SlideShare une entreprise Scribd logo
1  sur  66
Télécharger pour lire hors ligne
Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and
the failure of the minimum-variance hedging
Artur Sepp
Global Risk Analytics
Bank of America Merrill Lynch, London
artur.sepp@baml.com
Global Derivatives Trading & Risk Management 2014
Amsterdam
May 13-15, 2014
1
Plan
1) Empirical evidence for the log-normality of implied and realized volatil-
ities of stock indices
2) Apply the beta stochastic volatility (SV) model for quantifying implied
and realized index skews
3) Origin of the premium for risk-neutral skews and its impacts on profit-
and-loss (P&L) of delta-hedging strategies
4) Optimal delta-hedging strategies to improve Sharpe ratios
5) Argue why log-normal beta SV model is better than its alternatives
2
References
Technical details can be found in references
Beta stochastic volatility model:
Karasinski, P., Sepp, A., (2012), “Beta stochastic volatility model,” Risk,
October, 67-73
http://ssrn.com/abstract=2150614
Sepp, A. (2013), “Consistently Modeling Joint Dynamics of Volatility and
Underlying To Enable Effective Hedging”, Global Derivatives conference
in Amsterdam 2013
http://math.ut.ee/~spartak/papers/PresentationGlobalDerivatives2013.pdf
Implied and realized skews, jumps, delta-hedging P&L:
Sepp, A., (2014), “Empirical Calibration and Minimum-Variance Delta
Under Log-Normal Stochastic Volatility Dynamics”
http://ssrn.com/abstract=2387845
Sepp, A., (2014), “Log-Normal Stochastic Volatility Model: Pricing of
Vanilla Options and Econometric Estimation”
http://ssrn.com/abstract=2522425
Optimal delta-hedging strategies:
Sepp, A., (2013), “When You Hedge Discretely: Optimization of Sharpe
Ratio for Delta-Hedging Strategy under Discrete Hedging and Transaction
Costs,” Journal of Investment Strategies 3(1), 19-59
http://ssrn.com/abstract=1865998 3
How to build a dynamic model for volatility?
Suppose we know nothing about stochastic volatility
We want to learn only by looking at empirical data
How do we start?
4
Empirical frequency of implied vol is log-normal
First, check whether stationary distribution of volatility is:
A) Normal or B) Log-normal
Compute the empirical frequency of one-month implied at-the-money
(ATM) volatility proxied by the VIX index for last 20 years
Daily observations normalized to have zero mean and unit variance
Left figure: empirical frequency of the VIX - it is definitely not normal
Right figure: the frequency of the logarithm of the VIX - it does look
like the normal density (especially for the right tail)!
3%
4%
5%
6%
7%
Frequency
Empirical frequency of
normalized VIX
Empirical
Standard Normal
0%
1%
2%
-4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4
Frequency
VIX
3%
4%
5%
6%
7%
Frequency
Empirical frequency of
normalized logarithm of the VIX
Empirical
Standard Normal
0%
1%
2%
3%
-4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4
Frequency
Log-VIX
5
Empirical frequency of realized vol is log-normal
Compute one-month realized volatility of daily returns on the S&P 500
index for each month over non-overlapping periods for last 60 years from
1954
Below is the empirical frequency of normalized historical volatility
Left figure: frequency of realized vol - it is definitely not normal
Right figure: frequency of the logarithm of realized vol - again it does
look like the normal density (especially for the right tail)
4%
6%
8%
10%
Frequency
Frequency of Historic 1m
Volatility of S&P500 returns
Empirical
Standard Normal
0%
2%
4%
-4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4
Frequency
Vol
4%
6%
8%
10%
Frequency
Frequency of Logarithm of
Historic 1m Volatility of S&P500
Empirical
Standard Normal
0%
2%
4%
-4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4
FrequencyLog-Vol
6
Dynamic model for volatility evolution should
not be based on price-volatility correlation
Now we look for a dynamic factor model for volatility (next slide)
We cannot apply model based on correlation between S&P500 returns
and changes in volatility because using correlation we can only predict
the direction of change, not the magnitude of change
For risk management of options, we need a factor model for volatility
dynamics
7
Factor model for volatility uses regression model for
changes in vol V (tn) predicted by returns in price S(tn)
V (tn) − V (tn−1) = β
S(tn) − S(tn−1)
S(tn−1)
+ V (tn−1) n (1)
iid normal residuals n are scaled by vol V (tn−1) due to log-normality
Volatility beta β explains about 70% of variations in volatility!
Left figure: scatter plot of daily changes in the VIX vs returns on S&P
500 for past 14 years and estimated regression model
Right: time series of empirical residuals n of regression model (1)
Residual volatility does not exhibit any systemic patterns
Regression model is stable across different estimation periods
y = -1.08x
R² = 67%
0%
5%
10%
15%
20%
-10% -5% 0% 5% 10%
ChangeinVIX
Change in VIX vs Return on S&P500
-20%
-15%
-10%
-5%-10% -5% 0% 5% 10%
Return % on S&P 500
-10%
0%
10%
20%
30% Time Series of Residual Volatility
-30%
-20%
Dec-99
Dec-00
Jan-02
Jan-03
Jan-04
Jan-05
Jan-06
Jan-07
Jan-08
Jan-09
Jan-10
Jan-11
Jan-12
Jan-13
Volatility beta β: expected change in ATM vol predicted by price return
For return of −1%: expected change in vol = −1.08 × (−1%) = 1.08%8
More evidence on log-normal dynamics of vol: indepen-
dence of regression parameters on level of ATM vol
Estimate empirically the elasticity α of volatility by:
1) computing volatility beta and residual vol-of-vol for each month using
daily returns within this month
2) test if the logarithm of these variables depends on the log of the VIX
in that month using regression model
Left figure: test ˆβ(V ) = βV α by regression model: ln ˆβ(V ) = α ln V + c
Right: test ˆε(V ) = εV 1+α by regression model: ln |ˆε(V )| = (1+α) ln V +c
The estimated value of elasticity α is small and statistically insignificant
Indeed the realized volatility is close to log-normal
y = 0.15x + 0.14
R² = 2%
-0.5
0.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
ln(|VIXbeta|)
ln(VIX beta) vs ln(Average VIX)
-1.5
-1.0
-0.5
-2.5 -2.0 -1.5 -1.0 -0.5 0.0
ln(|VIXbeta|)
ln(Average VIX)
y = 0.14x - 0.45
R² = 4%
-0.5
0.0
0.5
ln(|VIXresidualvol)
ln(VIX residualvol) vs ln(AverageVIX)
-1.5
-1.0
-2.5 -2.0 -1.5 -1.0 -0.5 0.0
ln(|VIXresidualvol)
ln(Average VIX)
9
Empirical estimation of volatility elasticity α:
volatility dynamics is log-normal
(maximum likelihood estimation - see my paper on log-normal volatility)
Figure: 95% confidence bounds for estimated value of elasticity α using
realized (RV) and implied (IV) volatilities for 4 major stock indices
-1.0
-0.5
0.0
0.5
1.0
Alpha
95% confidence bounds for
estimated elasticity alpha
-1.0
VIX,Reg
VSTOXX,Reg
VIX,ML
VSTOXX,ML
IV,S&P500
IV,FTSE100
IV,NIKKEI
IV,STOXX50
RV,S&P500
RV,FTSE100
RV,NIKKEI
RV,STOXX50
Estimation results confirm evidence for log-normality of volatility:
[i] In majority of cases (7 out of 12), bounds for ˆα contain zero
[ii] One outlier ˆα = −0.4 (realized volatility of Nikkei index)
[iii] Remaining are symmetric: two with ˆα ≈ 0.2 and two with ˆα ≈ −0.2
To conclude - alternative SV models are safely rejected:
1) Heston and Stein-Stein SV models with α = −1
2) 3/2 SV model with α = 1
Also, excellent econometric study by Christoffersen-Jacobs-Mimouni (2010),
Review of Financial Studies: log-normal SV outperforms its alternatives10
Beta stochastic volatility model (Karasinski-Sepp 2012):
is obtained by summarizing our empirical findings for
dynamics of index price S(t) and volatility V (t):
dS(t) = V (t)S(t)dW(0)(t)
dV (t) = β
dS(t)
S(t)
+ εV (t)dW(1)(t) + κ(θ − V (t))dt
(2)
V (t) is either returns vol or short-term ATM implied vol
W(0)(t) and W(1)(t) are independent Brownian motions
β is volatility beta - sensitivity of volatility to changes in price
ε is residual vol-of-vol - standard deviation of residual changes in vol
Mean-reversion rate κ and mean θ are added for stationarity of volatility
A closer inspection shows that these dynamics are similar to other log-
normal based SV models widely used in industry:
A) in interest rates - SABR model
B) in equities - a version of log-normal based aka exp-OU SV models
We arrived to beta SV model (2) only by looking at empirical data
for realized&implied vols and using factor model for vol dynamics
11
Implied interpretation of volatility beta and residual vol-
of-vol from Black-Scholes-Merton (BSM) volatilities, σBSM(z) as func-
tions of log-strike z = ln(K/S), inferred form option prices
Compute vol skew SKEW and convexity CONV for small maturities:
SKEW = [σBSM(5%) − σBSM(−5%)] / (2 × 5%)
CONV = [σBSM(5%) + σBSM(−5%) − 2σBSM(0)] / 5%2
Volatility beta β[I] implied by skew:
β[I]
= 2 × SKEW
Residual vol-of-vol ε[I] implied by convexity:
ε[I]
= 3 × σBSM(0) × CONV + 2 × (SKEW)2
As model parameters, volatility beta (left figure) and idiosyncratic vol-
of-vol (right figure) have orthogonal impact on BSM implied vols
15%
25%
35%
BSMimpliedvols
Impact of volatility beta on BSM vol
Base vols with beta = -1
Down vols with beta = -0.5
Up vols with beta = -1.5
5%
15%
0.7 0.78 0.86 0.94 1.02 1.1
BSMimpliedvols
Strike
15%
25%
35%
BSMimpliedvols
Impact of residual vol-vol on BSM vol
Base vols with ResidVol=1.0
Down vols with ResidVol=0.5
Up vols with ResidVol=1.5
5%
15%
0.70 0.78 0.86 0.94 1.02 1.10
BSMimpliedvols
Strike
12
Topic II: Implied and realized skew using beta SV model
Use time series from April 2007 to December 2013 for one-month ATM
vols and the S&P500 index with estimation window of one month
Figure 1): Implied and realized one
month volatilities
ATM volatility tends to trade at
a small premium to realized
Figure 2): One-month average of
implied and realized volatility beta
Implied volatility beta consis-
tently over-estimates realized one
Figure 3): Average of implied and
realized residual vol-of-vol
Implied residual vol-of-vol signifi-
cantly over-estimates realized
Absolute (Abs) and relative (Rel)
spreads between implieds&realizeds
Spreads Vol Beta VolVol
Abs, Mean 0.51% -0.27 0.78
Abs, Stdev 6.2% 0.21 0.16
Rel, Mean 7% 21% 57%
Rel, Stdev 24% 17% 11%
20%
30%
40%
50%
60%
70%
80% 1m ATM Implied Volatility
1m Realized Volatility
0%
10%
20%
Feb-07
Sep-07
Apr-08
Nov-08
Jun-09
Jan-10
Aug-10
Mar-11
Oct-11
May-12
Dec-12
Jul-13
-0.5
0.0
Feb-07
Sep-07
Apr-08
Nov-08
Jun-09
Jan-10
Aug-10
Mar-11
Oct-11
May-12
Dec-12
Jul-13
Implied Volatility Beta
Realized Volatility Beta
-2.0
-1.5
-1.0
0.5
0.8
1.1
1.4
1.7 Implied Residual Vol-of-Vol
Realized Residual Vol-of-Vol
0.2
0.5
Feb-07
Sep-07
Apr-08
Nov-08
Jun-09
Jan-10
Aug-10
Mar-11
Oct-11
May-12
Dec-12
Jul-13
13
Explanation of the skew premium in a quantitative way
In a very interesting study, Bakshi-Kapadia-Madan (2003), Review of
Financial Studies, find relationship between risk-neutral and physical skew
using investor’s risk-aversion
Fat tails (not necessarily skewed) of returns distribution under phys-
ical measure P along with risk-aversion lead to increased negative
skeweness under the risk neutral-measure Q
Quantitatively:
SKEWENESSQ = SKEWENESSP − γ × KURTOSISP × VOLATILITYP
SKEWENESSQ is risk-neutral skeweness of price returns
SKEWENESSP is physical skeweness of price returns
KURTOSISP is kurtosis as measure of fat tails of physical distribution
VOLATILITYP is volatility of returns under physical distribution
γ > 0 is risk-aversion parameter of investors
To conclude: the risk-neutral premium arises because risk-averse
investors assign higher value to insurance puts
Important: Volatility skew is proportional to skeweness of returns
14
Apply Merton Jump-Diffusion (JD) with normal jumps
Figure 1: Use last 14 years of daily returns on S&P 500 index to estimate
skeweness and kurtosis of returns - see column ”Empirical P”
Table 1: Use γ = 22.0 (estimated from time series of implied vols by
inverting BKM formula) and apply BKM to obtain SKEWENESSQ = −2
Figure&Table 2: Fit Merton JD to first four moments of physical and
risk-neutral distribution (jump frequency is set to one jump per month)
From calibration: JumpMean is 0 under empirical P and -5% under Q
Empirical P Q
Stdev 21% 21%
Skeweness 0 -2
Kurtosis 8 8
Merton JD params P Q
Jump Mean 0% -5%
Jump Volatility 4% 0%
Diffusion vol 17% 13%
Jump Frequency 12 12
Figure 3: Value one month options - implied volatility from Merton JD
under Q is skewed, while implied volatility under P is symmetric
4%
6%
8%
10%
Frequency
Frequency of S&P500 daily returns
Empirical
Frequency
Normal Density
0%
2%
4%
-9% -7% -5% -4% -2% 0% 2% 4% 6% 7%
Frequency
Daily return
4%
6%
8%
10%
Frequency
Frequency of S&P500 daily returns
Empirical
Frequency
Physical Merton
under P
Risk-Neutral
0%
2%
4%
-9% -7% -5% -4% -2% 0% 2% 4% 6% 7%
Frequency
Daily return
Risk-Neutral
Merton under Q
25%
30%
ImpliedVol
Implied volatility skew for one
month options on S&P500
Physical Merton under P
Risk-Neutral Merton under Q
15%
20%
0.75 0.85 0.95 1.05 1.15 1.25
ImpliedVol
Strike
15
To summarize our developments so far:
1) Log-normal beta SV model is consistent with empirical distribu-
tion for realized and implied vols
2) Beta SV model is applied to quantify realized and implied skews
and the spread between them, which turns out to be significant
Any option position is mark-to-market so no point of arguing about
market prices
However, hedging strategy is discretionary and can be the ”edge”
By computing the delta-hedge: should we use implied or realized
skews?
This question is analyzed in the third topic of my talk:
Part I - Quantitative analysis of impact of realized and implied skews on
delta-hedging P&L
Part II - Monte-Carlo simulations for empirical analysis
16
Statistically significant spread between realized and im-
plied skews β[R] − β[I] leads to dependence on realized
price returns and invalidates the minimum-variance hedge
Minimum-variance delta ∆ is applied to hedge against changes in price
and price-induced changes in volatility
Given hedging portfolio Π for option U on S
Π(t, S, V ) = U(t, S, V ) − ∆ × S
∆ is computed by minimizing variance of Π using SV beta dynamics (2)
under risk-neutral measure Q (classic approach) with implied vol betaβ[I]
∆ = US + β[I] × UV /S
where US and UV model delta and vega
To see dependence on return δS due to spread between implied vol beta
β[I] and realized β[R]: given δS apply beta SV for change in vol δV under
physical measure P:
δV = β[R] × δS + ε[R] × V
√
δt
By Taylor expansion of realized P&L:
δΠ(t, S, V ) = β[R] − β[I] × UV × δS + ε[R] × UV × V
√
δt + O(dt)
ε(R) is random non-hedgable part from residual vol-of-vol
O(dt) part includes quadratic terms (δS)2, (δV )2, (δS)(δV )
17
Volatility skew-beta is important for computing correct
option delta
Figure 1) Apply regression model
(1) for time series of ATM vols for
maturities T = {1m, 3m, 6m, 12m, 24m}
(m=month) to estimate regression
volatility beta βREGRES(T) using
S&P500 returns:
δσATM(T) = βREGRES(T) × δS
Volatility beta for SV dynamics is in-
stantaneous beta for very small T
Regression vol beta decays in log-T
due to mean-reversion: long-dated
ATM vols are less sensitive in abso-
lute values to price-returns
Figure 2) Implied vol skew for ma-
turity T has similar decay in log-T
Figure 3) Volatility skew-beta is
regression beta divided by skew
Skew-Beta(T) ∝ βREGRES(T)/SKEW(T)
It is nearly maturity-homogeneous
y = 0.19*ln(x) - 0.37
R² = 99%
-0.6
-0.4
-0.2
0.0 Regression Volatility Beta(T)
-1.0
-0.8
-0.6
0.08 0.25 0.50 1.00 2
Maturity T
Regression Vol Beta(T)
Decay of Vol Beta in ln(T)
y = 0.16*ln(x) - 0.29
R² = 99%
-0.4
-0.2
0.0 Implied Volatility Skew (T)
-0.8
-0.6
1m 3m 6m 1y 2y
Maturity, T
Vol Skew (T)
Decay of Skew in ln(T)
y = 0.06*ln(x) + 1.41
R² = 80%1.0
1.5
2.0 Volatility Skew-Beta(T)
Vol Skew-Beta (T)
0.0
0.5
1m 3m 6m 1y 2y
Maturity T
Vol Skew-Beta (T)
Decay of Vol Skew-Beta in ln(T)
18
Technical supplement to compute model implied skew-
beta (omitted during the talk)
Using backward pricers and PDE:
1) Compute the term structure of ATM volatility σATM(S0; T) and skew
SKEW(S0; T), with strike width α%, implied by model parameters
2) Bump the spot price down by α%, S1 = (1 − α%)S0, and apply corre-
sponding bumping rule for model state variables
For the beta SV:
V1 → V0 + βα , θ → θ +
β
2κ
α (3)
3) Compute new term structure of ATM vols σATM(S1; T)
4) Compute model implied skew-beta
Skew-Beta(T) = −
σATM(S1; T) − σATM(S0; T)
α × SKEW(S0; T)
(4)
Using Monte-Carlo pricers:
1) Specify number of paths and simulate set of independent Brownians
2) Compute paths starting from {S0, V0}
2A) Evaluate term structure of ATM volatility σATM(K = S0; T) and
skew using σ(K = S1; T), both using Brownians in 1)
3) Compute paths starting from {S1, V1} with S1 = (1 − α%)S0 and V (1)
bumped as in Eq (3), using Brownians in 1)
4) Evaluate ATM vols σATM(K = S1; T) and skew-beta by Eq (4) 19
Volatility and Skew contribution to P&L - important for
volatility positions with daily mark-to-market!
Mark BSM implied vol σBSM(K) in %-strike K relative to price S(0):
σBSM(K; S) = σATM(S) + SKEW × Z(K; S)
Z(K; S) is log-moneyness relative to current price S:
Z(K; S) = ln (K × S(0)/S)
SKEW < 0 is inferred from spread between call and put implied vols
In practice, this form is augmented with extras for convexity and tails
Any SV model implies quadratic form for implied vols near ATM strikes
(Lewis 2000, Bergomi-Guyon 2012) so my approach for vol P&L is generic
Volatility P&L arises from change in spot price S → S {1 + δS}:
δσBSM(K; S) ≡ σBSM (K; S {1 + δS}) − σBSM(K; S)
= δσATM(S) + SKEW × δZ(K; S)
First contributor to P&L: change in ATM vol δσATM(S):
δσATM(S) = σATM (S {1 + δS}) − σATM(S)
Second contributor to P&L: change in log-moneyness relative to skew:
δZ(K; S) = − ln(1 + δS) ≈ −δS
20
Example of volatility and skew P&L with regression beta
(omitted during the talk)
σATM(S(0)) = 15%, δS = −1.0%, SKEW = −0.5, βREGRESS = −1.0
It is very important how we keep log-moneyness Z(K; S):
1) For strikes re-based to new ATM level (forward-based strikes):
S → S{1 + δS} and log-moneyness does not change δZ(K; S) = 0
P&L arises from change in ATM vol predicted by price return com-
puted using βREGRESS:
δσBSM(K) = βREGRESS × δS = −1.0 × −1% = 1%
2) For strikes fixed at old ATM level (vanilla strikes with fixed S(0))
Thus log-moneyness changes by δZ(K; S) ≈ −δS = 1%
P&L is change in ATM vol adjusted for change in money-ness:
δσBSM(K) = βREGRESS ×δS+SKEW×δS = 1%+(−0.5)×(1%) = 0.50%
0.5%
0.8%
1.0%
Change in vols, strikes fixed to ATM 0
Change in vols, strikes re-based to ATM 1
0.0%
0.3%
0.5%
90% 95% 100% 105%
Strike K%
18%
21%
BSMvol(K)
BSM vol 0, strikes fixed to ATM 0
BSM vol 1, strikes fixed to ATM 0
BSM vol 1, strikes re-based to ATM 1
12%
15%
90% 95% 100% 105%
BSMvol(K)
Strike K%
21
Changes in skew are not correlated to changes in price
and ATM vols - important for correct predict of vol and skew P&L
Empirical observations yet again confirm log-normality dynamics!
(Using S&P500 data from January 2007 to December 2013)
Figure 1: weekly changes in 100% − 95% skew vs price returns for
maturity of one month (left) and one year (right)
Regression slope = 0.13 (1m) & 0.03 (1y); R2 = 0% (1m) & 1% (1y)
-0.1
0
0.1
0.2
0.3
ChangeinSkew
Change in 1m skew vs Price Return
y = 0.13x - 0.00
R² = 0%
-0.3
-0.2
-0.1
-15% -5% 5% 15%
ChangeinSkew
Price return
y = 0.03x - 0.00
-0.02
0
0.02
0.04
ChangeinSkew
Change in 1y skew vs Price Return
y = 0.03x - 0.00
R² = 1%
-0.06
-0.04
-0.02
-15% -5% 5% 15%
ChangeinSkew
Price return
Figure 2: weekly changes in 100% − 95% skew vs changes in ATM
vols for maturity of one month (left) and one year (right)
Regression slope = −0.15 (1m) & −0.06 (1y); R2 = 0% (1m) & 2% (1y)
-0.1
0
0.1
0.2
0.3
ChangeinSkew
Change in 1m skew vs 1m ATM vol
y = -0.15x - 0.00
R² = 0%-0.3
-0.2
-0.1
-15% -5% 5% 15%
ChangeinSkew
Change in ATM vol
-0.02
0
0.02
0.04
ChangeinSkew
Change in 1y skew vs 1y ATM vol
y = -0.09x - 0.00
R² = 2%
-0.06
-0.04
-0.02
-15% -5% 5% 15%
ChangeinSkew
Change in ATM vol
22
Volatility skew-beta combines the skew and volatility
P&L together
Given price return δS:
S → S {1 + δS}
Volatility P&L is computed by:
1) For strikes re-based to new ATM level
Log-moneyness does not change, δZ(K; S) = 0
P&L follows change in ATM vol predicted by regression beta and vol
skew-beta:
δσBSM(K) ≡ δσATM(S) = βREGRESS × δS
= SKEWBETA × SKEW × δS
2) For strikes fixed at old ATM level
Log-moneyness changes by δZ(K; S) ≈ −δS
P&L is change in ATM vol adjusted for skew P&L:
δσBSM(K) ≡ δσATM(S) − SKEW × δS
= [SKEWBETA − 1] × SKEW × δS
Positive change in ATM vol from negative return is reduced by
skew
23
Volatility skew-beta under minimum-variance approach
is applied to compute min-var delta ∆ for hedging against
changes in price and price-induced changes in implied vol
A) We adjust option delta for change in implied vol at fixed strikes
B) The adjustment is proportional to option vega at this strike:
∆(K, T) = ∆BSM(K, T) + [SKEWBETA(T) − 1] × SKEW(T) × VBSM(K, T)/
∆BSM(K, T) is BSM delta for strike K and maturity T
VBSM(K, T) is BSM vega, both evaluated at volatility skew
I classify volatility regimes using vol skew-beta for delta-adjustments:
∆(K, T) =



