the broadcasting industry’s position, thus providing support for the revolving door hypothesis. Yet Gormley notes two points: the former broadcasters only narrowly supported broadcasting against cable television (53.2% of the time), and the differences between the “pro” commissioners and the rest of the commissioners are enhanced by the fact that Gormley is only counting non-unanimous votes. Additionally, he found that party identification predicted vote behavior better than occupational background3 . Nonetheless, this does not detract from Gormley’s revolving door findings: it has been long established that political party affiliations play a role in regulatory policymaking, but the impact of prior employment is less known. The main takeaway from Gormley’s research is that the revolving door has some kind of effect on regulation, as work history in broadcasting caused FCC commissioners to be more accepting of the interests of the industry but the full effects are ambiguous, as other factors like political party also have a strong effect on support for broadcasting industry positions. Cohen (Cohen 1986) advances Gormley’s FCC revolving door work further by expanding the dataset and including more nuanced measures of the effect of the revolving door. He expanded the dataset beyond two years by gathering voting records on non-unanimous FCC votes from 1955 to 1974, which included votes from 28 commissioners (increased from Gormley’s seven). Mirroring Gormley, Cohen also considered all votes as a decision that did or did not support the broadcasting industry position. Cohen moves one step beyond Gormley by gathering more in-depth data on 2 This may at first seem counter-intuitive but Gormley considered the “broadcast industry” to be just organizations transmitting via radio, whose direct competitor would therefore be cable television. 3 Republican commissioners were much more likely than Democratic commissioners to support the broadcasting industry in all three aforementioned areas.
  • 5. Jameson 5 specific characteristics about each commissioner, including both pre- and post-FCC employment data instead of just pre-FCC employment data. This new data coupled with his larger sample of commissioners allowed him to include controls to better understand the factors that affect a regulator’s support of the broadcasting industry. Cohen recognizes that there are two sides of the revolving door: the “entrance” side and the “exit” side. On the one hand, the “entrance” side suggests that regulators that come from the regulated industry are more likely to support that industry as a regulator. According to Cohen, the “exit” side suggests, on the other hand, that the lure of a lucrative job in the industry after spending time as a regulator will lead the regulator to support the industry4 . Cohen designed his study based on his database containing 2,064 votes from 20-year period. From this set, he randomly sampled 10 votes from each year to compare, which allows for more complete and even assessment of commissioner behavior as the earlier years had fewer votes than the later years. Similar to Gormley, Cohen scored the votes of each commissioner on a binary scale: 1 representing industry support, 0 representing nonsupport. He also maintains Gormley’s scoring criteria: pro-broadcasting votes support license renewal, loosen content restrictions, and go against the cable industry. Cohen once again expands on Gormley’s data by collecting pre- and post-employment data from the FCC, the Who’s Who series, and The New York Times. Cohen creates four hypotheses total, which are broken evenly into two types: temporal and revolving door. Cohen’s four hypotheses (from p. 693-695): Hypothesis 1: FCC Commissioners previously employed in the regulated industry will be more supportive of the broadcast industry. Hypothesis 2: In their first year, FCC commissioners with industry experience will support the broadcast industry more than those without industry experience, but by the second year, the difference in industry support will narrow 4 It is worth noting that Cohen cites a lack of empirical support for the exit hypothesis – Eckert (Eckert 1981) reports that only 20% of regulators find direct employment in the regulated industry and Quirk (Quirk 2014) finds (via interviews) that regulators do not feel like their level of support will affect their chances at a job in the industry.
  • 6. Jameson 6 Hypothesis 3: Regulators employed in the regulated industry after their term in office ends will be more supportive of the regulated industry while in office than those who do not secure such employment. Hypothesis 4: In a commissioner’s last year on a regulatory body, the commissioner’s support for the regulated industry will increase. Cohen’s “entrance” hypothesis results are clear: regulator prior experience plays a role in industry support, thus confirming the revolving door hypothesis. Commissioners with prior experience in the broadcasting industry are 14% more supportive of the industry than commissioners without that experience. Also, post-FCC broadcast employment impacts commissioner support of industry, but in the opposite direction that Cohen would lead one to assume: commissioners that secure industry jobs post-FCC are less supportive (more stringent) of the industry during their term than commissioners who do not secure industry jobs. Further, commissioners in their last year of employment at the FCC seem to posture to increase their attractiveness to the industry: final year commissioners increased their industry support by 11%. Strangely, the final year posturing effect is more pronounced for those hired by the industry than those who are not: those who would go on to get hired were supportive 63.9% of the time in their final year, whereas those who did not go on