∆BSM(K, T) + SKEW(T) × VBSM(K, T)/S, Sticky local
∆BSM(K, T), Sticky strike
∆BSM(K, T) − SKEW(T) × VBSM(K, T)/S, Sticky delta
∆BSM(K, T) + 1
2SKEW(T) × VBSM(K, T)/S, Empirical S&P50
”Shadow” delta is obtained using ratio O (may be different from 1/2):
∆(K, T) = ∆BSM(K, T) + O × SKEW(T) × VBSM(K, T)/S
which is traders’ ad-hoc adjustment of option delta
24
Does ”shadow” delta create a vision or an illusion?
We need a quantitative model to describe different volatility
regimes and produce correct option delta !
25
Volatility skew-beta and vol regimes (also see Bergomi 2009):
SkewBeta =



2, Sticky local regime: minimum-variance delta in SV and LV
1, Sticky strike regime: BSM delta evaluated at implied skew
0, Sticky delta regime: model delta in space-homogeneous SV
Empirical estimates for skew-beta and its lower and upper bounds are
found by regression model (see my paper)
In beta SV model, with empirical estimate of vol beta and adding jumps/risk-
aversion to match skew premium, we fit empirical vol skew-beta:
1) S&P 500: empirical skew-beta of about 1.5
2) STOXX 50: strong skew-beta close to 2
3) NIKKEI: weak skew-beta is about 0.5
As result: beta SV model with jumps can produce the correct delta!
1.00
1.50
2.00
2.50
Vol Skew-Beta for S&P500
SVJ Skew-Beta with empirical beta
0.00
0.50
1m
3m
5m
7m
9m
11m
13m
15m
17m
19m
21m
23m
T in months
SVJ Skew-Beta with empirical beta
Sticky local with Min-var delta
Empirical bounds
1.00
1.50
2.00
2.50
Vol Skew-Beta for STOXX 50
SVJ Skew-Beta with empirical beta
0.00
0.50
1m
3m
5m
7m
9m
11m
13m
15m
17m
19m
21m
23m
T in months
SVJ Skew-Beta with empirical beta
Sticky local with Min-var delta
Empirical bounds
1.00
1.50
2.00
2.50
Vol Skew-Beta for NIKKEI
SVJ Skew-Beta with empirical beta
Sticky local with Min-var delta
Empirical bounds
0.00
0.50
1m
3m
5m
7m
9m
11m
13m
15m
17m
19m
21m
23m
T in months
26
Second part of topic III: Monte Carlo analysis of delta-
hedging P&L
Now let’s have some fun and do some number crunching!
We are going to simulate the market dynamics and compare hedging
performance under different specifications of delta
In next few slides I briefly discuss the methodology
Details are provided for the interested for self-studying
Details are important to understand how to improve the performance of
delta-hedging strategies
Application to actual market data produces equivalent conclusions
In my talk, I will only discuss final results and conclusions
27
Apply beta SV for dynamics under physical measure P:
1) Index price S(t),
2) Volatility of returns Vret(t):
3) Short-term implied volatility Vimp(t):
dS(t) = Vret(t)S(t)dW(0)(t)
dVret(t) = κ[P] θ[P] − Vret(t) dt + β[P]Vret(t)dW(0)(t) + ε[P]Vret(t)dW(1)(t)
dVimp(t) = κ[I] θ[I] − Vimp(t) dt + β[I]Vimp(t)dW(0)(t) + ε[I]Vret(t)dW(1)(t)
4) At-the-money (ATM) implied vol Vatm(t) is obtained by computing
model implied ATM vol for maturity T using model dynamics for Vimp(t)
Important: Model parameters are estimated from time series by
maximum likelihood methods - as a rule, parameters for returns vol
[P] and for implied vol [I] are different
Here, apply the same parameters for clarity
Physical for Returns dVret(t), [P] Vol dVimp(t), [I]
V.(0) 16% 16.75%
θ[.] 16% 16.75%
κ[.] 3.0 3.0
ε[.] 0.5 0.5
β[.] -1.0 -1.0
28
Volatility and skew premiums are produced using BSM implied
volatility, σBSM(K), as function of % strike K relative to S(0):
σBSM(K) = Vatm(t) + SKEW × ln (K × S(0)/S(t)) (5)
SKEW = −0.5 is vol implied skew specified exogenously by
strike % BSM vol σBSM(K) σBSM(K) − Vret(0)
99% 17.25% 1.25%
100% 16.75% 0.75%
101% 16.25% 0.25%
Market Skew -0.50
Important - option delta is computed using two models:
1) Beta SV model with market implied beta β[I] = -1.1
2) Beta SV model with empirical beta β[I] = -1.0 and jumps (risk-
aversion) to price-in excessive skew −1.1 − 1.0 = −0.1 (discussed later)
Both SV models fit to market skew exactly!
[i] Premium of implied vol to realized vol is:
16.75% − 16% = 0.75% (in line with empirical spread)
[ii] Premium of implied and empirical beta is:
β[I] − β[R] = -1.1 − ( -1.0 ) = -0.1 (empirical is about −0.2)
As we saw using Madan-Merton fits, physical dynamics don’t need to
have asymmetric jumps to produce skew premium - now, skew premium
arises from excess kurtosis produced by empirical SV model for returns29
Consistency with market skew does not guar-
antee fit to empirical dynamics
Both hedging models are consistent with market implied skew
However, we observe discrepancy:
SV model with market implied beta,called Minimum variance hedge
Implies vol skew-beta about 2.0 , which is inconsistent with empirical
dynamics
SV model with jumps and empirical beta, called Empirical hedge:
Implies vol skew-beta about 1.6 , which is consistent with empirical
dynamics
Important - no re-calibration along a MC path is applied:
Both hedging models are initially consistent with the market skew - as
price S(t) and vol Vimp(t) change, both models remain very close to
market skew
Log-normality assumption - independence of implied&realized skew
from volatility - comes into play
30
Specification for trading in delta-hedged positions:
1) Straddle - short ATM put and call
Figure 1: P&L profile with Delta= 0 is function of realized return squared
Important: P&L/delta of straddle are not sensitive to realized/implied
skew - Benefits from small realized variance of price returns
2) Risk-reversal - short put with strike 99% and long call with strike
101% of forward
Figure 2: P&L profile with Delta= −0.8 is function of realized return
Important: P&L/delta of risk-reversal are very sensitive to real-
ized/implied skew - Benefits from small realized covariance of changes
in price and ATM vol
-5.0%
-2.5%
0.0%
2.5%
5.0%
PayOff+PV-DeltaHedge with Delta=0
PayOff
-10.0%
-7.5%
-5.0%
-10%-8%-6%-4%-2% 0% 2% 4% 6% 8%10%
Straddle P&L vs Price return
-2.5%
0.0%
2.5%
5.0%
7.5%
10.0%
PayOff+PV-DeltaHedge with delta=-0.8
PayOff
-10.0%
-7.5%
-5.0%
-2.5%
-10%-8%-6%-4%-2% 0% 2% 4% 6% 8%10%
Risk-Reversal P&L vsPrice return
31
Specification for notionals of delta-hedged positions
Notionals are normalized by CashGamma=(1/2) × (S2)×OptionGamma
Notionals for straddle:
PutNotional(tn) = CallNotional(tn) = −
0.5
ATM CashGamma(tn)
Notionals for risk-reversal:
PutNotional(tn) = −
0.5 × (Vatm(tn))2T
2% × {Put Vega(tn)}
CallNotional(tn) = +
0.5 × (Vatm(tn))2T
2% × {Call Vega(tn)}
where 2% comes from strike width 2% = 101% − 99%
Important: for Straddle, cash-gamma is 1.0
For Risk-reversal, the vanna (vega of delta) is 1.0
32
Monte-Carlo analysis: P&L accrual
Daily re-balancing at times tn, n = 1, ..., N
At the end of each day, we roll into new position so straddle is at-the-
money and risk-reversal has the same strike width
Realized P&L is P&L on hedges minus P&L on options position:
P&L =
N
n=1
{∆(tn−1) S(tn) − S(tn−1)
− Π (T − dt, S(tn), Vatm(tn)) − Π T, S(tn−1), Vatm(tn−1) }
Π (T, S(tn), Vatm(tn)) is options position computed using BSM formula and
implied volatility skew (5) with Vatm(tn), T = 1/12, dt = 1/252
Transaction costs are 2bp (k = 0.0002) per delta-rebalancing:
TC = k |∆(t0)| S(t0) + k
N
n=1
|∆(tn) − ∆(tn−1)| S(tn)
where ∆(tn) is combined delta for newly rolled position
Important: P&L across different days and paths is maturity-time
and strike-space homogeneous - robust for statistical inference!
33
Monte-Carlo analysis - final notes
Trade notional is 100,000,000$
Realized P&L and explanatory variables are reported in thousands of $
Option maturity: one month
Daily re-hedging with total for each path: N = 21
P&L is annualized by multiplying by 12
Draw 2,000 paths and compute realized P&L and price return, variance,
volatility beta for changes in price and ATM vol, etc
Price and volatility paths are the same for straddle and risk-reversal
and different hedging strategies
A) Analyze realized delta-hedging P&L (Profit and Loss) by
[i] Realized P&L and its volatility, transaction costs
[ii] Sharpe ratios
B) P&L Explain using regression model with explanatory variables
What factors (realized variance, covariance, etc) contribute to P&L
34
1. Analysis of realized P&L for straddle
Figure left - realized P&L with no accounting for transaction costs
Right - realized P&L with transaction costs
Approximately, straddle P&L is spread between implied&realized vols2:
P&L = Γ × (Vatm)2 − (Vret)2
= 100, 000 × (16.75%)2 − (16.00%)2 = 246
where Γ is cash-gamma notional in thousands $
Realized P&L little depends on the delta hedging strategy
Important is that asset drift is zero, otherwise P&L-s for different hedging
strategies have directional exposure to realized asset drift
244 243
100
200
300 Straddle P&L, zero trans costs
0
Minimum var Empirical beta
161 161
100
200
300 Straddle P&L after trans costs
161 161
0
Minimum var Empirical beta
35
2. Analysis of realized P&L for risk-reversal
Figure: left - realized P&L with no accounting for transaction costs
Right - realized P&L with transaction costs
Approximately, risk-reversal P&L is spread between implied and realized
co-variance of price and vol returns:
P&L = V × −SKEW × (Vatm)2 + (Vret)2 + β[R] × (Vret)2
= 100, 211 × 0.5 × (16.75%)2 + (16.00%)2 − 0.88 × (16.00%)2 = 431
where V is vanna notional in thousands $
Again, realized P&L little depends on the delta hedging strategy when
asset drift is zero
423 423
100
200
300
400
500 Risk-Reversal P&L, zero trans costs
0
100
Minimum var Empirical beta
190 192100
200
300
400
500 Risk-Reversal P&L after trans costs
190 192
0
100
Minimum var Empirical beta
36
3. Analysis of transaction costs
Transaction costs are 2bp per traded delta notional or 1$ per 5, 000$
Left figure: realized transaction costs
1) Risk-reversal has higher transaction costs due to larger delta notional
2) Minimum variance hedge and empirical hedge imply about equal trans-
action costs for straddle
3) Minimum variance hedge implies higher transaction costs for
risk-reversal because of over-hedging the put side
Right figure: volatility of transaction costs
Volatility is about uniform and very small compared to mean costs
233 231100
200
300 Realized Transaction costs
83 82
0
Min var for
straddle
Empirical
beta for
straddle
Min var for
risk-reversal
Empirical
beta for
risk-reversal
5 5
2
4
6
Volatility of Transaction costs
2 2
0
2
Min var for
straddle
Empirical
beta for
straddle
Min var for
risk-reversal
Empirical
beta for
risk-reversal
37
4. Volatility of Realized P&L
Left figure: P&L volatility without accounting for transaction costs
Empirical hedge implies lower P&L volatility for:
[i] Risk-reversal (about 20%)
[ii] Straddle (about 2 − 3%)
Because Minimum Variance delta over-hedges for put side and make delta
more volatile
Right figure: volatility of realized P&L accounting for costs
1) Transaction costs increase P&L slightly by about 1 − 2%
2) Contrast with reduction of realized P&L by about 50%
328 320
100
200
300
400 P&L Volatility, zero transaction costs
122 102
0
100
Min var for
straddle
Empirical
beta for
straddle
Min var for
risk-reversal
Empirical
beta for
risk-reversal
331 323
100
200
300
400 P&L Volatility, after transaction costs
122 102
0
100
Min var for
straddle
Empirical
beta for
straddle
Min var for
risk-reversal
Empirical
beta for
risk-reversal
38
5. Sharpe ratios of realized P&L-s
Left figure: Sharpe ratios for delta-hedging P&L without account-
ing for transaction costs
Right figure: Sharpe ratios for P&L accounting for costs
1) For straddle, both Minimum Variance and Empirical hedges imply
about the Sharpe ratio
2) For risk-reversal, Minimum Var hedge implies smaller Sharpe
than Empirical hedge (by about 20%) because of higher P&L volatility
and transaction costs
3.46
4.14
1.00
2.00
3.00
4.00
Sharpe ratio, zero tranaction costs
0.74 0.76
0.00
1.00
Min var for
straddle
Empirical
beta for
straddle
Min var for
risk-reversal
Empirical
beta for risk-
reversal
1.56
1.88
0.50
1.00
1.50
2.00
Sharpe ratio, after transaction cost
0.49 0.50
0.00
0.50
Min var for
straddle
Empirical
beta for
straddle
Min var for
risk-reversal
Empirical
beta for risk-
reversal
39
P&L Attribution to risk factors is applied to understand
what factors contribute to P&L by using regression
P&L = α + s1X1 + s2X2 + s3X3 + s4X4 + s5X5 + s6X6 (6)
α (”Alpha”) is theta related P&L - P&L we would realize if nothing would
move
X1 (”Var”) is returns variance: X1 = S(tn)
S(tn−1)
− 1
2
X2 (”VolChange”) is change in ATM vol: X2 = Vatm(tn) − Vatm(tn−1)
X3 (”Covar”) is covariance: X3 = S(tn)
S(tn−1)
− 1 Vatm(tn) − Vatm(tn−1)
X4 (”VarVol”) is variance of vol changes: X4 = Vatm(tn) − Vatm(tn−1) 2
X5 (”Return3”) is cubic return: X5 = S(tn)
S(tn−1)
− 1
3
X6 (”Return”) is realized return: X6 = S(tn)
S(tn−1)
− 1
Summation runs from n = 1 to n = N, N = 21
R2 indicates how well the realized variables explain realized P&L (not
accounting for transaction costs) - we should aim for R2 = 90%
Some explanatory variables are correlated so it is robust to test reduced
regressions
40
P&L explain for straddle by realized variance of returns:
Empirical hedge has stronger explanatory power
Is needed to confirm theoretical P&L explain by MC simulations
For P&L of straddle hedged at implied vol, first-order approximation:
V 2
atm −
n
S(tn)
S(tn−1)
− 1
2
First term is alpha or ”carry” - approximate alpha is
α = Γ × V 2
atm = 100, 000 × 0.16752 = 2806
Second term is short risk to realized variance - key variable for P&L
Theoretical slope should be −Γ = −100, 000
Figure: explanatory power using only realized variance is weak because
of impact of other variables and skew (for multiple variables, R2 ≈ 90%)
P&L = -48,768*Var + 1,559
R² = 30%
0
4,000
P&L
Straddle P&L by Min-Var Hedge
-8,000
-4,000
0.00 0.05 0.10 0.15
P&L
Realized Variance
P&L = -55,132*Var + 1,730
R² = 40%
0
4,000
P&L
Straddle P&L by Empirical hedge
-8,000
-4,000
0.00 0.05 0.10 0.15
P&L
Realized Variance
41
P&L explain for risk-reversal by realized vol beta:
Empirical hedge implies that realized vol beta is clear
driver behind P&L of risk-reversal with R2 = 50%
For P&L of risk-reversal hedged at implied vol skew, approximation:
−SKEW × V 2
atm +
n
S(tn)
S(tn−1)
− 1
2
+
n
S(tn)
S(tn−1)
− 1 (Vatm(tn) − Vatm(tn−1))
In terms of returns vol Vret and implied vol beta βR:
−SKEW × V 2
atm + V 2
ret + β[R]
× V 2
ret
First term is ”carry” or alpha
Second term is risk to realized beta between returns and vol - key variable
In our example: α = 0.5 × V × {(16.75%)2 + (16.00%)2} = 2, 682
Slope= V × (16.00%)2 = 2, 560
P&L = 2129*Beta + 2570
R² = 37%
0
1500
3000Risk-Reversal P&L
by Min-Var Hedge
-1500
0
-2.0 -1.5 -1.0 -0.5
P&L
Realized Volatility Beta
P&L = 2050*Beta + 2490
R² = 49%
0
1500
3000Risk-Reversal P&L
by Empirical Hedge
-1500
0
-2.0 -1.5 -1.0 -0.5
P&L
Realized Volatility Beta
42
Important: vol beta (for skew) is comparable to Black-
Scholes-Merton (BSM) implied volatility (for one strike)
1) Volatility and vol beta are meaningful and intuitive model pa-
rameters which can be inferred from both implied and historical data
Implied vol σ[I] is inferred from option market price
Realized vol σ[R] is volatility of price returns
Implied vol beta β[I] is inferred from market skew (β[I] ≈ 2 × SKEW)
Realized vol beta β[R] is change in implied ATM volatility predicted by
price returns: β[R] = dS(t)dVatm(t) /(σ[R])2
2) Both serve as directs input for computation of hedges
3) Both allow for P&L explain of vanilla options in terms of implied
and realized model parameters:
Implied/realized volatility- P&L of delta-hedged straddle:
σ[I] 2
− σ[R] 2
Implied/realized volatility beta- P&L of short delta-hedged risk-reversal
(more noisy because of contribution from σ[R]):
−β[I] ×
1
2
σ[I] 2
+ σ[R] 2
+ β[R] × σ[R] 2
43
Conclusion: existing practical approaches for hedging
improvement are not fully satisfactory - we need proper
model for dynamic delta-hedging!
A) Hedge all vega exposure
B) Recalibration for computing delta-risks (most common):
⊗ Project change in implied volatility using empirical backbone
(For example, by applying empirical volatility skew-beta)
⊗ Re-calibrate valuation model to bumped volatility surface
⊗ Re-valuate and compute delta by finite-differences
However runs into problems:
1) A) - vega-hedging is (very) expensive and unprofitable unless
implied skew and vol-of-vol are sold at large premiums to future realizeds
2) B) - re-calibration works poorly for path-dependent and multi-
asset products and it makes P&L explain very noisy
Recall applying regression for P&L explain of straddle and risk-reversal
3) any mix of A) and B) becomes very tedious for CVA computations
Important: the choice between local vol (LV) or stoch vol (SV) is irrel-
evant when hedging using minimum variance hedge at implied vol skew -
any combination of LV and SV produces almost the same deltas! 44
Beta SV model with jumps is fitted to empirical&implied
dynamics for computing correct delta (Sepp 2014):
dS(t)
S(t)
= (µ(t) − λ(eη − 1)) dt + V (t)dW(0)(t) + (eη − 1) dN(t)
dV (t) = κ(θ − V (t))dt + βV (t)dW(0)(t) + εV (t)dW(1)(t) + βη dN(t)
1) Consistent with empirical dynamics of implied ATM volatility by
specifying empirical volatility beta β
2) Has jumps, as degree of risk-aversion, to make model fit to both
empirical dynamics and risk-neutral skew premium
Only one parameter with simple calibration! - explained in a bit
Jumps/risk-aversion under risk-neutral measure Q produced by:
Poisson process N(t) with intensity λ:
negative&positive jumps in returns&vols with constant size η < 0&βη > 0
3) Easy-to-implement (with no extra parameters) extension to multi-
asset dynamics using common jumps - produces basket correlation skew
4) Beta SVJ model is robust to produce optimal hedges for path-
dependent and multi-asset trades and CVA
45
Third to last topic: closed-form solution for log-normal
Beta SV
Mean-reverting log-normal SV models are not analytically tractable
I derive a very accurate exp-affine approximation for moment generating
function (details in my paper)
Idea comes from information theory: apply Kullback-Leibler relative en-
tropy for unknown PDF p(x) and test PDF q(x) with moment constraints:
xkp(x)dx = xkq(x)dx, k = 1, 2, ...
Now let’s think in terms of moment function:
[i] MGF for Beta SV model with normal driver for SV (as in Stein-Stein
SV model) has exact solution, which has exp-affine form
[ii] Correction for log-normal SV has an exp-affine form
15%
20%
25%
30%
35% Implied vol for 1y S&P500
options, beta SV, NO JUMPS
Analytic for Normal SV
5%
10%
15%
0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0 1.1 1.2 1.3
Strike
Analytic for Normal SV
Closed-form for Log-normal SV
Monte-Carlo for Log-normal SV
15%
20%
25%
30%
35% Implied vol for 1y S&P500
options, beta SV, WITH JUMPS
5%
10%
15%
0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0 1.1 1.2 1.3
Strike
Analytic for Normal SV
Closed-form for Log-normal SV
Monte-Carlo for Log-normal SV
46
Proof that closed-form MFG for log-normal model pro-
duces theoretically consistent probability density