to get hired were supportive 51.9% of the time. These last two findings paint a strange picture: for a regulator to be an ideal candidate for hire by the industry, they should spend almost their entire career against the industry, except the last year where they should begin to support the industry more. Using the variables based on the aforementioned hypotheses, Cohen finds that only three variables are statistically significant: pre-FCC industry employment, post-FCC industry employment, and last year on the FCC. He then makes his results more rigorous by including controls for other explanations for his outcomes. He controls for political party, geographically linked ideology, presidential impacts, and congressional impacts, and finds that including the control variables changes the outcome of significant variables. The significant variables now include: post-FCC employment, last
  • 7. Jameson 7 year on the FCC, and the party of the appointing president.5 This is a large shift – the pre-FCC employment variable is replaced entirely by the presidential party variable because Democratic presidents in the dataset did not appoint a single commissioner with previous broadcast experience. The main takeaway from Cohen’s study is that more studies of the revolving door are needed in other areas in order to make broad statements about regulatory agency decision-making. The revolving door may not have an extremely large influence on FCC decisions, but this conclusion is far from the idea that the revolving door is irrelevant or inapplicable to regulatory policymaking. It is possible that the FCC is uniquely influenced by presidential appointments (the control variable that replaced the “entrance” revolving door variable), as the selection of FCC commissioners is not a politically salient issue when compared to selection of Federal Reserve Chairmen or the heads of other major regulatory agencies. The Revolving Door is often cited as a mechanism that influences lawmaking and regulatory policymaking. Some, like Baker (Baker 2010), contend that the revolving door increases the influence of private sector actors, which leads to regulatory capture (when combined with other factors). Baker emphasizes his notion of regulatory capture in the through four causal mechanisms: lobbying, the degree of political salience, institutional design/revolving doors, and intellectual capture. In financial regulation, Baker points to the revolving door between private banks like Goldman Sachs to regulatory agencies, like the United States Treasury (the Treasury) or the Federal Reserve Bank of the United States (the Fed). Baker specifically mentions the presence of a “Wall Street – Washington” corridor, referring to the frequent movement of executives back and fourth between the two areas. This exchange of workers, according to Baker, can have a colonizing effect on regulatory agencies and can provide dysfunctional incentive structures for regulators. Baker cites a piece by Makkai and Braithwaite (Makkai and Braithwaite 1992) who contend that regulators are encouraged to pass industry-friendly regulations through implicit promises of future careers in the industry, but support for that idea in general is shaky at best as shown in part by the aforementioned piece by 5 ‘Conservative coalition’ vote success in the House is also statistically significant, but Cohen states that, “This result may be spurious” (p. 703).
  • 8. Jameson 8 Cohen. Baker cites Johnson’s (Johnson 2009) work detailing how the flow of professionals from the public to private sector allows for the formation of a belief system. This belief system idea, sometimes referred to as financialization, contends that what is good for Wall Street will also be good for the US (like large financial institutions and freer capital markets) which according to Baker, causes overly lenient regulations. Baker’s piece is useful insofar that it succinctly summarizes possible reasons for concern surrounding the revolving door. Blanes i Vidal, Draca, and Fons-Rosen (Vidal, Draca, and Fons-Rosen 2012) study the impact of the revolving door on the careers of congressional staffers turned lobbyists. They note the direct connection between revenue production from former staffers and the politicians for whom they previously served – they find that on average, lobbyists connected to a US senator suffers a 24% drop in generated revenue when their previous employer leaves the Senate. This effect is stronger for lobbyists who previously served under a congressman on an important committee6 . Blanes i Vidal et al. note that the connection between revenue generation and a lobbyist’s former boss is stronger for those that served in the Senate – being connected to a serving senator is associated with 23% higher revenue, whereas connection to a serving representative is only associated with 9% higher revenue generation. There is also evidence that ex- staffers are less likely to work in the lobbying industry after their connected senators exit Congress – being connected to a serving senator is associated with 27% higher likelihood of working as a lobbyist. Blanes i Vidal et al. provide crucial empirical evidence of the value of personal (revolving door) connections in the lobbying industry. These personal connections allow the lobbyists with them to be more effective (as they are generating more revenue) when certain politicians are in power. This piece of information is crucial to understanding how the revolving door works for financial regulation. McKay (McKay 2012) examines the role of money in lobbying and influencing policy outcomes. She wants to know how money affects policymaking – does more 6 Vidal et al. consider the Senate Finance and Appropriations Committee and House Ways and Means Committee important congressional committees.