1) Derive solutions for excepted values, variances, and covariances of the
log-price and quadratic variance (QV) by solving PDE directly
2) Prove that moments derived using approximate MGF equal to theo-
retical moments derived in 1)
Using closed-form MFG for log-normal model, we apply standard valuation
methods for affine SV models based on Lipton-Lewis formula
Implementation of closed-form moment function (MGF), MC, and PDE
pricers produce values of vanilla options on equity and quadratic variance
that are equal within numerical accuracy of these methods
15%
20%
25%
30%
35% Implied vol for 1y S&P500
options, beta SV, NO JUMPS
Closed-form MGF
5%
10%
15%
0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0 1.1 1.2 1.3
Strike
Closed-form MGF
Monte-Carlo
PDE, numerical solver
15%
20%
25%
30%
35% Implied vol for 1y S&P500
options, beta SV, WITH JUMPS
Closed-form MGF
5%
10%
15%
0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0 1.1 1.2 1.3
Strike
Closed-form MGF
Monte-Carlo
PDE, numerical solver
47
Second to last topic - optimal hedging under discrete
trading and transaction costs
To adopt to practical option trading:
a) change ”kid” to ”trader”
b) change ”cantaloupes” to ”millions of delta over an infinitesimal time
period dt”
As we saw in simulation of P&L, we need quantitative framework that
incorporates discrete hedging and optimizes trade-off between:
the reward - higher P&L and lower transaction costs
the risk - higher P&L volatility
48
Illustration of trading in implied&realized vol with strad-
dle: unique optimal hedging frequency can be found!
Figure 1) Forecast expected upside:
the spread between implied and real-
ized vol for given maturity T
This is independent of valua-
tion&hedging model and hedging
frequency
Figure 2) Forecast P&L volatility
and transaction costs
These depend on valuation&hedging
model and hedging frequency
Part of P&L volatility is not hedge-
able due to vol-of-vol and jumps -
Not optimal to hedge too fre-
quently
Figure 3) Obtain Sharpe ratio as ra-
tio of forecast P&L after costs and
P&L volatility
1%
2%
3%
Expected/Forcasted P&L(N)
0%
1%
10 160 310 460 610 760 910
N - hedging frequency
1%
2%
3% Expected/Forcasted P&L
Volatility and Costs (N)
P&L Volatility
Transaction costs
0%
1%
10 160 310 460 610 760 910
N - hedging frequency
0.6
0.8
1.0
1.2
1.4 Expected/Forcasted
Sharpe Ratio (N)
0.0
0.2
0.4
0.6
10 160 310 460 610 760 910
N - hedging frequency
49
Solution for optimal Sharpe ratio with dynamics under
physical measure driven by Diffusion and SV with jumps
Sharpe(N) =
Expected P&L − TransactionCosts(N)
P&L Volatility(N)
N is hedging frequency - for details see my paper on optimal delta-hedging
Using this solution we can analyze:
Figure 1) What maturity is optimal to trade given the forecast spread
between implieds and realizeds
(longer maturities have higher spreads but their P&L is more volatile
because of higher risk to ATM vol changes)
Figure 2) What is optimal hedging frequency for each maturity
Translate into approximations of optimal bands for price and delta triggers
Naturally, results are sensitive to assumed price dynamics
Under SV with jumps: lower Sharp ratio and less frequent hedging
1.0
1.3
1.6
Optimal Sharpe ratio
Diffusion
Stochastic volatility with jumps
0.4
0.7
1m
4m
7m
10m
13m
16m
19m
22m
25m
28m
31m
34m
37m
Option maturity in months
4
6
8
10
12 Optimal hedging frequency in days
Diffusion
Stochastic volatility with jumps
0
2
4
1m
4m
7m
10m
13m
16m
19m
22m
25m
28m
31m
34m
37m
Option maturity in months
50
Last topic: why the beta stochastic vol model with
jumps is better than its alternatives (for stock indices)
The most important feature for dynamic hedging model:
1) Ability to produce different volatility regimes as observed in the
market and to imply empirically consistent delta
Recall definition of volatility skew-beta: change in term structure of ATM
volatility, σATM(T), predicted by price return times SKEW(T)
We saw that vol skew-beta is very important to account for correct P&L
arising from change in BSM implied vols
Skew-consistent SV and LV models imply skew-beta of 2
Empirical vol skew-beta: S&P 500 ≈ 1.5; STOXX50 ≈ 1.8; Nikkei≈ 0.5
1.00
1.50
2.00
2.50
Vol Skew-Beta for S&P500
SVJ Skew-Beta with empirical beta
0.00
0.50
1m
3m
5m
7m
9m
11m
13m
15m
17m
19m
21m
23m
T in months
SVJ Skew-Beta with empirical beta
Sticky local with Min-var delta
Empirical bounds
1.00
1.50
2.00
2.50
Vol Skew-Beta for STOXX 50
SVJ Skew-Beta with empirical beta
0.00
0.50
1m
3m
5m
7m
9m
11m
13m
15m
17m
19m
21m
23m
T in months
SVJ Skew-Beta with empirical beta
Sticky local with Min-var delta
Empirical bounds
1.00
1.50
2.00
2.50
Vol Skew-Beta for NIKKEI
SVJ Skew-Beta with empirical beta
Sticky local with Min-var delta
Empirical bounds
0.00
0.50
1m
3m
5m
7m
9m
11m
13m
15m
17m
19m
21m
23m
T in months
51
Why the beta SV with jumps is better than its alterna-
tives
Extra arguments to look at apart from implied volatility skew-beta
2) Fit to empirical distribution of implied and realized volatilities
3) Interpretation of model parameters in terms of impact on model implied
BSM vols
4) P&L explain for delta-hedging strategies of vanilla options in terms of
implied and realized model parameters
5) Stability of model parameters
Calibration to vanilla options is not a problem in practical applications -
it is easy to achieve by introducing a (small) local vol part
Calibration problem is solved by Dupire (1994) for diffusions, Andersen-
Andreasen (2000) for jump-diffusions, Lipton (2002) for SV with jumps
52
I. Non-parametric local volatility model - textbook im-
plementation of Dupire local volatility using discrete set
of option prices and interpolation
It is a good competitor to start my comparison because it fails on all
counts
As for interpretation and stability of model parameters - see quiz on the
next slide
53
Interpretation and stability of non-parametric LV
Quiz: one of two figures below is
[A] local vol surface fitted to discrete prices of S&P500 index options
[B] Eckert IV map projection of a ski mountain where I was skiing last
winter
Which is which ?
The same conclusion is for any SV and LV model implemented naively
using direct calibration to market prices and mean-variance hedging:
1-2) Wrong hedges and empirical inconsistency
3-5) Uninterpretable and unstable model parameters
54
II. Industry-standard alternative (in equity derivatives)
Implied volatility@strike-into-density@price approach (my terminology)
Conceptually:
σimpl(K; T) → Pimpl(S(T) = K) (7)
where→ is Dupire LV formula in terms of implied vols at strike K&mat T
Figure 1A) Given parametric form for implied vols σimpl(K; T)
Figure 1B) Given backbone function fbackbone(δS; K, T) to map price
changes δS into changes in vols δσimpl(K; T) according to specified regime
Figure 2) → in Eq(7) serves as interpolator from implied vols in strike
space to implied densities in price space
Figure 3) LV model projects densities to option prices in ”model-independent”
way using MC or PDE methods
20%
30%
40%
50%
ImpliedVolatility
Implied Volatility (S0=1.00)
Implied Volatility (S1=0.95)
Change in IV from backbone function
0%
10%
20%
0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0 1.1 1.2
ImpliedVolatility
Strike
0.75%
1.50%
2.25%
Density
Implied Density from LV mapping (S0=1.00)
Implied Density from LV mapping (S1=0.95)
Change in Density from LV mapping
-0.75%
0.00%
0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0 1.1 1.2
Density
Spot
0.10
0.20
0.30
0.40
0.50
PV
PV Risk-Reversal 95-105% (S0)
PV Risk-Reversal 95-105% (S1)
Change in PV Risk-Reversal 95-105%
-0.20
-0.10
0.00
0.10
0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0 1.1 1.2
Spot
55
1) Hedging performance for local vol approach are pri-
mary driven by parametric form for implied vols σimpl(K; T)
and empirical backbone function
2) No consistency with empirical distribution of implied and realized vol
3) & 4) Model interpretation and P&L explain are possible only in terms
of parameters of functional form for implied volatility
Key drawback of implied volatility-into-density approach:
[i] For computation of delta it requires a re-calibration of local vol and
re-valuation for any change in market data
[ii] Lacks vol-of-vol so it is inconsistent for hedging of path-dependent
options sensitive to forward vols and skews
56
Alternatives for local vol or σimpl(K; T) → Pimpl(S(T) = K)
approach do not produce improvements
Instead of LV to map implied vol into price density, it is also customary
to use SV or LSV models as interpolators with extra degree of freedom
Hereby hodel choice is typically motivated by availability of a ”closed-
form” solution, not empirical consistency!
Figure: SV and LSV models are not applied for hedging as dynamic
models since their model delta is wrong - with and without minimum
variance hedge - but through re-calibration to empirical backbone
1.5%
2.5%
3.5%
Change in implied vol, S1-S0=-0.05
SV model delta
SV with Min Var Hedge
Empirical backbone
-1.5%
-0.5%
0.5%
0.70 0.80 0.90 1.00 1.10 1.20
Strike
0.40
0.60
0.80
1.00Delta for 1y call option on
S&P500
SV model
0.00
0.20
0.40
0.70 0.80 0.90 1.00 1.10 1.20 Strike
SV with Min Var hedge
Sticky-Strike BSM delta
SV re-calibrated to empirical backbone
To conclude I use a quote from Richard P. Feynman:
It doesn’t matter how beautiful your theory is, it doesn’t matter
how smart you are. If it doesn’t agree with experiment, it’s wrong!
57
III. Arguments in favor of Beta SVJ model:
1) the model has ability to fit empirical vol skew-beta
and produce correct option delta without re-calibration
Figure: delta from SVJ model fits empirical backbone
0.40
0.60
0.80
1.00 Delta for 1y call option on
S&P500
SV model
0.00
0.20
0.40
0.70 0.80 0.90 1.00 1.10 1.20Strike
SV with Min Var hedge
SV re-calibrated to Market backbone
SVJ (without re-calibration)
2) Consistent with the empirical distributions of implied and realized
volatilities, which are very close to log-normal
3) It has clear intuition behind the key model parameters:
Volatility beta is sensitivity to changes in short-term ATM vol
Residual vol-of-vol is volatility of idiosyncratic changes in ATM vol
4) P&L explain is possible in terms of implied and realized quantities
of key model parameter - vol beta
5) Stability and calibration - next slide
58
Calibration of beta SV model is based on econometric
and implied approaches without large-scale non-linear
and non-intuitive calibrations
1) Parameters of SV part are estimated from time series
2) Jump/risk-aversion params are fitted to empirical vol skew-beta
Params in 1) & 2) are updated only following changes in volatility regime
3) Small mis-calibrations of the SV part and jumps are corrected
using local vol (LV) part
Contribution to skew from LV part is kept small (no more than 10-15%)
Local vol part is re-calibrated on the fly to reproduce small variations in
some parts of implied vol surface, which are caused by temporary supply-
demand factors specific to that part
It is also robust to compute bucketed vega risk in this way
In practical terms:
1) Local volatility part accounts for the noise from idiosyncratic
changes in implied volatility surface
2) Stochastic volatility and jumps serve as time- and space-homogeneou
factors for the shape of the implied volatility surface
59
More details on calibration of beta SV model (technical
part omitted during the talk)
1) Parameters of SV part are calibrated using maximum likelihood meth-
ods from time series of 1m implied ATM volatility (or the VIX)
[i] mean-reversion κ is estimated over longer-period, at least 5 years, -
better to keep it constant at 3.00
[ii] vol beta β and residual vol-vol ε are estimated over shorter periods,
1y, - typically β ≈ −1.00 and ε ∈ [0.60, 1.00]
2) Negative jump in return η is fitted using Merton jump model to put
options with maturity of 6 months and [80% − 100%] OTM strikes -
typically η = −30%
3) Given 1) and 2): 3A) jump intensity λ is calibrated to fit the empirical
sensitivity of implied volatility changes to price changes, aka volatility
skew-beta, - typically λ ∈ [0.03, 0.2]
Given all above: 3B) initial vol V (0) and mean vol θ calibrated to fit the
current term structure of ATM vols
Parameters in 1), 2) 3A) (relatively uniform for major stock indices) are
updated infrequently
4) Local vol part is added to fit daily variations in implied vol surface
60
For risk-neutral pricing, distribution of jumps does not
matter - jumps are only needed to fit skew premium
Recall illustration of emergence of Q-
skew using Bakshi-Kapadia-Madan
formula and Merton jump model:
[i] Under P, jumps are symmetric
with mean of 0% and volatility of 4%
[ii] The risk-neutral mean jump is
−5% with zero volatility
4%
6%
8%
10%
Frequency
Frequency of S&P500 daily returns
Empirical
Frequency
Physical Merton
under P
Risk-Neutral
0%
2%
4%
-9% -7% -5% -4% -2% 0% 2% 4% 6% 7%
Frequency
Daily return
Risk-Neutral
Merton under Q
Yet, jumps are needed to fit market prices & compute correct deltas
Also jumps are important to fit market prices of options on realized and
implied volatilities (VIX) - see my presentations at GD in 2011 & 2012
Practical explanation for excessive risk-neutral skew premium:
1) Risk-averse investors always ready to over-pay for insurance ir-
respectively of price changes
2) As part of index correlation skew premium, when holders of
stock portfolios buy index puts for (macro) protection
To make things robust, I assume constant jumps with simple calibration
61
How to explain the difference between implied
and realized dynamics using preference theory
For retail option buyer - option value is derived from his preference/utility
for specific payoffs in certain market scenarios
For institutional option seller - option value is derived from:
[i] Expected hedging costs
[ii] Smooth stream of fees and P&L
[iii] Premium for suffering losses in bad market conditions
As a result:
1) Option prices in the market are set by demand-supply equilibrium
between sellers and buyers
2) Risk-aversion parameters is a degree of demand-supply imbal-
ance
3) Implied and realized vols and, in particular, skews are different
62
To conclude: we can think of jumps as a mea-
sure of risk-aversion for pricing kernel!
Recently, interesting research is made and also presented at Global Deriva-
tives on how to imply the ”expected-implied” physical distribution from
options market prices and specified risk-aversion
Stephen Ross:The Recovery Theorem, GD2012, Journal of Finance 2014
Peter Carr: Can we recover?, Global Derivatives 2013
Computation of ”empirical” delta and calibration of excessive skew are
related concepts:
1) Compute option delta under ”expected-implied” physical distri-
bution using empirical vol beta
2) Fit level of risk-aversion to excessive skew premium observed in
market prices of index options
These concepts and volatility skew-beta are related to the interplay be-
tween the implied and realized risk premiums:
[i] high implied / positive realized risk premiums - sticky strike vol regime
[ii] low implied / negative realized risk premiums - sticky local vol regime
To be continued at next year Global Derivatives conference...
63
Summary
1) Dynamics of implied and real-
ized vols are log-normal
2) Implied vol beta significantly
overestimates realized beta
3) Vol skew-beta is important for
correct P&L - any dynamic hedging
model should fit empirical skew-beta
Risk-Aversion/Jumps parameter
is added to fit empirical skew-beta
SVJ fits empirical skew-beta≈ 1.5,
unlike Minimum Var delta≈ 2.0
4) Beta SVJ model applied for
delta-hedging risk-reversal is tool to
produce P&L from spread be-
tween implied and realized skews
Log-normal beta SVJ model:
⊗Is consistent with the empirical
dynamics of ATM volatility
⊗Produces correct option deltas
⊗Can significantly improve Shar-
pe ratios for delta-hedging P&Ls
3%
4%
5%
6%
7%
Frequency
Empirical frequency of
normalized logarithm of the VIX
Empirical
Standard Normal
0%
1%
2%
3%
-4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4
Frequency
Log-VIX
-0.5
0.0
Feb-07
Sep-07
Apr-08
Nov-08
Jun-09
Jan-10
Aug-10
Mar-11
Oct-11
May-12
Dec-12
Jul-13
Implied Volatility Beta
Realized Volatility Beta
-2.0
-1.5
-1.0
1.00
1.50
2.00
2.50
Vol Skew-Beta for S&P500
SVJ Skew-Beta with empirical beta
0.00
0.50
1m
3m
5m
7m
9m
11m
13m
15m
17m
19m
21m
23m
T in months
SVJ Skew-Beta with empirical beta
Sticky local with Min-var delta
Empirical bounds
P&L = 2050*Beta + 2490
R² = 49%
0
1500
3000
P&L
Risk-Reversal P&L vs
Realized Vol Beta
-1500
0
-2.0 -1.5 -1.0 -0.5
P&L
Realized Volatility Beta
64
Disclaimer
The views represented herein are the author own views and do not neces-
sarily represent the views of Bank of America Merrill Lynch or its affiliates
65
References
Andersen, L., Andreasen, J., (2000), “Jump-Diffusion Processes - Volatility Smile Fitting
and Numerical Methods for Option Pricing ,” Review of Derivatives Research 4, 231-262
Bakshi, G., Kapadia, N., Madan, D., (2003), “Stock return characteristics, skew laws,
and the differential pricing of individual equity options,” Review of Financial Studies 16
(1), 101-143
Bergomi, L., (2009), “Smile dynamics 4,” Risk, December, 94-100
Bergomi,L.,Guyon,J.,(2012),“Stochastic volatility’s orderly smiles,”Risk,May,117-123
Christoffersen, P., Jacobs, K., Mimouni, K., (2010), “Models for S&P 500 Dynam-
ics: Evidence from Realized Volatility, Daily Returns and Options Prices,” Review of
Financial Studies 23(8), 3141-3189
Derman, E., (1999), “Volatility Regimes,” Risk, April, 55-59
Dupire, B. (1994), “Pricing with a smile”, Risk, July, 18-20
Karasinski, P., Sepp, A., (2012), “Beta stochastic volatility model,” Risk, October,
67-73
Lewis, A., (2000), “Option valuation under stochastic volatility,” Finance Press, New-
port Beach, California
Lipton, A., (2002). “The vol smile problem”, Risk, February, 81-85
Ross, S., (2014). “The Recovery Theorem”, Journal of Finance, forthcoming
Sepp, A., (2011), “Efficient Numerical PDE Methods to Solve Calibration and Pricing
Problems in Local Stochastic Volatility Models”, Global Derivatives conference in Paris
Sepp, A., (2012), “Achieving Consistent Modeling Of VIX and Equities Derivatives”,
Global Derivatives conference in Barcelona
Sepp, A., (2013), “Consistently Modeling Joint Dynamics of Volatility and Underlying
To Enable Effective Hedging”, Global Derivatives conference in Amsterdam
Sepp, A., (2013), “When You Hedge Discretely: Optimization of Sharpe Ratio for
Delta-Hedging Strategy under Discrete Hedging and Transaction Costs,” The Journal
of Investment Strategies 3(1), 19-59
Sepp, A., (2014), “Empirical Calibration and Minimum-Variance Delta Under Log-
Normal Stochastic Volatility Dynamics,” Working paper, http://ssrn.com/abstract=2387845
Sepp, A., (2014), “Log-Normal Stochastic Volatility Model: Pricing of Vanilla Options
and Econometric Estimation,” Working paper, http://ssrn.com/abstract=2522425
66