  • 9. Jameson 9 money mean more lobbying success? Specifically, do wealthier groups achieve more lobbying success than less wealthy groups? To answer this question, McKay combines data on lobbyist resources and policy outcomes with existing data from interviews with lobbyists conducted from 1977-1982. She finds that financial wealth has little to do with a group’s policy success; what is far more important, is how the group spends the money. Spending money on increasing lobbying intensity (measured via more time spent in Washington DC, more lobbyists working on an issue, etc.) is correlated with greater lobbying success. She also states that experienced lobbyists with prior connections are a factor in more successful lobbying – these connections and experience can be acquired through the revolving door. But greater financial wealth does not always lead to greater lobbying intensity. The main takeaway from McKay, with respect to studying the revolving door, is that money alone does not buy lobbying success, but how money is spent does affect a group’s ability to influence policy. Reading in between the lines, McKay insinuates that spending money to increase lobbying intensity for lobbyists with experience and connections on Capitol Hill (revolving door lobbyists) is the best way to affect policy change. The revolving door does not only impact regulations – the private sector is also affected by the revolving door. Shive and Forster (Shive and Forster 2013) study these private sector impacts. They compile a dataset of regulators from any of the six financial regulatory institutions: the Federal Reserve (Fed), the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC), the Financial Industry Regulatory Authority (FINRA), the Commodity Futures Trading Commission (CFTC), the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency (OCC), and the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC). Shive and Forster focus on regulators that leave their institution through the revolving door to work at a private firm. Their findings are crucial: firms that hire revolving door regulators see a positive 0.9% return on hiring announcement day, and their stock volatility is 5% lower in the quarter following the revolving door hire. Financial firms are also twice as likely to hire a regulator from the body that directly regulates it. In other words, private firms become more profitable and more stable when they hire a revolving door regulator, and these firms seek out workers that previously regulated them. Shive and Forster find that
  • 10. Jameson 10 the most consistent determinant of hire by a financial firm is the revolving-door employee’s length of employment at the regulator – in other words, more experienced and presumably connected regulators are more desirable to firms. This information is crucial to our understanding of the revolving door: it establishes quantifiable ways in which private firms benefit from the revolving door. Research Methods The data for this project was compiled from the subscription-based online lobbying database lobbyists.info7 . The website contains information on over 28,000 federal lobbyists, over 2,400 lobbying firms, and over 12,000 corporations and associations. The data can be accessed in a number of ways: one can search for lobbyists by bill or bill sponsor, by legislative area, or by the industry in which a lobbyist is active. The lobbyist information in the database is segregated; when one searches for lobbyists by the aforementioned methods, the results only include in-house lobbyists, not lobbyists employed by lobbying firms. There is an option for searching for lobbying firm lobbyists, but it is separate from the main searches. I gathered the lobbying data manually8 , so the project moved slowly. I gathered the lobbyists’ name, the organization that he or she lobbied on behalf of, the sector they were found in, and their professional employment experience (if listed). Lobbyists.info is not a comprehensive source for employment history – there are many lobbyists that list their name and organization only. In the interest of brevity, I could not gather background information on every single lobbyist in the database. I reduced the size of the sample in two ways: first, I only gathered data on in-house lobbyists, and second I only searched for lobbyists active in one of four sectors of the economy. The four sectors are: finance, energy, pharmaceuticals, and telecommunications. I am mainly interested in financial sector 7 www.lobbyists.info 8 I would enter the data displayed on the website into a separate excel spreadsheet organization-by-organization, lobbyist-by-lobbyist.
  • 11. Jameson 11 lobbyists, but in order for my study to be broadly applicable and to accurately represent the greater lobbying industry, additional and diverse sectors are required. These four sectors are distinct, representing different sections of the economy, although they share certain features. The energy industry, like the financial industry, is important to the health and functioning of the rest of the larger economy, as economic productivity requires both capital and energy. The pharmaceutical industry, like the financial industry, is very seriously complex. The science behind cutting-edge medicines and research is beyond the scope of the average person, similar to the complexity and scale of modern financial instruments and derivatives. The telecommunications industry is similar to finance in that it generates an enormous amount of revenue, yet it is concentrated in a relatively small number of firms9 . These similarities will allow me to draw relative conclusions about revolving door lobbyists across sectors. It is important to acknowledge both the strengths and limitations of my data. The lobbyists.info website allows one to search for industry-specific lobbyists based on a large number of vague, pre-defined search terms. Please see Figure 1 for a description of the search terms used in this study with their corresponding sector. 9 According to the US Census Bureau, in 1992 roughly the top 7% of cable and broadcasting companies (ranked by revenue) were responsible for over 70% of the sector’s total revenue (United States Census Bureau 1992). The story is similar for finance: the top 1.8% of Securities Industry companies are responsible for over 58% of the sector’s total revenue (United States Census Bureau 1992).
  • 12. Jameson 12 Figure 1 – Sector Search Terms When the website is queried using these sector keywords, only organizations and associations are returned as results. Therefore, it is important to stress that my data only contains information on in-house lobbyists, not lobbying firms. Each organization/association had workers listed in one of two separate tabs: in-house government relations personnel and other key personnel. I gathered my lobbyist info from the in-house government relations personnel tab only – the “other key personnel” tab listed people in leadership positions like CEO, CFO, CLO, etc. who are obviously not involved in the day to day activities of lobbyists and are therefore outside the scope of this project. On my first round of data gathering I only collected information on lobbyists that had background data – I did not gather information (names, organizations, sector, etc.) on lobbyists without professional working experience listed on lobbyists.info. But information on the lobbyists without listed working experience is important also – it weights the data I was able to gather on lobbyists with background information and allows for a more complete picture of the revolving door lobbyists’ universe. Thankfully, lobbyists.info has a bulk download feature that will gather the Finance Energy Pharmaceuticals Telecommunications Banking/credit-&- finance/savings-&- loan Energy Pharmaceutical- Industry Telecommunications/Inter net/Cable Banking/finance/inv estments Energy/elect ricity Pharmacology Investments/securit ies-industry Coal Gas Gasoline Nuclear- Energy Petroleum- Industry Fuels-see- coal,-gas,-oil,- petroleum
  • 13. Jameson 13 names and organizations of lobbyists listed by sector. Working backgrounds are not included in the bulk download, but they are not needed in my case because I have the working history of every lobbyist listed in the sectors already. However, bulk downloading is not a perfect solution: it is impossible to differentiate which “tab” someone belongs to (the “in-house government relations personnel” or the “other key personnel” tab) when a bulk download is performed. In the bulk download spreadsheet there is a binary variable representing the Lobbying Disclosure Act (LDA) – a “Y” signifies that the information provided for that lobbyist was gleaned from an LDA, and an “N” signifies that the information provided was gotten from elsewhere. The Lobbying Disclosure Act mandates that lobbyists provide their contact information, their client’s contact information, and a statement about the general issue area that they will be lobbying on to the Clerk of the House of Representatives and the Secretary of the Senate. The LDA is mandatory for all in-house lobbying efforts costing more than $12,500 per economic quarter, therefore most people with a “Y” in the LDA column are also listed on the lobbyists.info site under the “in-house government relations personnel” tab. But unfortunately, not everyone listed under the “in-house government relations personnel” tab disclosed his or her information via an LDA. It is impossible to tell how the lobbyists.info site categorizes someone as a lobbyist who did not disclose their information via an LDA. This makes it impossible for me to get the optimal sample of people: only lobbyists, or those listed as “in-house government relations personnel”. This is less than preferred, but is not excessively detrimental to the validity of my data. In order to account for these differences, I deploy sector-based measures of the revolving door using three different “weighting” groups of lobbyists: 1) just the lobbyists that had background information (the “information group”), 2) the same as the first group with the addition of all bulk downloaded lobbyists that disclosed via an LDA (the “LDA group”), and 3) all personnel listed on the lobbyists.info site which includes non- lobbyists from the “other key personnel” tab (the “all group). I also compare revolving door contamination measures of the top 20 largest firms (ranked by their number of in- house lobbyists) against the rest of the sector across all three weighting groups. It is worth noting that my data does not capture the comprehensive working background of
  • 14. Jameson 14 every currently active lobbyist – the lobbyists.info site, and therefore also my data, is reliant upon the disclosure of lobbyist data via LDAs, interviews, or public online profiles10 . Obviously, it would be best if my data included the background of every active lobbyist, but that is currently unfeasible and unrealistic. This study focuses on the revolving door, or the exchange of professionals between the regulated industry and their regulator. Therefore, the working history of the 3,544 lobbyists in my data is not useful in the raw – certain jobs represent “contamination” via the revolving door, and certain jobs do not. In order for the data to reflect that, I must categorize some jobs as representing “contamination”. First, I coded the job of every lobbyist into one of the following broad categories (please see Figure 2). Figure 2 – Coding Categories 10 LinkedIn profiles were common. Also, many organizations have small bios of their executive level staff on their websites – usually including a picture and professional working experience. House Senate International Judicial Gov't4Agency Interest4Group Military Political4Party Firm Lobbyist PR4Firm State4Gov't Campaign Consulting University White4House Other