Contenu connexe

En vedette

Enhanced Call Overwriting (2005)
Enhanced Call Overwriting (2005)Enhanced Call Overwriting (2005)
Enhanced Call Overwriting (2005)
Ryan Renicker CFA
 
ImperialMathFinance: Finance and Stochastics Seminar
ImperialMathFinance: Finance and Stochastics SeminarImperialMathFinance: Finance and Stochastics Seminar
ImperialMathFinance: Finance and Stochastics Seminar
elviszhang
 

En vedette (20)

Quantitative Methods for Counterparty Risk
Quantitative Methods for Counterparty RiskQuantitative Methods for Counterparty Risk
Quantitative Methods for Counterparty Risk
 
Short Variance Swap Strategies on the S&P 500 Index Profitable, Yet Risky
Short Variance Swap Strategies on the S&P 500 Index Profitable, Yet RiskyShort Variance Swap Strategies on the S&P 500 Index Profitable, Yet Risky
Short Variance Swap Strategies on the S&P 500 Index Profitable, Yet Risky
 
Convertible Bonds and Call Overwrites - 2007
Convertible Bonds and Call Overwrites - 2007Convertible Bonds and Call Overwrites - 2007
Convertible Bonds and Call Overwrites - 2007
 
Options on the VIX and Mean Reversion in Implied Volatility Skews
Options on the VIX and Mean Reversion in Implied Volatility Skews Options on the VIX and Mean Reversion in Implied Volatility Skews
Options on the VIX and Mean Reversion in Implied Volatility Skews
 
Style-Oriented Option Investing - Value vs. Growth?
Style-Oriented Option Investing - Value vs. Growth?Style-Oriented Option Investing - Value vs. Growth?
Style-Oriented Option Investing - Value vs. Growth?
 
Consistently Modeling Joint Dynamics of Volatility and Underlying To Enable E...
Consistently Modeling Joint Dynamics of Volatility and Underlying To Enable E...Consistently Modeling Joint Dynamics of Volatility and Underlying To Enable E...
Consistently Modeling Joint Dynamics of Volatility and Underlying To Enable E...
 
Stochastic Local Volatility Models: Theory and Implementation
Stochastic Local Volatility Models: Theory and ImplementationStochastic Local Volatility Models: Theory and Implementation
Stochastic Local Volatility Models: Theory and Implementation
 
Implied volatility explanation
Implied volatility explanationImplied volatility explanation
Implied volatility explanation
 
Volatility arbitrage
Volatility arbitrageVolatility arbitrage
Volatility arbitrage
 
Enhanced Call Overwriting (2005)
Enhanced Call Overwriting (2005)Enhanced Call Overwriting (2005)
Enhanced Call Overwriting (2005)
 
The Lehman Brothers Volatility Screening Tool
The Lehman Brothers Volatility Screening ToolThe Lehman Brothers Volatility Screening Tool
The Lehman Brothers Volatility Screening Tool
 
ImperialMathFinance: Finance and Stochastics Seminar
ImperialMathFinance: Finance and Stochastics SeminarImperialMathFinance: Finance and Stochastics Seminar
ImperialMathFinance: Finance and Stochastics Seminar
 
Pricing Exotics using Change of Numeraire
Pricing Exotics using Change of NumerairePricing Exotics using Change of Numeraire
Pricing Exotics using Change of Numeraire
 
Stochastic Vol Forecasting
Stochastic Vol ForecastingStochastic Vol Forecasting
Stochastic Vol Forecasting
 
Uncertain Volatility Models
Uncertain Volatility ModelsUncertain Volatility Models
Uncertain Volatility Models
 
Efficient Numerical PDE Methods to Solve Calibration and Pricing Problems in ...
Efficient Numerical PDE Methods to Solve Calibration and Pricing Problems in ...Efficient Numerical PDE Methods to Solve Calibration and Pricing Problems in ...
Efficient Numerical PDE Methods to Solve Calibration and Pricing Problems in ...
 
Volatility Trading - Hedge Fund Strategies
Volatility Trading - Hedge Fund StrategiesVolatility Trading - Hedge Fund Strategies
Volatility Trading - Hedge Fund Strategies
 
An Approximate Distribution of Delta-Hedging Errors in a Jump-Diffusion Model...
An Approximate Distribution of Delta-Hedging Errors in a Jump-Diffusion Model...An Approximate Distribution of Delta-Hedging Errors in a Jump-Diffusion Model...
An Approximate Distribution of Delta-Hedging Errors in a Jump-Diffusion Model...
 