  • 15. Jameson 15 Then, I coded each category into one of two groups: private sector or public sector. After that, I broke down the public sector jobs further, many of which are in the following categories: State Gov’t, the White House, Gov’t Agency, Senate, or House. In order to establish a measure of revolving door “contamination”, I coded each job as directly relevant to one of my four sectors, if applicable. A job is directly relevant to a sector if it had regulatory power over that sector. Lobbyists that have worked these jobs are considered “contaminated” by the revolving door. The State Gov’t jobs11 are irrelevant for the purposes of a federal lobbyist, as none of these jobs are directly germane to one of the four sectors. Therefore, no State Gov’t jobs are considered contaminated. Many of the White House positions are also too general to classify as relevant to finance, energy, pharmaceuticals, or telecommunications12 . The remaining jobs in the House of Representatives, the Senate, and Government Agencies were all coded with respect to the four sectors. Specifically, if a government agency were a regulator responsible for one of the four industries (like the Securities and Exchange Commission and finance), it would be coded as contaminated for that industry. Many lobbyists were previously staffers for elected officials in the Senate and House – I treated these jobs as contaminated if the elected official held a position on a committee relevant to the industry that the staffer would later go on to lobby in. For example, if a staffer’s congressperson is a member of the House Financial Services committee, that staffer would be revolving door “contaminated” for the financial sector. Please see Figure 3 for an explanation of how each committee was coded, and why they were coded that way. 11 These consisted almost entirely of tenure in state legislatures. 12 Many had vague titles like “Senior White House Staff” or “Senior White House Legislative Correspondent”
  • 16. Jameson 16 Figure 3 – Congressional Committee Coding Committee Coded(As Justification House&Committee&on&Energy&and& Commerce Pharma,&Energy,& Telecom Jurisdiction&over&the&EPA,&FDA,&and&FCC.&Not& coded&as&finance,&although&they&do&have& jurisdiction&over&the&FTC House&Committee&on&Financial&Services Finance Oversees&the&Fed,&Treasury,&and&SEC House&Judiciary&Subcommittee&on& Courts,&Intellectual&Property&and&the& Internet Telecom Given&administration&of&information& technology&matters&&&the&internet House&Subcommittee&on&Energy&and& Water&Development,&and&Related& Agencies Energy Has&jurisdiction&over&the&budget&for&the&US& Department&of&Energy. House&Transportation&Subcommittee&on& Water&Resources&and&Environment Energy Jurisdiction&over&the&EPA House&Ways&and&Means&Subcommittee& on&Health Pharma Jurisdiction&over&programs&providing& payments&for&health&care&and&related&things House&Committee&on&Natural&Resources Energy Jurisdiction&over&energy&agencies Senate&Appropriations&Subcommittee&on& Agriculture,&Rural&Development,&Food& and&Drug&Administration,&and&Related& Agencies Pharma Jurisdiction&over&the&FDA Senate&Appropriations&Subcommittee&on& Energy&and&Water&Development Energy Jurisdiction&over&the&Department&of&Energy Senate&Appropriations&Subcommittee&on& Energy&and&Water&Development Energy Responsible&for&funding&the&Department&of& Energy,&oversees&the&Nuclear&Regulatory& Commission Senate&Appropriations&Subcommittee&on& Financial&Services&and&General& Government Finance,&Telecom Jurisdiction&over&the&discretionary&spending&of& the&Treasury&Department,&along&with& oversight&on&the&FDIC,&and&the&FCC Senate&Commerce&Subcommittee&on& Communications,&Technology,& Innovation,&and&the&Internet Telecom Legislative&oversight&of&communications& (telephones,&internet,&etc.) Senate&Committee&on&Agriculture,& Nutrition,&and&Forestry Pharma Has&jurisdiction&over&matters&relating&to& nutrition&and&health Senate&Committee&on&Banking,&Housing,& and&Urban&Affairs Finance Jursidiction&over&matters&related&to&banks&and& banking Senate&Committee&on&Commerce,& Science,&and&Transportation Telecom Legislative&oversight&of&communications Senate&Committee&on&Energy&and& Natural&Resources Energy Jurisdiction&over&energy&agencies Senate&Committee&on&Health,&Education,& Labor&and&Pensions Pharma Jurisdiction&over&public&health,&biomedical& research,&etc. Senate&Environment&and&Public&Works& Subcommittee&on&Oversight Energy Jurisdiction&over&the&EPA Senate&Finance&Committee Finance SelfRexplanatory Senate&Finance&Subcommittee&on& Energy,&Natural&Resources,&and& Infrastructure Energy,&Finance Responsible&for&energy&and&finance&policies Senate&Finance&Subcommittee&on&Health& Care Pharma Has&jurisdiction&over&health&care& Senate&Subcommittee&on&Energy,& Science,&and&Technology Energy Has&jurisdiction&over&renewable&energy& programs&and&energy&efficiency&programs House&Appropriations&Subcommittee&on& Labor,&Health&and&Human&Services,& Education,&and&Related&Agencies Pharma Jurisdiction&of&the&Department&of&Health&and& Human&Services House&Committee&on&Science,&Space&and& Technology Energy Jurisdiction&over&the&EPA,&DEP,&etc.
  • 17. Jameson 17 Once every job has been coded, I am able to construct ratios of an individual’s “contaminated” jobs to their “clean”13 jobs, along with the ratio of non-contaminated public sector jobs to contaminated jobs for each individual. The “contaminated to clean” ratio is a good approximation of the revolving door as it compares all the available information on a lobbyist’s jobs to their number of contaminated jobs. A higher ratio here suggests a greater presence of the revolving door in a sector. The ratio of public sector jobs to contaminated jobs, when aggregated by sector, shows how often a lobbyist works contaminated public sector jobs. A higher number here indicates that connected regulation-related workers will tend to move directly to become lobbyists at a higher rate; they may be more affected by the pull of the “exit” side of the revolving door as discussed by Gormley and Cohen, as they waste less time in non-revolving-door- relevant public jobs before becoming a lobbyist. Individual level ratios are aggregated and sorted by sector, and are compared using the three weighting groups mentioned earlier (the “information” group, the “LDA” group, and the “all” group). Findings My data includes the professional working background of 3,546 lobbyists. There are also 2,320 lobbyists that have disclosed via an LDA, and a total of 13,221 people in my database including the bulk downloaded “other key personnel”. All of these lobbyists come from one of 1,613 organizations. Please see Figure 4 for a sector-specific breakdown of the number of lobbyists and organizations in each group, and Figures 5 and 6 for a graphical representation of the organizations per sector and the rate of listed previous employment per sector. Figure 4 – Sector Breakdown of various Lobbyist groups Information Group14 LDA Group All Group Organizations 13 A “clean” job is one that is not contaminated or related to the revolving door. 14 These are the lobbyists that I was able to find information on in the lobbyists.info database.