IFRS 9 Instrument financier
IFRS 9 Instrument financierIFRS 9 Instrument financier
IFRS 9 Instrument financier
 
Achieving Consistent Modeling Of VIX and Equities Derivatives
Achieving Consistent Modeling Of VIX and Equities DerivativesAchieving Consistent Modeling Of VIX and Equities Derivatives
Achieving Consistent Modeling Of VIX and Equities Derivatives
 

Similaire à Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Sharpe index model
Sharpe index modelSharpe index model
Sharpe index model
Ashwini Das
 
MEASUREMENT & EVALUATION OF RISK
MEASUREMENT & EVALUATION OF RISKMEASUREMENT & EVALUATION OF RISK
MEASUREMENT & EVALUATION OF RISK
Raj Anwar
 
Riskandrateofreturnsinfinancialmanagement 100331231141-phpapp01
Riskandrateofreturnsinfinancialmanagement 100331231141-phpapp01Riskandrateofreturnsinfinancialmanagement 100331231141-phpapp01
Riskandrateofreturnsinfinancialmanagement 100331231141-phpapp01
jocelyn rojo
 

Similaire à Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging (20)

Chap011.ppt
Chap011.pptChap011.ppt
Chap011.ppt
 
Express measurement of market volatility using ergodicity concept
Express measurement of market volatility using ergodicity conceptExpress measurement of market volatility using ergodicity concept
Express measurement of market volatility using ergodicity concept
 
Asset Pricing Implications of Volatility Term Structure Risk
Asset Pricing Implications of Volatility Term Structure RiskAsset Pricing Implications of Volatility Term Structure Risk
Asset Pricing Implications of Volatility Term Structure Risk
 
Research Presentation
Research PresentationResearch Presentation
Research Presentation
 
Financial Management Slides Ch 05
Financial Management Slides Ch 05Financial Management Slides Ch 05
Financial Management Slides Ch 05
 
Sharpe index model
Sharpe index modelSharpe index model
Sharpe index model
 
Mpt pdf
Mpt pdfMpt pdf
Mpt pdf
 
MEASUREMENT & EVALUATION OF RISK
MEASUREMENT & EVALUATION OF RISKMEASUREMENT & EVALUATION OF RISK
MEASUREMENT & EVALUATION OF RISK
 
Ch_05 - Risk and Return Valuation Theory.ppt
Ch_05 - Risk and Return Valuation Theory.pptCh_05 - Risk and Return Valuation Theory.ppt
Ch_05 - Risk and Return Valuation Theory.ppt
 
Ch_05 - Risk and Return Valuation Theory.ppt
Ch_05 - Risk and Return Valuation Theory.pptCh_05 - Risk and Return Valuation Theory.ppt
Ch_05 - Risk and Return Valuation Theory.ppt
 
Credit-Implied Volatility
Credit-Implied VolatilityCredit-Implied Volatility
Credit-Implied Volatility
 
Risk Return Trade Off PowerPoint Presentation Slides
Risk Return Trade Off PowerPoint Presentation SlidesRisk Return Trade Off PowerPoint Presentation Slides
Risk Return Trade Off PowerPoint Presentation Slides
 
Customer Lifetime Value Modeling
Customer Lifetime Value ModelingCustomer Lifetime Value Modeling
Customer Lifetime Value Modeling
 
Econometrics
EconometricsEconometrics
Econometrics
 
2. Module II (1) FRM.pdf
2. Module II (1) FRM.pdf2. Module II (1) FRM.pdf
2. Module II (1) FRM.pdf
 
Robust Calibration For SVI Model Arbitrage Free
Robust Calibration For SVI Model Arbitrage FreeRobust Calibration For SVI Model Arbitrage Free
Robust Calibration For SVI Model Arbitrage Free
 
Riskandrateofreturnsinfinancialmanagement 100331231141-phpapp01
Riskandrateofreturnsinfinancialmanagement 100331231141-phpapp01Riskandrateofreturnsinfinancialmanagement 100331231141-phpapp01
Riskandrateofreturnsinfinancialmanagement 100331231141-phpapp01
 
Volatility as an Asset Class
Volatility as an Asset ClassVolatility as an Asset Class
Volatility as an Asset Class
 
Sqqs1013 ch2-a122
Sqqs1013 ch2-a122Sqqs1013 ch2-a122
Sqqs1013 ch2-a122
 
Financial Analysis 5.pptx
Financial Analysis 5.pptxFinancial Analysis 5.pptx
Financial Analysis 5.pptx
 

Dernier

( Jasmin ) Top VIP Escorts Service Dindigul 💧 7737669865 💧 by Dindigul Call G...
( Jasmin ) Top VIP Escorts Service Dindigul 💧 7737669865 💧 by Dindigul Call G...( Jasmin ) Top VIP Escorts Service Dindigul 💧 7737669865 💧 by Dindigul Call G...
( Jasmin ) Top VIP Escorts Service Dindigul 💧 7737669865 💧 by Dindigul Call G...
dipikadinghjn ( Why You Choose Us? ) Escorts
 
VIP Independent Call Girls in Bandra West 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Esc...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Bandra West 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Esc...VIP Independent Call Girls in Bandra West 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Esc...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Bandra West 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Esc...
dipikadinghjn ( Why You Choose Us? ) Escorts
 
CBD Belapur Expensive Housewife Call Girls Number-📞📞9833754194 No 1 Vipp HIgh...
CBD Belapur Expensive Housewife Call Girls Number-📞📞9833754194 No 1 Vipp HIgh...CBD Belapur Expensive Housewife Call Girls Number-📞📞9833754194 No 1 Vipp HIgh...
CBD Belapur Expensive Housewife Call Girls Number-📞📞9833754194 No 1 Vipp HIgh...
priyasharma62062
 
VIP Independent Call Girls in Andheri 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Andheri 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts...VIP Independent Call Girls in Andheri 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Andheri 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts...
dipikadinghjn ( Why You Choose Us? ) Escorts
 
➥🔝 7737669865 🔝▻ Malda Call-girls in Women Seeking Men 🔝Malda🔝 Escorts Ser...
➥🔝 7737669865 🔝▻ Malda Call-girls in Women Seeking Men  🔝Malda🔝   Escorts Ser...➥🔝 7737669865 🔝▻ Malda Call-girls in Women Seeking Men  🔝Malda🔝   Escorts Ser...
➥🔝 7737669865 🔝▻ Malda Call-girls in Women Seeking Men 🔝Malda🔝 Escorts Ser...
amitlee9823
 
VIP Independent Call Girls in Mira Bhayandar 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai ...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Mira Bhayandar 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai ...VIP Independent Call Girls in Mira Bhayandar 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai ...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Mira Bhayandar 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai ...
dipikadinghjn ( Why You Choose Us? ) Escorts
 
VIP Call Girl in Mira Road 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday ...
VIP Call Girl in Mira Road 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday ...VIP Call Girl in Mira Road 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday ...
VIP Call Girl in Mira Road 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday ...
dipikadinghjn ( Why You Choose Us? ) Escorts
 

Dernier (20)

( Jasmin ) Top VIP Escorts Service Dindigul 💧 7737669865 💧 by Dindigul Call G...
( Jasmin ) Top VIP Escorts Service Dindigul 💧 7737669865 💧 by Dindigul Call G...( Jasmin ) Top VIP Escorts Service Dindigul 💧 7737669865 💧 by Dindigul Call G...
( Jasmin ) Top VIP Escorts Service Dindigul 💧 7737669865 💧 by Dindigul Call G...
 
Technology industry / Finnish economic outlook
Technology industry / Finnish economic outlookTechnology industry / Finnish economic outlook
Technology industry / Finnish economic outlook
 
Strategic Resources May 2024 Corporate Presentation
Strategic Resources May 2024 Corporate PresentationStrategic Resources May 2024 Corporate Presentation
Strategic Resources May 2024 Corporate Presentation
 
Lion One Corporate Presentation May 2024
Lion One Corporate Presentation May 2024Lion One Corporate Presentation May 2024
Lion One Corporate Presentation May 2024
 
(INDIRA) Call Girl Srinagar Call Now 8617697112 Srinagar Escorts 24x7
(INDIRA) Call Girl Srinagar Call Now 8617697112 Srinagar Escorts 24x7(INDIRA) Call Girl Srinagar Call Now 8617697112 Srinagar Escorts 24x7
(INDIRA) Call Girl Srinagar Call Now 8617697112 Srinagar Escorts 24x7
 
W.D. Gann Theory Complete Information.pdf
W.D. Gann Theory Complete Information.pdfW.D. Gann Theory Complete Information.pdf
W.D. Gann Theory Complete Information.pdf
 
VIP Independent Call Girls in Bandra West 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Esc...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Bandra West 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Esc...VIP Independent Call Girls in Bandra West 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Esc...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Bandra West 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Esc...
 
CBD Belapur Expensive Housewife Call Girls Number-📞📞9833754194 No 1 Vipp HIgh...
CBD Belapur Expensive Housewife Call Girls Number-📞📞9833754194 No 1 Vipp HIgh...CBD Belapur Expensive Housewife Call Girls Number-📞📞9833754194 No 1 Vipp HIgh...
CBD Belapur Expensive Housewife Call Girls Number-📞📞9833754194 No 1 Vipp HIgh...
 
Toronto dominion bank investor presentation.pdf
Toronto dominion bank investor presentation.pdfToronto dominion bank investor presentation.pdf
Toronto dominion bank investor presentation.pdf
 
Kopar Khairane Russian Call Girls Number-9833754194-Navi Mumbai Fantastic Unl...
Kopar Khairane Russian Call Girls Number-9833754194-Navi Mumbai Fantastic Unl...Kopar Khairane Russian Call Girls Number-9833754194-Navi Mumbai Fantastic Unl...
Kopar Khairane Russian Call Girls Number-9833754194-Navi Mumbai Fantastic Unl...
 
(Sexy Sheela) Call Girl Mumbai Call Now 👉9920725232👈 Mumbai Escorts 24x7
(Sexy Sheela) Call Girl Mumbai Call Now 👉9920725232👈 Mumbai Escorts 24x7(Sexy Sheela) Call Girl Mumbai Call Now 👉9920725232👈 Mumbai Escorts 24x7
(Sexy Sheela) Call Girl Mumbai Call Now 👉9920725232👈 Mumbai Escorts 24x7
 
Call Girls Koregaon Park Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance Booking
Call Girls Koregaon Park Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance BookingCall Girls Koregaon Park Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance Booking
Call Girls Koregaon Park Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance Booking
 
falcon-invoice-discounting-unlocking-prime-investment-opportunities
falcon-invoice-discounting-unlocking-prime-investment-opportunitiesfalcon-invoice-discounting-unlocking-prime-investment-opportunities
falcon-invoice-discounting-unlocking-prime-investment-opportunities
 
VIP Independent Call Girls in Andheri 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Andheri 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts...VIP Independent Call Girls in Andheri 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Andheri 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai Escorts...
 
➥🔝 7737669865 🔝▻ Malda Call-girls in Women Seeking Men 🔝Malda🔝 Escorts Ser...
➥🔝 7737669865 🔝▻ Malda Call-girls in Women Seeking Men  🔝Malda🔝   Escorts Ser...➥🔝 7737669865 🔝▻ Malda Call-girls in Women Seeking Men  🔝Malda🔝   Escorts Ser...
➥🔝 7737669865 🔝▻ Malda Call-girls in Women Seeking Men 🔝Malda🔝 Escorts Ser...
 
cost-volume-profit analysis.ppt(managerial accounting).pptx
cost-volume-profit analysis.ppt(managerial accounting).pptxcost-volume-profit analysis.ppt(managerial accounting).pptx
cost-volume-profit analysis.ppt(managerial accounting).pptx
 
Navi Mumbai Cooperetive Housewife Call Girls-9833754194-Natural Panvel Enjoye...
Navi Mumbai Cooperetive Housewife Call Girls-9833754194-Natural Panvel Enjoye...Navi Mumbai Cooperetive Housewife Call Girls-9833754194-Natural Panvel Enjoye...
Navi Mumbai Cooperetive Housewife Call Girls-9833754194-Natural Panvel Enjoye...
 
7 tips trading Deriv Accumulator Options
7 tips trading Deriv Accumulator Options7 tips trading Deriv Accumulator Options
7 tips trading Deriv Accumulator Options
 
VIP Independent Call Girls in Mira Bhayandar 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai ...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Mira Bhayandar 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai ...VIP Independent Call Girls in Mira Bhayandar 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai ...
VIP Independent Call Girls in Mira Bhayandar 🌹 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Mumbai ...
 
VIP Call Girl in Mira Road 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday ...
VIP Call Girl in Mira Road 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday ...VIP Call Girl in Mira Road 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday ...
VIP Call Girl in Mira Road 💧 9920725232 ( Call Me ) Get A New Crush Everyday ...
 

Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

  • 1. Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging Artur Sepp Global Risk Analytics Bank of America Merrill Lynch, London artur.sepp@baml.com Global Derivatives Trading & Risk Management 2014 Amsterdam May 13-15, 2014 1
  • 2. Plan 1) Empirical evidence for the log-normality of implied and realized volatil- ities of stock indices 2) Apply the beta stochastic volatility (SV) model for quantifying implied and realized index skews 3) Origin of the premium for risk-neutral skews and its impacts on profit- and-loss (P&L) of delta-hedging strategies 4) Optimal delta-hedging strategies to improve Sharpe ratios 5) Argue why log-normal beta SV model is better than its alternatives 2
  • 3. References Technical details can be found in references Beta stochastic volatility model: Karasinski, P., Sepp, A., (2012), “Beta stochastic volatility model,” Risk, October, 67-73 http://ssrn.com/abstract=2150614 Sepp, A. (2013), “Consistently Modeling Joint Dynamics of Volatility and Underlying To Enable Effective Hedging”, Global Derivatives conference in Amsterdam 2013 http://math.ut.ee/~spartak/papers/PresentationGlobalDerivatives2013.pdf Implied and realized skews, jumps, delta-hedging P&L: Sepp, A., (2014), “Empirical Calibration and Minimum-Variance Delta Under Log-Normal Stochastic Volatility Dynamics” http://ssrn.com/abstract=2387845 Sepp, A., (2014), “Log-Normal Stochastic Volatility Model: Pricing of Vanilla Options and Econometric Estimation” http://ssrn.com/abstract=2522425 Optimal delta-hedging strategies: Sepp, A., (2013), “When You Hedge Discretely: Optimization of Sharpe Ratio for Delta-Hedging Strategy under Discrete Hedging and Transaction Costs,” Journal of Investment Strategies 3(1), 19-59 http://ssrn.com/abstract=1865998 3
  • 4. How to build a dynamic model for volatility? Suppose we know nothing about stochastic volatility We want to learn only by looking at empirical data How do we start? 4
  • 5. Empirical frequency of implied vol is log-normal First, check whether stationary distribution of volatility is: A) Normal or B) Log-normal Compute the empirical frequency of one-month implied at-the-money (ATM) volatility proxied by the VIX index for last 20 years Daily observations normalized to have zero mean and unit variance Left figure: empirical frequency of the VIX - it is definitely not normal Right figure: the frequency of the logarithm of the VIX - it does look like the normal density (especially for the right tail)! 3% 4% 5% 6% 7% Frequency Empirical frequency of normalized VIX Empirical Standard Normal 0% 1% 2% -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 Frequency VIX 3% 4% 5% 6% 7% Frequency Empirical frequency of normalized logarithm of the VIX Empirical Standard Normal 0% 1% 2% 3% -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 Frequency Log-VIX 5
  • 6. Empirical frequency of realized vol is log-normal Compute one-month realized volatility of daily returns on the S&P 500 index for each month over non-overlapping periods for last 60 years from 1954 Below is the empirical frequency of normalized historical volatility Left figure: frequency of realized vol - it is definitely not normal Right figure: frequency of the logarithm of realized vol - again it does look like the normal density (especially for the right tail) 4% 6% 8% 10% Frequency Frequency of Historic 1m Volatility of S&P500 returns Empirical Standard Normal 0% 2% 4% -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 Frequency Vol 4% 6% 8% 10% Frequency Frequency of Logarithm of Historic 1m Volatility of S&P500 Empirical Standard Normal 0% 2% 4% -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 FrequencyLog-Vol 6
  • 7. Dynamic model for volatility evolution should not be based on price-volatility correlation Now we look for a dynamic factor model for volatility (next slide) We cannot apply model based on correlation between S&P500 returns and changes in volatility because using correlation we can only predict the direction of change, not the magnitude of change For risk management of options, we need a factor model for volatility dynamics 7
  • 8. Factor model for volatility uses regression model for changes in vol V (tn) predicted by returns in price S(tn) V (tn) − V (tn−1) = β S(tn) − S(tn−1) S(tn−1) + V (tn−1) n (1) iid normal residuals n are scaled by vol V (tn−1) due to log-normality Volatility beta β explains about 70% of variations in volatility! Left figure: scatter plot of daily changes in the VIX vs returns on S&P 500 for past 14 years and estimated regression model Right: time series of empirical residuals n of regression model (1) Residual volatility does not exhibit any systemic patterns Regression model is stable across different estimation periods y = -1.08x R² = 67% 0% 5% 10% 15% 20% -10% -5% 0% 5% 10% ChangeinVIX Change in VIX vs Return on S&P500 -20% -15% -10% -5%-10% -5% 0% 5% 10% Return % on S&P 500 -10% 0% 10% 20% 30% Time Series of Residual Volatility -30% -20% Dec-99 Dec-00 Jan-02 Jan-03 Jan-04 Jan-05 Jan-06 Jan-07 Jan-08 Jan-09 Jan-10 Jan-11 Jan-12 Jan-13 Volatility beta β: expected change in ATM vol predicted by price return For return of −1%: expected change in vol = −1.08 × (−1%) = 1.08%8
  • 9. More evidence on log-normal dynamics of vol: indepen- dence of regression parameters on level of ATM vol Estimate empirically the elasticity α of volatility by: 1) computing volatility beta and residual vol-of-vol for each month using daily returns within this month 2) test if the logarithm of these variables depends on the log of the VIX in that month using regression model Left figure: test ˆβ(V ) = βV α by regression model: ln ˆβ(V ) = α ln V + c Right: test ˆε(V ) = εV 1+α by regression model: ln |ˆε(V )| = (1+α) ln V +c The estimated value of elasticity α is small and statistically insignificant Indeed the realized volatility is close to log-normal y = 0.15x + 0.14 R² = 2% -0.5 0.0 0.5 1.0 1.5 ln(|VIXbeta|) ln(VIX beta) vs ln(Average VIX) -1.5 -1.0 -0.5 -2.5 -2.0 -1.5 -1.0 -0.5 0.0 ln(|VIXbeta|) ln(Average VIX) y = 0.14x - 0.45 R² = 4% -0.5 0.0 0.5 ln(|VIXresidualvol) ln(VIX residualvol) vs ln(AverageVIX) -1.5 -1.0 -2.5 -2.0 -1.5 -1.0 -0.5 0.0 ln(|VIXresidualvol) ln(Average VIX) 9
  • 10. Empirical estimation of volatility elasticity α: volatility dynamics is log-normal (maximum likelihood estimation - see my paper on log-normal volatility) Figure: 95% confidence bounds for estimated value of elasticity α using realized (RV) and implied (IV) volatilities for 4 major stock indices -1.0 -0.5 0.0 0.5 1.0 Alpha 95% confidence bounds for estimated elasticity alpha -1.0 VIX,Reg VSTOXX,Reg VIX,ML VSTOXX,ML IV,S&P500 IV,FTSE100 IV,NIKKEI IV,STOXX50 RV,S&P500 RV,FTSE100 RV,NIKKEI RV,STOXX50 Estimation results confirm evidence for log-normality of volatility: [i] In majority of cases (7 out of 12), bounds for ˆα contain zero [ii] One outlier ˆα = −0.4 (realized volatility of Nikkei index) [iii] Remaining are symmetric: two with ˆα ≈ 0.2 and two with ˆα ≈ −0.2 To conclude - alternative SV models are safely rejected: 1) Heston and Stein-Stein SV models with α = −1 2) 3/2 SV model with α = 1 Also, excellent econometric study by Christoffersen-Jacobs-Mimouni (2010), Review of Financial Studies: log-normal SV outperforms its alternatives10
  • 11. Beta stochastic volatility model (Karasinski-Sepp 2012): is obtained by summarizing our empirical findings for dynamics of index price S(t) and volatility V (t): dS(t) = V (t)S(t)dW(0)(t) dV (t) = β dS(t) S(t) + εV (t)dW(1)(t) + κ(θ − V (t))dt (2) V (t) is either returns vol or short-term ATM implied vol W(0)(t) and W(1)(t) are independent Brownian motions β is volatility beta - sensitivity of volatility to changes in price ε is residual vol-of-vol - standard deviation of residual changes in vol Mean-reversion rate κ and mean θ are added for stationarity of volatility A closer inspection shows that these dynamics are similar to other log- normal based SV models widely used in industry: A) in interest rates - SABR model B) in equities - a version of log-normal based aka exp-OU SV models We arrived to beta SV model (2) only by looking at empirical data for realized&implied vols and using factor model for vol dynamics 11
  • 12. Implied interpretation of volatility beta and residual vol- of-vol from Black-Scholes-Merton (BSM) volatilities, σBSM(z) as func- tions of log-strike z = ln(K/S), inferred form option prices Compute vol skew SKEW and convexity CONV for small maturities: SKEW = [σBSM(5%) − σBSM(−5%)] / (2 × 5%) CONV = [σBSM(5%) + σBSM(−5%) − 2σBSM(0)] / 5%2 Volatility beta β[I] implied by skew: β[I] = 2 × SKEW Residual vol-of-vol ε[I] implied by convexity: ε[I] = 3 × σBSM(0) × CONV + 2 × (SKEW)2 As model parameters, volatility beta (left figure) and idiosyncratic vol- of-vol (right figure) have orthogonal impact on BSM implied vols 15% 25% 35% BSMimpliedvols Impact of volatility beta on BSM vol Base vols with beta = -1 Down vols with beta = -0.5 Up vols with beta = -1.5 5% 15% 0.7 0.78 0.86 0.94 1.02 1.1 BSMimpliedvols Strike 15% 25% 35% BSMimpliedvols Impact of residual vol-vol on BSM vol Base vols with ResidVol=1.0 Down vols with ResidVol=0.5 Up vols with ResidVol=1.5 5% 15% 0.70 0.78 0.86 0.94 1.02 1.10 BSMimpliedvols Strike 12
  • 13. Topic II: Implied and realized skew using beta SV model Use time series from April 2007 to December 2013 for one-month ATM vols and the S&P500 index with estimation window of one month Figure 1): Implied and realized one month volatilities ATM volatility tends to trade at a small premium to realized Figure 2): One-month average of implied and realized volatility beta Implied volatility beta consis- tently over-estimates realized one Figure 3): Average of implied and realized residual vol-of-vol Implied residual vol-of-vol signifi- cantly over-estimates realized Absolute (Abs) and relative (Rel) spreads between implieds&realizeds Spreads Vol Beta VolVol Abs, Mean 0.51% -0.27 0.78 Abs, Stdev 6.2% 0.21 0.16 Rel, Mean 7% 21% 57% Rel, Stdev 24% 17% 11% 20% 30% 40% 50% 60% 70% 80% 1m ATM Implied Volatility 1m Realized Volatility 0% 10% 20% Feb-07 Sep-07 Apr-08 Nov-08 Jun-09 Jan-10 Aug-10 Mar-11 Oct-11 May-12 Dec-12 Jul-13 -0.5 0.0 Feb-07 Sep-07 Apr-08 Nov-08 Jun-09 Jan-10 Aug-10 Mar-11 Oct-11 May-12 Dec-12 Jul-13 Implied Volatility Beta Realized Volatility Beta -2.0 -1.5 -1.0 0.5 0.8 1.1 1.4 1.7 Implied Residual Vol-of-Vol Realized Residual Vol-of-Vol 0.2 0.5 Feb-07 Sep-07 Apr-08 Nov-08 Jun-09 Jan-10 Aug-10 Mar-11 Oct-11 May-12 Dec-12 Jul-13 13
  • 14. Explanation of the skew premium in a quantitative way In a very interesting study, Bakshi-Kapadia-Madan (2003), Review of Financial Studies, find relationship between risk-neutral and physical skew using investor’s risk-aversion Fat tails (not necessarily skewed) of returns distribution under phys- ical measure P along with risk-aversion lead to increased negative skeweness under the risk neutral-measure Q Quantitatively: SKEWENESSQ = SKEWENESSP − γ × KURTOSISP × VOLATILITYP SKEWENESSQ is risk-neutral skeweness of price returns SKEWENESSP is physical skeweness of price returns KURTOSISP is kurtosis as measure of fat tails of physical distribution VOLATILITYP is volatility of returns under physical distribution γ > 0 is risk-aversion parameter of investors To conclude: the risk-neutral premium arises because risk-averse investors assign higher value to insurance puts Important: Volatility skew is proportional to skeweness of returns 14
  • 15. Apply Merton Jump-Diffusion (JD) with normal jumps Figure 1: Use last 14 years of daily returns on S&P 500 index to estimate skeweness and kurtosis of returns - see column ”Empirical P” Table 1: Use γ = 22.0 (estimated from time series of implied vols by inverting BKM formula) and apply BKM to obtain SKEWENESSQ = −2 Figure&Table 2: Fit Merton JD to first four moments of physical and risk-neutral distribution (jump frequency is set to one jump per month) From calibration: JumpMean is 0 under empirical P and -5% under Q Empirical P Q Stdev 21% 21% Skeweness 0 -2 Kurtosis 8 8 Merton JD params P Q Jump Mean 0% -5% Jump Volatility 4% 0% Diffusion vol 17% 13% Jump Frequency 12 12 Figure 3: Value one month options - implied volatility from Merton JD under Q is skewed, while implied volatility under P is symmetric 4% 6% 8% 10% Frequency Frequency of S&P500 daily returns Empirical Frequency Normal Density 0% 2% 4% -9% -7% -5% -4% -2% 0% 2% 4% 6% 7% Frequency Daily return 4% 6% 8% 10% Frequency Frequency of S&P500 daily returns Empirical Frequency Physical Merton under P Risk-Neutral 0% 2% 4% -9% -7% -5% -4% -2% 0% 2% 4% 6% 7% Frequency Daily return Risk-Neutral Merton under Q 25% 30% ImpliedVol Implied volatility skew for one month options on S&P500 Physical Merton under P Risk-Neutral Merton under Q 15% 20% 0.75 0.85 0.95 1.05 1.15 1.25 ImpliedVol Strike 15
  • 16. To summarize our developments so far: 1) Log-normal beta SV model is consistent with empirical distribu- tion for realized and implied vols 2) Beta SV model is applied to quantify realized and implied skews and the spread between them, which turns out to be significant Any option position is mark-to-market so no point of arguing about market prices However, hedging strategy is discretionary and can be the ”edge” By computing the delta-hedge: should we use implied or realized skews? This question is analyzed in the third topic of my talk: Part I - Quantitative analysis of impact of realized and implied skews on delta-hedging P&L Part II - Monte-Carlo simulations for empirical analysis 16
  • 17. Statistically significant spread between realized and im- plied skews β[R] − β[I] leads to dependence on realized price returns and invalidates the minimum-variance hedge Minimum-variance delta ∆ is applied to hedge against changes in price and price-induced changes in volatility Given hedging portfolio Π for option U on S Π(t, S, V ) = U(t, S, V ) − ∆ × S ∆ is computed by minimizing variance of Π using SV beta dynamics (2) under risk-neutral measure Q (classic approach) with implied vol betaβ[I] ∆ = US + β[I] × UV /S where US and UV model delta and vega To see dependence on return δS due to spread between implied vol beta β[I] and realized β[R]: given δS apply beta SV for change in vol δV under physical measure P: δV = β[R] × δS + ε[R] × V √ δt By Taylor expansion of realized P&L: δΠ(t, S, V ) = β[R] − β[I] × UV × δS + ε[R] × UV × V √ δt + O(dt) ε(R) is random non-hedgable part from residual vol-of-vol O(dt) part includes quadratic terms (δS)2, (δV )2, (δS)(δV ) 17
  • 18. Volatility skew-beta is important for computing correct option delta Figure 1) Apply regression model (1) for time series of ATM vols for maturities T = {1m, 3m, 6m, 12m, 24m} (m=month) to estimate regression volatility beta βREGRES(T) using S&P500 returns: δσATM(T) = βREGRES(T) × δS Volatility beta for SV dynamics is in- stantaneous beta for very small T Regression vol beta decays in log-T due to mean-reversion: long-dated ATM vols are less sensitive in abso- lute values to price-returns Figure 2) Implied vol skew for ma- turity T has similar decay in log-T Figure 3) Volatility skew-beta is regression beta divided by skew Skew-Beta(T) ∝ βREGRES(T)/SKEW(T) It is nearly maturity-homogeneous y = 0.19*ln(x) - 0.37 R² = 99% -0.6 -0.4 -0.2 0.0 Regression Volatility Beta(T) -1.0 -0.8 -0.6 0.08 0.25 0.50 1.00 2 Maturity T Regression Vol Beta(T) Decay of Vol Beta in ln(T) y = 0.16*ln(x) - 0.29 R² = 99% -0.4 -0.2 0.0 Implied Volatility Skew (T) -0.8 -0.6 1m 3m 6m 1y 2y Maturity, T Vol Skew (T) Decay of Skew in ln(T) y = 0.06*ln(x) + 1.41 R² = 80%1.0 1.5 2.0 Volatility Skew-Beta(T) Vol Skew-Beta (T) 0.0 0.5 1m 3m 6m 1y 2y Maturity T Vol Skew-Beta (T) Decay of Vol Skew-Beta in ln(T) 18
  • 19. Technical supplement to compute model implied skew- beta (omitted during the talk) Using backward pricers and PDE: 1) Compute the term structure of ATM volatility σATM(S0; T) and skew SKEW(S0; T), with strike width α%, implied by model parameters 2) Bump the spot price down by α%, S1 = (1 − α%)S0, and apply corre- sponding bumping rule for model state variables For the beta SV: V1 → V0 + βα , θ → θ + β 2κ α (3) 3) Compute new term structure of ATM vols σATM(S1; T) 4) Compute model implied skew-beta Skew-Beta(T) = − σATM(S1; T) − σATM(S0; T) α × SKEW(S0; T) (4) Using Monte-Carlo pricers: 1) Specify number of paths and simulate set of independent Brownians 2) Compute paths starting from {S0, V0} 2A) Evaluate term structure of ATM volatility σATM(K = S0; T) and skew using σ(K = S1; T), both using Brownians in 1) 3) Compute paths starting from {S1, V1} with S1 = (1 − α%)S0 and V (1) bumped as in Eq (3), using Brownians in 1) 4) Evaluate ATM vols σATM(K = S1; T) and skew-beta by Eq (4) 19
  • 20. Volatility and Skew contribution to P&L - important for volatility positions with daily mark-to-market! Mark BSM implied vol σBSM(K) in %-strike K relative to price S(0): σBSM(K; S) = σATM(S) + SKEW × Z(K; S) Z(K; S) is log-moneyness relative to current price S: Z(K; S) = ln (K × S(0)/S) SKEW < 0 is inferred from spread between call and put implied vols In practice, this form is augmented with extras for convexity and tails Any SV model implies quadratic form for implied vols near ATM strikes (Lewis 2000, Bergomi-Guyon 2012) so my approach for vol P&L is generic Volatility P&L arises from change in spot price S → S {1 + δS}: δσBSM(K; S) ≡ σBSM (K; S {1 + δS}) − σBSM(K; S) = δσATM(S) + SKEW × δZ(K; S) First contributor to P&L: change in ATM vol δσATM(S): δσATM(S) = σATM (S {1 + δS}) − σATM(S) Second contributor to P&L: change in log-moneyness relative to skew: δZ(K; S) = − ln(1 + δS) ≈ −δS 20
  • 21. Example of volatility and skew P&L with regression beta (omitted during the talk) σATM(S(0)) = 15%, δS = −1.0%, SKEW = −0.5, βREGRESS = −1.0 It is very important how we keep log-moneyness Z(K; S): 1) For strikes re-based to new ATM level (forward-based strikes): S → S{1 + δS} and log-moneyness does not change δZ(K; S) = 0 P&L arises from change in ATM vol predicted by price return com- puted using βREGRESS: δσBSM(K) = βREGRESS × δS = −1.0 × −1% = 1% 2) For strikes fixed at old ATM level (vanilla strikes with fixed S(0)) Thus log-moneyness changes by δZ(K; S) ≈ −δS = 1% P&L is change in ATM vol adjusted for change in money-ness: δσBSM(K) = βREGRESS ×δS+SKEW×δS = 1%+(−0.5)×(1%) = 0.50% 0.5% 0.8% 1.0% Change in vols, strikes fixed to ATM 0 Change in vols, strikes re-based to ATM 1 0.0% 0.3% 0.5% 90% 95% 100% 105% Strike K% 18% 21% BSMvol(K) BSM vol 0, strikes fixed to ATM 0 BSM vol 1, strikes fixed to ATM 0 BSM vol 1, strikes re-based to ATM 1 12% 15% 90% 95% 100% 105% BSMvol(K) Strike K% 21