  • 18. Jameson 18 Finance 793 749 4924 634 Energy 1460 883 4944 619 Pharmaceuticals 713 411 1713 161 Telecommunications 580 277 1640 199 Figure 5 – Sector Breakdown of all organizations in data Organization  Breakdown   Finance   Energy   Pharma   Telecom  
  • 19. Jameson 19 Figure 6 – Sector Breakdown of Lobbyists with listed work experience It is evident that both the financial sector and the energy sector are quite large, containing more lobbyists and more organizations than the pharmaceutical sector and the telecommunications sector. Financial lobbyists disclosed their information via an LDA at a much higher rate than lobbyists from any other sector. Also, there is less “noise” in the pharmaceuticals and telecommunications groups – there are fewer organizations and lobbyists listed yet they have a higher proportion of employment history data. This implies that there are more non-revolving-door-relevant organizations and lobbyists in finance and energy. Non-relevant organizations and lobbyists indicate smaller organizations, which must contract out 100% of their lobbying, as they can not afford in-house lobbyists. These smaller organizations are a function of the nature of the finance and energy sectors compared against the telecommunications and pharmaceutical sectors: there are many small banks or local utility providers, yet there are very few small drug manufacturers or Internet providers. Raw figures are interesting, but they are not the point of this study. There are two revolving door contamination variables representing two different ratios: the first is a Previous  Employment  Information   Finance   Energy   Pharma   Telecom  
  • 20. Jameson 20 ratio of contaminated jobs to non-contaminated jobs15 , and the second is a ratio of contaminated jobs to public sector jobs. These ratios change depending on which of the three weighting groups is used. Examining the ratios for only the lobbyists with employment history listed neglects the varying size of each sector. In order to account for this, I have ratios calculated for each of my three groups – the information group, the LDA group, and the all group. The LDA group partially represents the total amount of lobbyists in each sector. Representation is partial because lobbyists.info lists some people as lobbyists even though they have not disclosed their information with an LDA. Lobbyists.info does not divulge how they determine that these non-LDA people are in fact lobbyists. The all group fixes the gap in the LDA group by including everyone, even lobbyists that did not disclose with an LDA. Unfortunately, the all group also contains many non-lobbying related personnel, which will distort results for sectors with more organizations (finance, energy). The top 20 group controls for the distortion of sectors due to their size, as only the 20 largest organizations from each sector are included. As you can see in Figure 7, there is a wide distribution in the number of lobbyists per organizations, so the top 20 groups are distinct from the rest. 15 Non-contaminated jobs are both private sector jobs and public sector jobs that are not related to the sector that a lobbyist currently works in.
  • 21. Jameson 21 Figure 7 – Distribution of the # of lobbyists per sector Larger organizations should have more revolving door contamination than the smaller organizations outside of the top 20. As Vidal et al. have shown lobbyists with personal connections gained from revolving doors are more valuable than unconnected lobbyists. These lobbyists are paid higher salaries for their services, which is something that larger organizations are more able to afford than many smaller firms. Larger firms will also be able to recruit lobbyists more effectively, due to their size and the notion that better paying jobs at these organizations are more prestigious. Additionally, many smaller firms contract out their lobbying to lobbying firms, which reduces their contamination ratios in my data. Please see Figure 8 for a table containing the top 20 organizations in each sector. 05000500 0 20 40 60 80 0 20 40 60 80 Energy Finance Pharma Telecom Frequency (sum) kount Graphs by sector
  • 22. Jameson 22 Figure 8 – Top 20 Organizations/Associations The contaminated ratios for the lobbyists in the “information” group are highest for the financial sector. Please see Figure 9 for a graph representing the contamination ratios for the lobbyists with professional working experiences listed in my data. The blue variable, “contaminatedtoclean”, represents the ratio of contaminated revolving door jobs to all “clean” jobs, or all private jobs and public jobs not directly relevant to the area Finance Energy Pharmaceuticals Telecommunications Accenture American+Fuel+&+Petrochemical+ Manufacturers Abbott+Laboratories Association+of+Public+Television+ Stations American+Bankers+Association American+Petroleum+Institute American+Society+of+ Consultant+Pharmacists AT&T+Corporation American+Council+of+Life+Insurers+(ACLI) American+Public+Power+ Association Amgen+Inc. AT&T+Services,+Inc. American+Institute+of+Certified+Public+ Accountants BAE+Systems+Inc. AstraZeneca+Pharmaceuticals,+ LP BAE+Systems+Inc. Center+on+Budget+and+Policy+Priorities Biotechnology+Industry+ Organization+(BIO) Biotechnology+Industry+ Organization+(BIO) CenturyLink Citigroup,+Inc. Chevron+U.S.A.,+Inc. BristolLMyers+Squibb+ Company Cisco+Systems+Inc. Cornerstone+Credit+Union+League Edison+Electric+Institute Consumer+Healthcare+ Products+Association Comcast+Corporation Ernst+&+Young+LLP Exelon+Corporation E.I.+du+Pont+de+Nemours+&+ Company+(DuPont) CTIA+L+The+Wireless+Association Independent+Community+Bankers+of+ America Exxon+Mobil+Corporation Eli+Lilly+and+Company eBay+Inc. J.+P.+Morgan+Chase+and+Company General+Electric+Company Express+Scripts,+Inc. Information+Technology+ Industry+Council KPMG+LLP Intel+Corporation GlaxoSmithKline Interactive+Advertising+Bureau Mortgage+Bankers+Association+of+ America International+Business+Machines+ Corporation+(IBM) Healthcare+Distribution+ Management+Association Internet+Corporation+for+ Assigned+Names+and+Numbers+ (ICANN) National+Association+of+Federal+Credit+ Unions National+Electrical+Contractors+ Association Johnson+&+Johnson+Services,+ Inc. Internet+Society National+Association+of+Real+Estate+ Investment+Trusts+(NAREIT) National+Electrical+Manufacturers+ Association Merck+&+Company National+Cable+&+ Telecommunications+ Association PNC+Financial+Services+Group,+Inc. National+Rural+Electric+ Cooperative+Association National+Association+of+Chain+ Drug+Stores National+Telecommunications+ Cooperative+Association PriceWaterhouseCoopers Northrop+Grumman+Corporation National+Community+ Pharmacists+Association Qualcomm+Incorporated Securities+Industry+and+Financial+ Markets+Association+(SIFMA) Nuclear+Energy+Institute Novo+Nordisk,+Inc. Sprint+Nextel+Corporation Textron+Inc. Raytheon+Applied+Signal+ Technology,+Inc. Pfizer+Inc. TLMobile+USA The+Financial+Services+Roundtable Shell+Oil+Company Pharmaceutical+Research+and+ Manufacturers+of+America+ (PhRMA) United+Technologies+ Corporation Wells+Fargo+&+Company Southern+Company Procter+&+Gamble+Company Verizon+Communications