  • 22. Changes in skew are not correlated to changes in price and ATM vols - important for correct predict of vol and skew P&L Empirical observations yet again confirm log-normality dynamics! (Using S&P500 data from January 2007 to December 2013) Figure 1: weekly changes in 100% − 95% skew vs price returns for maturity of one month (left) and one year (right) Regression slope = 0.13 (1m) & 0.03 (1y); R2 = 0% (1m) & 1% (1y) -0.1 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 ChangeinSkew Change in 1m skew vs Price Return y = 0.13x - 0.00 R² = 0% -0.3 -0.2 -0.1 -15% -5% 5% 15% ChangeinSkew Price return y = 0.03x - 0.00 -0.02 0 0.02 0.04 ChangeinSkew Change in 1y skew vs Price Return y = 0.03x - 0.00 R² = 1% -0.06 -0.04 -0.02 -15% -5% 5% 15% ChangeinSkew Price return Figure 2: weekly changes in 100% − 95% skew vs changes in ATM vols for maturity of one month (left) and one year (right) Regression slope = −0.15 (1m) & −0.06 (1y); R2 = 0% (1m) & 2% (1y) -0.1 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 ChangeinSkew Change in 1m skew vs 1m ATM vol y = -0.15x - 0.00 R² = 0%-0.3 -0.2 -0.1 -15% -5% 5% 15% ChangeinSkew Change in ATM vol -0.02 0 0.02 0.04 ChangeinSkew Change in 1y skew vs 1y ATM vol y = -0.09x - 0.00 R² = 2% -0.06 -0.04 -0.02 -15% -5% 5% 15% ChangeinSkew Change in ATM vol 22
  • 23. Volatility skew-beta combines the skew and volatility P&L together Given price return δS: S → S {1 + δS} Volatility P&L is computed by: 1) For strikes re-based to new ATM level Log-moneyness does not change, δZ(K; S) = 0 P&L follows change in ATM vol predicted by regression beta and vol skew-beta: δσBSM(K) ≡ δσATM(S) = βREGRESS × δS = SKEWBETA × SKEW × δS 2) For strikes fixed at old ATM level Log-moneyness changes by δZ(K; S) ≈ −δS P&L is change in ATM vol adjusted for skew P&L: δσBSM(K) ≡ δσATM(S) − SKEW × δS = [SKEWBETA − 1] × SKEW × δS Positive change in ATM vol from negative return is reduced by skew 23
  • 24. Volatility skew-beta under minimum-variance approach is applied to compute min-var delta ∆ for hedging against changes in price and price-induced changes in implied vol A) We adjust option delta for change in implied vol at fixed strikes B) The adjustment is proportional to option vega at this strike: ∆(K, T) = ∆BSM(K, T) + [SKEWBETA(T) − 1] × SKEW(T) × VBSM(K, T)/ ∆BSM(K, T) is BSM delta for strike K and maturity T VBSM(K, T) is BSM vega, both evaluated at volatility skew I classify volatility regimes using vol skew-beta for delta-adjustments: ∆(K, T) =    ∆BSM(K, T) + SKEW(T) × VBSM(K, T)/S, Sticky local ∆BSM(K, T), Sticky strike ∆BSM(K, T) − SKEW(T) × VBSM(K, T)/S, Sticky delta ∆BSM(K, T) + 1 2SKEW(T) × VBSM(K, T)/S, Empirical S&P50 ”Shadow” delta is obtained using ratio O (may be different from 1/2): ∆(K, T) = ∆BSM(K, T) + O × SKEW(T) × VBSM(K, T)/S which is traders’ ad-hoc adjustment of option delta 24
  • 25. Does ”shadow” delta create a vision or an illusion? We need a quantitative model to describe different volatility regimes and produce correct option delta ! 25
  • 26. Volatility skew-beta and vol regimes (also see Bergomi 2009): SkewBeta =    2, Sticky local regime: minimum-variance delta in SV and LV 1, Sticky strike regime: BSM delta evaluated at implied skew 0, Sticky delta regime: model delta in space-homogeneous SV Empirical estimates for skew-beta and its lower and upper bounds are found by regression model (see my paper) In beta SV model, with empirical estimate of vol beta and adding jumps/risk- aversion to match skew premium, we fit empirical vol skew-beta: 1) S&P 500: empirical skew-beta of about 1.5 2) STOXX 50: strong skew-beta close to 2 3) NIKKEI: weak skew-beta is about 0.5 As result: beta SV model with jumps can produce the correct delta! 1.00 1.50 2.00 2.50 Vol Skew-Beta for S&P500 SVJ Skew-Beta with empirical beta 0.00 0.50 1m 3m 5m 7m 9m 11m 13m 15m 17m 19m 21m 23m T in months SVJ Skew-Beta with empirical beta Sticky local with Min-var delta Empirical bounds 1.00 1.50 2.00 2.50 Vol Skew-Beta for STOXX 50 SVJ Skew-Beta with empirical beta 0.00 0.50 1m 3m 5m 7m 9m 11m 13m 15m 17m 19m 21m 23m T in months SVJ Skew-Beta with empirical beta Sticky local with Min-var delta Empirical bounds 1.00 1.50 2.00 2.50 Vol Skew-Beta for NIKKEI SVJ Skew-Beta with empirical beta Sticky local with Min-var delta Empirical bounds 0.00 0.50 1m 3m 5m 7m 9m 11m 13m 15m 17m 19m 21m 23m T in months 26
  • 27. Second part of topic III: Monte Carlo analysis of delta- hedging P&L Now let’s have some fun and do some number crunching! We are going to simulate the market dynamics and compare hedging performance under different specifications of delta In next few slides I briefly discuss the methodology Details are provided for the interested for self-studying Details are important to understand how to improve the performance of delta-hedging strategies Application to actual market data produces equivalent conclusions In my talk, I will only discuss final results and conclusions 27
  • 28. Apply beta SV for dynamics under physical measure P: 1) Index price S(t), 2) Volatility of returns Vret(t): 3) Short-term implied volatility Vimp(t): dS(t) = Vret(t)S(t)dW(0)(t) dVret(t) = κ[P] θ[P] − Vret(t) dt + β[P]Vret(t)dW(0)(t) + ε[P]Vret(t)dW(1)(t) dVimp(t) = κ[I] θ[I] − Vimp(t) dt + β[I]Vimp(t)dW(0)(t) + ε[I]Vret(t)dW(1)(t) 4) At-the-money (ATM) implied vol Vatm(t) is obtained by computing model implied ATM vol for maturity T using model dynamics for Vimp(t) Important: Model parameters are estimated from time series by maximum likelihood methods - as a rule, parameters for returns vol [P] and for implied vol [I] are different Here, apply the same parameters for clarity Physical for Returns dVret(t), [P] Vol dVimp(t), [I] V.(0) 16% 16.75% θ[.] 16% 16.75% κ[.] 3.0 3.0 ε[.] 0.5 0.5 β[.] -1.0 -1.0 28
  • 29. Volatility and skew premiums are produced using BSM implied volatility, σBSM(K), as function of % strike K relative to S(0): σBSM(K) = Vatm(t) + SKEW × ln (K × S(0)/S(t)) (5) SKEW = −0.5 is vol implied skew specified exogenously by strike % BSM vol σBSM(K) σBSM(K) − Vret(0) 99% 17.25% 1.25% 100% 16.75% 0.75% 101% 16.25% 0.25% Market Skew -0.50 Important - option delta is computed using two models: 1) Beta SV model with market implied beta β[I] = -1.1 2) Beta SV model with empirical beta β[I] = -1.0 and jumps (risk- aversion) to price-in excessive skew −1.1 − 1.0 = −0.1 (discussed later) Both SV models fit to market skew exactly! [i] Premium of implied vol to realized vol is: 16.75% − 16% = 0.75% (in line with empirical spread) [ii] Premium of implied and empirical beta is: β[I] − β[R] = -1.1 − ( -1.0 ) = -0.1 (empirical is about −0.2) As we saw using Madan-Merton fits, physical dynamics don’t need to have asymmetric jumps to produce skew premium - now, skew premium arises from excess kurtosis produced by empirical SV model for returns29
  • 30. Consistency with market skew does not guar- antee fit to empirical dynamics Both hedging models are consistent with market implied skew However, we observe discrepancy: SV model with market implied beta,called Minimum variance hedge Implies vol skew-beta about 2.0 , which is inconsistent with empirical dynamics SV model with jumps and empirical beta, called Empirical hedge: Implies vol skew-beta about 1.6 , which is consistent with empirical dynamics Important - no re-calibration along a MC path is applied: Both hedging models are initially consistent with the market skew - as price S(t) and vol Vimp(t) change, both models remain very close to market skew Log-normality assumption - independence of implied&realized skew from volatility - comes into play 30
  • 31. Specification for trading in delta-hedged positions: 1) Straddle - short ATM put and call Figure 1: P&L profile with Delta= 0 is function of realized return squared Important: P&L/delta of straddle are not sensitive to realized/implied skew - Benefits from small realized variance of price returns 2) Risk-reversal - short put with strike 99% and long call with strike 101% of forward Figure 2: P&L profile with Delta= −0.8 is function of realized return Important: P&L/delta of risk-reversal are very sensitive to real- ized/implied skew - Benefits from small realized covariance of changes in price and ATM vol -5.0% -2.5% 0.0% 2.5% 5.0% PayOff+PV-DeltaHedge with Delta=0 PayOff -10.0% -7.5% -5.0% -10%-8%-6%-4%-2% 0% 2% 4% 6% 8%10% Straddle P&L vs Price return -2.5% 0.0% 2.5% 5.0% 7.5% 10.0% PayOff+PV-DeltaHedge with delta=-0.8 PayOff -10.0% -7.5% -5.0% -2.5% -10%-8%-6%-4%-2% 0% 2% 4% 6% 8%10% Risk-Reversal P&L vsPrice return 31
  • 32. Specification for notionals of delta-hedged positions Notionals are normalized by CashGamma=(1/2) × (S2)×OptionGamma Notionals for straddle: PutNotional(tn) = CallNotional(tn) = − 0.5 ATM CashGamma(tn) Notionals for risk-reversal: PutNotional(tn) = − 0.5 × (Vatm(tn))2T 2% × {Put Vega(tn)} CallNotional(tn) = + 0.5 × (Vatm(tn))2T 2% × {Call Vega(tn)} where 2% comes from strike width 2% = 101% − 99% Important: for Straddle, cash-gamma is 1.0 For Risk-reversal, the vanna (vega of delta) is 1.0 32
  • 33. Monte-Carlo analysis: P&L accrual Daily re-balancing at times tn, n = 1, ..., N At the end of each day, we roll into new position so straddle is at-the- money and risk-reversal has the same strike width Realized P&L is P&L on hedges minus P&L on options position: P&L = N n=1 {∆(tn−1) S(tn) − S(tn−1) − Π (T − dt, S(tn), Vatm(tn)) − Π T, S(tn−1), Vatm(tn−1) } Π (T, S(tn), Vatm(tn)) is options position computed using BSM formula and implied volatility skew (5) with Vatm(tn), T = 1/12, dt = 1/252 Transaction costs are 2bp (k = 0.0002) per delta-rebalancing: TC = k |∆(t0)| S(t0) + k N n=1 |∆(tn) − ∆(tn−1)| S(tn) where ∆(tn) is combined delta for newly rolled position Important: P&L across different days and paths is maturity-time and strike-space homogeneous - robust for statistical inference! 33
  • 34. Monte-Carlo analysis - final notes Trade notional is 100,000,000$ Realized P&L and explanatory variables are reported in thousands of $ Option maturity: one month Daily re-hedging with total for each path: N = 21 P&L is annualized by multiplying by 12 Draw 2,000 paths and compute realized P&L and price return, variance, volatility beta for changes in price and ATM vol, etc Price and volatility paths are the same for straddle and risk-reversal and different hedging strategies A) Analyze realized delta-hedging P&L (Profit and Loss) by [i] Realized P&L and its volatility, transaction costs [ii] Sharpe ratios B) P&L Explain using regression model with explanatory variables What factors (realized variance, covariance, etc) contribute to P&L 34
  • 35. 1. Analysis of realized P&L for straddle Figure left - realized P&L with no accounting for transaction costs Right - realized P&L with transaction costs Approximately, straddle P&L is spread between implied&realized vols2: P&L = Γ × (Vatm)2 − (Vret)2 = 100, 000 × (16.75%)2 − (16.00%)2 = 246 where Γ is cash-gamma notional in thousands $ Realized P&L little depends on the delta hedging strategy Important is that asset drift is zero, otherwise P&L-s for different hedging strategies have directional exposure to realized asset drift 244 243 100 200 300 Straddle P&L, zero trans costs 0 Minimum var Empirical beta 161 161 100 200 300 Straddle P&L after trans costs 161 161 0 Minimum var Empirical beta 35
  • 36. 2. Analysis of realized P&L for risk-reversal Figure: left - realized P&L with no accounting for transaction costs Right - realized P&L with transaction costs Approximately, risk-reversal P&L is spread between implied and realized co-variance of price and vol returns: P&L = V × −SKEW × (Vatm)2 + (Vret)2 + β[R] × (Vret)2 = 100, 211 × 0.5 × (16.75%)2 + (16.00%)2 − 0.88 × (16.00%)2 = 431 where V is vanna notional in thousands $ Again, realized P&L little depends on the delta hedging strategy when asset drift is zero 423 423 100 200 300 400 500 Risk-Reversal P&L, zero trans costs 0 100 Minimum var Empirical beta 190 192100 200 300 400 500 Risk-Reversal P&L after trans costs 190 192 0 100 Minimum var Empirical beta 36
  • 37. 3. Analysis of transaction costs Transaction costs are 2bp per traded delta notional or 1$ per 5, 000$ Left figure: realized transaction costs 1) Risk-reversal has higher transaction costs due to larger delta notional 2) Minimum variance hedge and empirical hedge imply about equal trans- action costs for straddle 3) Minimum variance hedge implies higher transaction costs for risk-reversal because of over-hedging the put side Right figure: volatility of transaction costs Volatility is about uniform and very small compared to mean costs 233 231100 200 300 Realized Transaction costs 83 82 0 Min var for straddle Empirical beta for straddle Min var for risk-reversal Empirical beta for risk-reversal 5 5 2 4 6 Volatility of Transaction costs 2 2 0 2 Min var for straddle Empirical beta for straddle Min var for risk-reversal Empirical beta for risk-reversal 37
  • 38. 4. Volatility of Realized P&L Left figure: P&L volatility without accounting for transaction costs Empirical hedge implies lower P&L volatility for: [i] Risk-reversal (about 20%) [ii] Straddle (about 2 − 3%) Because Minimum Variance delta over-hedges for put side and make delta more volatile Right figure: volatility of realized P&L accounting for costs 1) Transaction costs increase P&L slightly by about 1 − 2% 2) Contrast with reduction of realized P&L by about 50% 328 320 100 200 300 400 P&L Volatility, zero transaction costs 122 102 0 100 Min var for straddle Empirical beta for straddle Min var for risk-reversal Empirical beta for risk-reversal 331 323 100 200 300 400 P&L Volatility, after transaction costs 122 102 0 100 Min var for straddle Empirical beta for straddle Min var for risk-reversal Empirical beta for risk-reversal 38
  • 39. 5. Sharpe ratios of realized P&L-s Left figure: Sharpe ratios for delta-hedging P&L without account- ing for transaction costs Right figure: Sharpe ratios for P&L accounting for costs 1) For straddle, both Minimum Variance and Empirical hedges imply about the Sharpe ratio 2) For risk-reversal, Minimum Var hedge implies smaller Sharpe than Empirical hedge (by about 20%) because of higher P&L volatility and transaction costs 3.46 4.14 1.00 2.00 3.00 4.00 Sharpe ratio, zero tranaction costs 0.74 0.76 0.00 1.00 Min var for straddle Empirical beta for straddle Min var for risk-reversal Empirical beta for risk- reversal 1.56 1.88 0.50 1.00 1.50 2.00 Sharpe ratio, after transaction cost 0.49 0.50 0.00 0.50 Min var for straddle Empirical beta for straddle Min var for risk-reversal Empirical beta for risk- reversal 39
  • 40. P&L Attribution to risk factors is applied to understand what factors contribute to P&L by using regression P&L = α + s1X1 + s2X2 + s3X3 + s4X4 + s5X5 + s6X6 (6) α (”Alpha”) is theta related P&L - P&L we would realize if nothing would move X1 (”Var”) is returns variance: X1 = S(tn) S(tn−1) − 1 2 X2 (”VolChange”) is change in ATM vol: X2 = Vatm(tn) − Vatm(tn−1) X3 (”Covar”) is covariance: X3 = S(tn) S(tn−1) − 1 Vatm(tn) − Vatm(tn−1) X4 (”VarVol”) is variance of vol changes: X4 = Vatm(tn) − Vatm(tn−1) 2 X5 (”Return3”) is cubic return: X5 = S(tn) S(tn−1) − 1 3 X6 (”Return”) is realized return: X6 = S(tn) S(tn−1) − 1 Summation runs from n = 1 to n = N, N = 21 R2 indicates how well the realized variables explain realized P&L (not accounting for transaction costs) - we should aim for R2 = 90% Some explanatory variables are correlated so it is robust to test reduced regressions 40
  • 41. P&L explain for straddle by realized variance of returns: Empirical hedge has stronger explanatory power Is needed to confirm theoretical P&L explain by MC simulations For P&L of straddle hedged at implied vol, first-order approximation: V 2 atm − n S(tn) S(tn−1) − 1 2 First term is alpha or ”carry” - approximate alpha is α = Γ × V 2 atm = 100, 000 × 0.16752 = 2806 Second term is short risk to realized variance - key variable for P&L Theoretical slope should be −Γ = −100, 000 Figure: explanatory power using only realized variance is weak because of impact of other variables and skew (for multiple variables, R2 ≈ 90%) P&L = -48,768*Var + 1,559 R² = 30% 0 4,000 P&L Straddle P&L by Min-Var Hedge -8,000 -4,000 0.00 0.05 0.10 0.15 P&L Realized Variance P&L = -55,132*Var + 1,730 R² = 40% 0 4,000 P&L Straddle P&L by Empirical hedge -8,000 -4,000 0.00 0.05 0.10 0.15 P&L Realized Variance 41
  • 42. P&L explain for risk-reversal by realized vol beta: Empirical hedge implies that realized vol beta is clear driver behind P&L of risk-reversal with R2 = 50% For P&L of risk-reversal hedged at implied vol skew, approximation: −SKEW × V 2 atm + n S(tn) S(tn−1) − 1 2 + n S(tn) S(tn−1) − 1 (Vatm(tn) − Vatm(tn−1)) In terms of returns vol Vret and implied vol beta βR: −SKEW × V 2 atm + V 2 ret + β[R] × V 2 ret First term is ”carry” or alpha Second term is risk to realized beta between returns and vol - key variable In our example: α = 0.5 × V × {(16.75%)2 + (16.00%)2} = 2, 682 Slope= V × (16.00%)2 = 2, 560 P&L = 2129*Beta + 2570 R² = 37% 0 1500 3000Risk-Reversal P&L by Min-Var Hedge -1500 0 -2.0 -1.5 -1.0 -0.5 P&L Realized Volatility Beta P&L = 2050*Beta + 2490 R² = 49% 0 1500 3000Risk-Reversal P&L by Empirical Hedge -1500 0 -2.0 -1.5 -1.0 -0.5 P&L Realized Volatility Beta 42
  • 43. Important: vol beta (for skew) is comparable to Black- Scholes-Merton (BSM) implied volatility (for one strike) 1) Volatility and vol beta are meaningful and intuitive model pa- rameters which can be inferred from both implied and historical data Implied vol σ[I] is inferred from option market price Realized vol σ[R] is volatility of price returns Implied vol beta β[I] is inferred from market skew (β[I] ≈ 2 × SKEW) Realized vol beta β[R] is change in implied ATM volatility predicted by price returns: β[R] = dS(t)dVatm(t) /(σ[R])2 2) Both serve as directs input for computation of hedges 3) Both allow for P&L explain of vanilla options in terms of implied and realized model parameters: Implied/realized volatility- P&L of delta-hedged straddle: σ[I] 2 − σ[R] 2 Implied/realized volatility beta- P&L of short delta-hedged risk-reversal (more noisy because of contribution from σ[R]): −β[I] × 1 2 σ[I] 2 + σ[R] 2 + β[R] × σ[R] 2 43
  • 44. Conclusion: existing practical approaches for hedging improvement are not fully satisfactory - we need proper model for dynamic delta-hedging! A) Hedge all vega exposure B) Recalibration for computing delta-risks (most common): ⊗ Project change in implied volatility using empirical backbone (For example, by applying empirical volatility skew-beta) ⊗ Re-calibrate valuation model to bumped volatility surface ⊗ Re-valuate and compute delta by finite-differences However runs into problems: 1) A) - vega-hedging is (very) expensive and unprofitable unless implied skew and vol-of-vol are sold at large premiums to future realizeds 2) B) - re-calibration works poorly for path-dependent and multi- asset products and it makes P&L explain very noisy Recall applying regression for P&L explain of straddle and risk-reversal 3) any mix of A) and B) becomes very tedious for CVA computations Important: the choice between local vol (LV) or stoch vol (SV) is irrel- evant when hedging using minimum variance hedge at implied vol skew - any combination of LV and SV produces almost the same deltas! 44