  • 23. Jameson 23 in which a lobbyist is active. The red variable, “contaminatedratio”, represents the ratio of contaminated public sector jobs to non-contaminated public sector jobs. Figure 9 – Contamination including just lobbyists with working history listed When comparing lobbying data disclosed by sector, finance has the highest levels of revolving door contamination measured against all jobs and public sector jobs, though the energy sector and the pharmaceutical sector are not far behind. Using this group, there is little differentiation between the 20 largest firms and the rest of the industry for all sectors – the bulk of the energy industry is slightly less contaminated than the top firms, and the same goes for the pharmaceutical industry albeit to a slightly lesser degree. This is surprising because the top firms should be able to attract more for the lobbyists that have revolving door connections than the smaller firms can with higher salaries and prestige, yet that is not supported by the data. The gap between the contamination variables for the bulk of the pharmaceutical industry is strange – a low 0.05.1.15 Energy Finance Pharma Telecom Energy Finance Pharma Telecom Everyone Else 20 Largest Firms mean of contaminatedtoclean mean of contaminatedratio Graphs by top20
  • 24. Jameson 24 “contaminatedratio” measure yet relatively high “contaminatedtoclean” measure indicates that lobbyists for smaller pharmaceutical firms are less likely to work in non- contaminated public sector jobs when compared to their “top 20” counterparts. These ratios differ when you include more than just lobbyists with listed professional work experience. When all lobbyists that have filed an LDA are included in the study, the financial sector appears much less contaminated. Please see Figure 10 for a graph representing the contaminated ratios for each sector including lobbyists without background information that have filed an LDA. Figure 10 – Contamination including LDA lobbyists The reduction of revolving door contamination in finance is surprising, as is the continued prominence of contamination in the pharmaceutical industry. Again, it is odd that the top 20 firms are, for the most part, less contaminated than the rest of their respective sectors. 0.05.1.15 Energy Finance Pharma Telecom Energy Finance Pharma Telecom Everyone Else 20 Largest Firms mean of contaminatedtoclean mean of contaminatedratio Graphs by top20
  • 25. Jameson 25 These measures change once again when all available data is used. Please see Figure 11 for the average contaminated ratios of each sector when including data on both lobbyists and “other key personnel”. Figure 11 – Contamination including all data This is the only group where the 20 largest firms are all more contaminated than the rest of the industry, but these results are misleading. The lobbyists.info database includes organizations that contract their lobbying out to lobbyist firms, but information on the revolving door contamination of lobbying firms is not included here. There are numerous organizations that do this contracting, most of which are smaller. These small firms contract out their lobbying because they are not large enough to afford in house lobbyists; therefore, all that is listed for these companies in the database is “other key personnel”. There are many of these small firms who list “other key personnel” with zero chance of having a revolving door lobbyist because they do not have any lobbyists on 0.02.04.06 Energy Finance Pharma Telecom Energy Finance Pharma Telecom Everyone Else 20 Largest Firms mean of contaminatedtoclean mean of contaminatedratio Graphs by top20
  • 26. Jameson 26 staff at all. When these “other key personnel” are included, their lack of working history data artificially deflates the average contaminated ratios for each sector. The sources for revolving door contamination are the House, the Senate, and various government regulatory agencies. Each sector has a differing amount of contamination from each source. These sources matter – they reveal a sector’s preferences, as top firms will want as many revolving door lobbyists as possible from the sources that they intend to lobby. Please see Figure 12 for a graph of contamination from the House, Figure 13 for a graph of contamination from the Senate, and Figure 14 for a graph of contamination from an agency, all weighted by the “all” group. Figure 12 – Contamination from House (All) 0.1.2.3 Energy Finance Pharma Telecom Energy Finance Pharma Telecom Everyone Else 20 Largest Firms mean of contaminatedtoclean mean of contaminatedratio Graphs by top20
  • 27. Jameson 27 Figure 13 – Contamination from Senate (All) Figure 14 – Contamination from Agency (all) 0.1.2.3.4 Energy Finance Pharma Telecom Energy Finance Pharma Telecom Everyone Else 20 Largest Firms mean of contaminatedtoclean mean of contaminatedratio Graphs by top20 0.2.4.6 Energy Finance Pharma Telecom Energy Finance Pharma Telecom Everyone Else 20 Largest Firms mean of contaminatedtoclean mean of contaminatedratio Graphs by top20
  • 28. Jameson 28 The differences in these three graphs are striking. First, it is interesting to note that these are the only graphs where the red “contaminatedratio” variable is sometimes larger than the blue “contaminatedtoclean” variable. These larger red bars indicate that lobbyists from the Senate or a regulatory agency spend little time in other public sector jobs. More importantly, this data shows the differing sector preferences for revolving door contamination. Top financial firms place a premium on former government regulators, yet top energy related organizations have seemingly no interest in former regulators. Top pharmaceutical organizations clearly covet lobbyists with backgrounds in the Senate, while top energy firms desire connections in the House. Conclusion The data presented in this study holds crucial implications for our understanding of the revolving door. There is no doubt that legislative revolving door lobbyists are valued for their connections and that this value is expressed as higher salaries paid by organizations for lobbyists with those connections (Vidal, Draca, and Fons-Rosen 2012). But this is an incomplete description; organizations do not desire just any revolving door connections. My data, which includes legislative as well as other sources of revolving door contamination, supports a more nuanced understanding of the dynamics of the revolving door. If organizations valued all revolving door connections equally, then the data would show that the top 20 firms in each sector are much more contaminated by the revolving door than the smaller firms, as the top firms are better able to recruit these lobbyists with higher salaries, better benefits, and a sense of prestige. My data shows that quite often, smaller firms have the same or a greater amount of revolving door contamination. In addition, my data shows that a sector’s demand for revolving door connections is not broad and unfocused, as is often conjectured. There is overwhelming demand from top financial organizations for regulatory agency-based revolving door connections, whereas there is very little demand for the same types of connections from top energy companies. Understanding this variation is important – we should not think of all revolving door connections as equal, as clearly firms do not. Top financial firms value agency-based revolving door
  • 29. Jameson 29 connections because their regulatory agencies are simultaneously powerful and collegial. On one hand, agencies like the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) and the Federal Reserve (Fed) wield great power over the financial sector, yet they also seek input from the industry when creating new laws16 . Conversely, Congress rarely passes financial laws as they are too complex and they are more wary of being seen as too friendly towards bankers. Even the Dodd-Frank Act, Congress’s hallmark piece of financial legislation, focused on changes to be undertaken by regulatory agencies17 . Therefore it makes sense that top financial firms would prefer agency connections: the agencies play the largest role in shaping their regulatory environment and they provide opportunity for influence. The case for the energy sector is completely opposite: the EPA is notorious for butting heads with their industry, even as some critics complain that the agency no longer has teeth. In addition, Congress can, and does, pass standalone energy related legislation18 . Why would the energy sector bother trying to influence an ineffective, uncooperative agency when they could spend that time and money lobbying Congress, which is both effective and open to influence? Wide, generalized conclusions about the revolving door understate the variation in revolving door demand from various organizations in different sectors of the economy. In order to further expand our knowledge of the revolving door, future research could focus on the relationship between a firm or organization’s level of lobbying success and their level of revolving door contamination. Do larger firms need more revolving door connections to be successful, or do they just have them because they are able to get them? Are smaller firms more effective at lobbying than larger firms if 16 For example, the SEC actually invites people and organizations to comment on proposed rule changes. You can submit comments very easily, right on their website: https://www.sec.gov/rules/submitcomments.htm 17 Congress delegated changes to be made to the agencies instead of directly making changes themselves – why waste time lobbying Congress then if the agencies will be the ones to implement the final rules? 18 Examples: H.R. 527(113th ) is a passed bill finalizing the privatization of the Federal helium reserve, H.R. 678(113th ) authorized many federal facilities for hydropower development, and H.R. 5057(113th ) provided exemptions for certain power supplies from efficiency standards.
  • 30. Jameson 30 they both have similar revolving door contamination levels? Qualitative research on firm or organization’s attitudes towards the revolving door would also be fascinating. Do top financial organizations internally acknowledge that they target agency-related revolving door lobbyists? Finally, further study is required on lobbyists that are members of lobbying firms, which are not included at all in my data or analysis.
  • 31. Jameson 31 Bibliography Baker, Andrew. 2010. “Restraining Regulatory Capture? Anglo-America, Crisis Politics and Trajectories of Change in Global Financial Governance.” International Affairs 86 (3): 647–63. Cohen, Jeffrey E. 1986. “The Dynamics of the ‘Revolving Door’ on the FCC.” American Journal of Political Science 30 (4): 689–708. Eckert, Ross D. 1981. “Life Cycle of Regulatory Commissioners, The.” JL & Econ. 24: 113. Gormley, William T. 1979. “A Test of the Revolving Door Hypothesis at the FCC.” American Journal of Political Science 23 (4): 665–83. Johnson, Simon. 2009. “The Quiet Coup.” The Atlantic 52: 1. Makkai, Toni, and John Braithwaite. 1992. “In and out of the Revolving Door: Making Sense of Regulatory Capture.” Journal of Public Policy 12 (1): 61–78. McKay, Amy. 2012. “Buying Policy? The Effects of Lobbyists’ Resources on Their Policy Success.” Political Research Quarterly 65 (4): 908–23. Quirk, Paul J. 2014. Industry Influence in Federal Regulatory Agencies. Princeton University Press. Shive, Sophie, and Margaret Forster. 2013. “The Revolving Door for Financial Regulators.” SSRN Working Paper Series, November. doi:http://dx.doi.org.silk.library.umass.edu/10.2139/ssrn.2348968. United States Census Bureau. 1992. Economic Census. Section 483, Broadcasting and Cable Services. United States Census Bureau. Vidal, Jordi Blanes I, Mirko Draca, and Christian Fons-Rosen. 2012. “Revolving Door Lobbyists.” The American Economic Review 102 (7): 3731–48. doi:10.1257/aer.102.7.3731.