  • 45. Beta SV model with jumps is fitted to empirical&implied dynamics for computing correct delta (Sepp 2014): dS(t) S(t) = (µ(t) − λ(eη − 1)) dt + V (t)dW(0)(t) + (eη − 1) dN(t) dV (t) = κ(θ − V (t))dt + βV (t)dW(0)(t) + εV (t)dW(1)(t) + βη dN(t) 1) Consistent with empirical dynamics of implied ATM volatility by specifying empirical volatility beta β 2) Has jumps, as degree of risk-aversion, to make model fit to both empirical dynamics and risk-neutral skew premium Only one parameter with simple calibration! - explained in a bit Jumps/risk-aversion under risk-neutral measure Q produced by: Poisson process N(t) with intensity λ: negative&positive jumps in returns&vols with constant size η < 0&βη > 0 3) Easy-to-implement (with no extra parameters) extension to multi- asset dynamics using common jumps - produces basket correlation skew 4) Beta SVJ model is robust to produce optimal hedges for path- dependent and multi-asset trades and CVA 45
  • 46. Third to last topic: closed-form solution for log-normal Beta SV Mean-reverting log-normal SV models are not analytically tractable I derive a very accurate exp-affine approximation for moment generating function (details in my paper) Idea comes from information theory: apply Kullback-Leibler relative en- tropy for unknown PDF p(x) and test PDF q(x) with moment constraints: xkp(x)dx = xkq(x)dx, k = 1, 2, ... Now let’s think in terms of moment function: [i] MGF for Beta SV model with normal driver for SV (as in Stein-Stein SV model) has exact solution, which has exp-affine form [ii] Correction for log-normal SV has an exp-affine form 15% 20% 25% 30% 35% Implied vol for 1y S&P500 options, beta SV, NO JUMPS Analytic for Normal SV 5% 10% 15% 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0 1.1 1.2 1.3 Strike Analytic for Normal SV Closed-form for Log-normal SV Monte-Carlo for Log-normal SV 15% 20% 25% 30% 35% Implied vol for 1y S&P500 options, beta SV, WITH JUMPS 5% 10% 15% 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0 1.1 1.2 1.3 Strike Analytic for Normal SV Closed-form for Log-normal SV Monte-Carlo for Log-normal SV 46
  • 47. Proof that closed-form MFG for log-normal model pro- duces theoretically consistent probability density 1) Derive solutions for excepted values, variances, and covariances of the log-price and quadratic variance (QV) by solving PDE directly 2) Prove that moments derived using approximate MGF equal to theo- retical moments derived in 1) Using closed-form MFG for log-normal model, we apply standard valuation methods for affine SV models based on Lipton-Lewis formula Implementation of closed-form moment function (MGF), MC, and PDE pricers produce values of vanilla options on equity and quadratic variance that are equal within numerical accuracy of these methods 15% 20% 25% 30% 35% Implied vol for 1y S&P500 options, beta SV, NO JUMPS Closed-form MGF 5% 10% 15% 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0 1.1 1.2 1.3 Strike Closed-form MGF Monte-Carlo PDE, numerical solver 15% 20% 25% 30% 35% Implied vol for 1y S&P500 options, beta SV, WITH JUMPS Closed-form MGF 5% 10% 15% 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0 1.1 1.2 1.3 Strike Closed-form MGF Monte-Carlo PDE, numerical solver 47
  • 48. Second to last topic - optimal hedging under discrete trading and transaction costs To adopt to practical option trading: a) change ”kid” to ”trader” b) change ”cantaloupes” to ”millions of delta over an infinitesimal time period dt” As we saw in simulation of P&L, we need quantitative framework that incorporates discrete hedging and optimizes trade-off between: the reward - higher P&L and lower transaction costs the risk - higher P&L volatility 48
  • 49. Illustration of trading in implied&realized vol with strad- dle: unique optimal hedging frequency can be found! Figure 1) Forecast expected upside: the spread between implied and real- ized vol for given maturity T This is independent of valua- tion&hedging model and hedging frequency Figure 2) Forecast P&L volatility and transaction costs These depend on valuation&hedging model and hedging frequency Part of P&L volatility is not hedge- able due to vol-of-vol and jumps - Not optimal to hedge too fre- quently Figure 3) Obtain Sharpe ratio as ra- tio of forecast P&L after costs and P&L volatility 1% 2% 3% Expected/Forcasted P&L(N) 0% 1% 10 160 310 460 610 760 910 N - hedging frequency 1% 2% 3% Expected/Forcasted P&L Volatility and Costs (N) P&L Volatility Transaction costs 0% 1% 10 160 310 460 610 760 910 N - hedging frequency 0.6 0.8 1.0 1.2 1.4 Expected/Forcasted Sharpe Ratio (N) 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 10 160 310 460 610 760 910 N - hedging frequency 49
  • 50. Solution for optimal Sharpe ratio with dynamics under physical measure driven by Diffusion and SV with jumps Sharpe(N) = Expected P&L − TransactionCosts(N) P&L Volatility(N) N is hedging frequency - for details see my paper on optimal delta-hedging Using this solution we can analyze: Figure 1) What maturity is optimal to trade given the forecast spread between implieds and realizeds (longer maturities have higher spreads but their P&L is more volatile because of higher risk to ATM vol changes) Figure 2) What is optimal hedging frequency for each maturity Translate into approximations of optimal bands for price and delta triggers Naturally, results are sensitive to assumed price dynamics Under SV with jumps: lower Sharp ratio and less frequent hedging 1.0 1.3 1.6 Optimal Sharpe ratio Diffusion Stochastic volatility with jumps 0.4 0.7 1m 4m 7m 10m 13m 16m 19m 22m 25m 28m 31m 34m 37m Option maturity in months 4 6 8 10 12 Optimal hedging frequency in days Diffusion Stochastic volatility with jumps 0 2 4 1m 4m 7m 10m 13m 16m 19m 22m 25m 28m 31m 34m 37m Option maturity in months 50
  • 51. Last topic: why the beta stochastic vol model with jumps is better than its alternatives (for stock indices) The most important feature for dynamic hedging model: 1) Ability to produce different volatility regimes as observed in the market and to imply empirically consistent delta Recall definition of volatility skew-beta: change in term structure of ATM volatility, σATM(T), predicted by price return times SKEW(T) We saw that vol skew-beta is very important to account for correct P&L arising from change in BSM implied vols Skew-consistent SV and LV models imply skew-beta of 2 Empirical vol skew-beta: S&P 500 ≈ 1.5; STOXX50 ≈ 1.8; Nikkei≈ 0.5 1.00 1.50 2.00 2.50 Vol Skew-Beta for S&P500 SVJ Skew-Beta with empirical beta 0.00 0.50 1m 3m 5m 7m 9m 11m 13m 15m 17m 19m 21m 23m T in months SVJ Skew-Beta with empirical beta Sticky local with Min-var delta Empirical bounds 1.00 1.50 2.00 2.50 Vol Skew-Beta for STOXX 50 SVJ Skew-Beta with empirical beta 0.00 0.50 1m 3m 5m 7m 9m 11m 13m 15m 17m 19m 21m 23m T in months SVJ Skew-Beta with empirical beta Sticky local with Min-var delta Empirical bounds 1.00 1.50 2.00 2.50 Vol Skew-Beta for NIKKEI SVJ Skew-Beta with empirical beta Sticky local with Min-var delta Empirical bounds 0.00 0.50 1m 3m 5m 7m 9m 11m 13m 15m 17m 19m 21m 23m T in months 51
  • 52. Why the beta SV with jumps is better than its alterna- tives Extra arguments to look at apart from implied volatility skew-beta 2) Fit to empirical distribution of implied and realized volatilities 3) Interpretation of model parameters in terms of impact on model implied BSM vols 4) P&L explain for delta-hedging strategies of vanilla options in terms of implied and realized model parameters 5) Stability of model parameters Calibration to vanilla options is not a problem in practical applications - it is easy to achieve by introducing a (small) local vol part Calibration problem is solved by Dupire (1994) for diffusions, Andersen- Andreasen (2000) for jump-diffusions, Lipton (2002) for SV with jumps 52
  • 53. I. Non-parametric local volatility model - textbook im- plementation of Dupire local volatility using discrete set of option prices and interpolation It is a good competitor to start my comparison because it fails on all counts As for interpretation and stability of model parameters - see quiz on the next slide 53
  • 54. Interpretation and stability of non-parametric LV Quiz: one of two figures below is [A] local vol surface fitted to discrete prices of S&P500 index options [B] Eckert IV map projection of a ski mountain where I was skiing last winter Which is which ? The same conclusion is for any SV and LV model implemented naively using direct calibration to market prices and mean-variance hedging: 1-2) Wrong hedges and empirical inconsistency 3-5) Uninterpretable and unstable model parameters 54
  • 55. II. Industry-standard alternative (in equity derivatives) Implied volatility@strike-into-density@price approach (my terminology) Conceptually: σimpl(K; T) → Pimpl(S(T) = K) (7) where→ is Dupire LV formula in terms of implied vols at strike K&mat T Figure 1A) Given parametric form for implied vols σimpl(K; T) Figure 1B) Given backbone function fbackbone(δS; K, T) to map price changes δS into changes in vols δσimpl(K; T) according to specified regime Figure 2) → in Eq(7) serves as interpolator from implied vols in strike space to implied densities in price space Figure 3) LV model projects densities to option prices in ”model-independent” way using MC or PDE methods 20% 30% 40% 50% ImpliedVolatility Implied Volatility (S0=1.00) Implied Volatility (S1=0.95) Change in IV from backbone function 0% 10% 20% 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0 1.1 1.2 ImpliedVolatility Strike 0.75% 1.50% 2.25% Density Implied Density from LV mapping (S0=1.00) Implied Density from LV mapping (S1=0.95) Change in Density from LV mapping -0.75% 0.00% 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0 1.1 1.2 Density Spot 0.10 0.20 0.30 0.40 0.50 PV PV Risk-Reversal 95-105% (S0) PV Risk-Reversal 95-105% (S1) Change in PV Risk-Reversal 95-105% -0.20 -0.10 0.00 0.10 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0 1.1 1.2 Spot 55
  • 56. 1) Hedging performance for local vol approach are pri- mary driven by parametric form for implied vols σimpl(K; T) and empirical backbone function 2) No consistency with empirical distribution of implied and realized vol 3) & 4) Model interpretation and P&L explain are possible only in terms of parameters of functional form for implied volatility Key drawback of implied volatility-into-density approach: [i] For computation of delta it requires a re-calibration of local vol and re-valuation for any change in market data [ii] Lacks vol-of-vol so it is inconsistent for hedging of path-dependent options sensitive to forward vols and skews 56
  • 57. Alternatives for local vol or σimpl(K; T) → Pimpl(S(T) = K) approach do not produce improvements Instead of LV to map implied vol into price density, it is also customary to use SV or LSV models as interpolators with extra degree of freedom Hereby hodel choice is typically motivated by availability of a ”closed- form” solution, not empirical consistency! Figure: SV and LSV models are not applied for hedging as dynamic models since their model delta is wrong - with and without minimum variance hedge - but through re-calibration to empirical backbone 1.5% 2.5% 3.5% Change in implied vol, S1-S0=-0.05 SV model delta SV with Min Var Hedge Empirical backbone -1.5% -0.5% 0.5% 0.70 0.80 0.90 1.00 1.10 1.20 Strike 0.40 0.60 0.80 1.00Delta for 1y call option on S&P500 SV model 0.00 0.20 0.40 0.70 0.80 0.90 1.00 1.10 1.20 Strike SV with Min Var hedge Sticky-Strike BSM delta SV re-calibrated to empirical backbone To conclude I use a quote from Richard P. Feynman: It doesn’t matter how beautiful your theory is, it doesn’t matter how smart you are. If it doesn’t agree with experiment, it’s wrong! 57
  • 58. III. Arguments in favor of Beta SVJ model: 1) the model has ability to fit empirical vol skew-beta and produce correct option delta without re-calibration Figure: delta from SVJ model fits empirical backbone 0.40 0.60 0.80 1.00 Delta for 1y call option on S&P500 SV model 0.00 0.20 0.40 0.70 0.80 0.90 1.00 1.10 1.20Strike SV with Min Var hedge SV re-calibrated to Market backbone SVJ (without re-calibration) 2) Consistent with the empirical distributions of implied and realized volatilities, which are very close to log-normal 3) It has clear intuition behind the key model parameters: Volatility beta is sensitivity to changes in short-term ATM vol Residual vol-of-vol is volatility of idiosyncratic changes in ATM vol 4) P&L explain is possible in terms of implied and realized quantities of key model parameter - vol beta 5) Stability and calibration - next slide 58
  • 59. Calibration of beta SV model is based on econometric and implied approaches without large-scale non-linear and non-intuitive calibrations 1) Parameters of SV part are estimated from time series 2) Jump/risk-aversion params are fitted to empirical vol skew-beta Params in 1) & 2) are updated only following changes in volatility regime 3) Small mis-calibrations of the SV part and jumps are corrected using local vol (LV) part Contribution to skew from LV part is kept small (no more than 10-15%) Local vol part is re-calibrated on the fly to reproduce small variations in some parts of implied vol surface, which are caused by temporary supply- demand factors specific to that part It is also robust to compute bucketed vega risk in this way In practical terms: 1) Local volatility part accounts for the noise from idiosyncratic changes in implied volatility surface 2) Stochastic volatility and jumps serve as time- and space-homogeneou factors for the shape of the implied volatility surface 59
  • 60. More details on calibration of beta SV model (technical part omitted during the talk) 1) Parameters of SV part are calibrated using maximum likelihood meth- ods from time series of 1m implied ATM volatility (or the VIX) [i] mean-reversion κ is estimated over longer-period, at least 5 years, - better to keep it constant at 3.00 [ii] vol beta β and residual vol-vol ε are estimated over shorter periods, 1y, - typically β ≈ −1.00 and ε ∈ [0.60, 1.00] 2) Negative jump in return η is fitted using Merton jump model to put options with maturity of 6 months and [80% − 100%] OTM strikes - typically η = −30% 3) Given 1) and 2): 3A) jump intensity λ is calibrated to fit the empirical sensitivity of implied volatility changes to price changes, aka volatility skew-beta, - typically λ ∈ [0.03, 0.2] Given all above: 3B) initial vol V (0) and mean vol θ calibrated to fit the current term structure of ATM vols Parameters in 1), 2) 3A) (relatively uniform for major stock indices) are updated infrequently 4) Local vol part is added to fit daily variations in implied vol surface 60
  • 61. For risk-neutral pricing, distribution of jumps does not matter - jumps are only needed to fit skew premium Recall illustration of emergence of Q- skew using Bakshi-Kapadia-Madan formula and Merton jump model: [i] Under P, jumps are symmetric with mean of 0% and volatility of 4% [ii] The risk-neutral mean jump is −5% with zero volatility 4% 6% 8% 10% Frequency Frequency of S&P500 daily returns Empirical Frequency Physical Merton under P Risk-Neutral 0% 2% 4% -9% -7% -5% -4% -2% 0% 2% 4% 6% 7% Frequency Daily return Risk-Neutral Merton under Q Yet, jumps are needed to fit market prices & compute correct deltas Also jumps are important to fit market prices of options on realized and implied volatilities (VIX) - see my presentations at GD in 2011 & 2012 Practical explanation for excessive risk-neutral skew premium: 1) Risk-averse investors always ready to over-pay for insurance ir- respectively of price changes 2) As part of index correlation skew premium, when holders of stock portfolios buy index puts for (macro) protection To make things robust, I assume constant jumps with simple calibration 61
  • 62. How to explain the difference between implied and realized dynamics using preference theory For retail option buyer - option value is derived from his preference/utility for specific payoffs in certain market scenarios For institutional option seller - option value is derived from: [i] Expected hedging costs [ii] Smooth stream of fees and P&L [iii] Premium for suffering losses in bad market conditions As a result: 1) Option prices in the market are set by demand-supply equilibrium between sellers and buyers 2) Risk-aversion parameters is a degree of demand-supply imbal- ance 3) Implied and realized vols and, in particular, skews are different 62
  • 63. To conclude: we can think of jumps as a mea- sure of risk-aversion for pricing kernel! Recently, interesting research is made and also presented at Global Deriva- tives on how to imply the ”expected-implied” physical distribution from options market prices and specified risk-aversion Stephen Ross:The Recovery Theorem, GD2012, Journal of Finance 2014 Peter Carr: Can we recover?, Global Derivatives 2013 Computation of ”empirical” delta and calibration of excessive skew are related concepts: 1) Compute option delta under ”expected-implied” physical distri- bution using empirical vol beta 2) Fit level of risk-aversion to excessive skew premium observed in market prices of index options These concepts and volatility skew-beta are related to the interplay be- tween the implied and realized risk premiums: [i] high implied / positive realized risk premiums - sticky strike vol regime [ii] low implied / negative realized risk premiums - sticky local vol regime To be continued at next year Global Derivatives conference... 63
  • 64. Summary 1) Dynamics of implied and real- ized vols are log-normal 2) Implied vol beta significantly overestimates realized beta 3) Vol skew-beta is important for correct P&L - any dynamic hedging model should fit empirical skew-beta Risk-Aversion/Jumps parameter is added to fit empirical skew-beta SVJ fits empirical skew-beta≈ 1.5, unlike Minimum Var delta≈ 2.0 4) Beta SVJ model applied for delta-hedging risk-reversal is tool to produce P&L from spread be- tween implied and realized skews Log-normal beta SVJ model: ⊗Is consistent with the empirical dynamics of ATM volatility ⊗Produces correct option deltas ⊗Can significantly improve Shar- pe ratios for delta-hedging P&Ls 3% 4% 5% 6% 7% Frequency Empirical frequency of normalized logarithm of the VIX Empirical Standard Normal 0% 1% 2% 3% -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 Frequency Log-VIX -0.5 0.0 Feb-07 Sep-07 Apr-08 Nov-08 Jun-09 Jan-10 Aug-10 Mar-11 Oct-11 May-12 Dec-12 Jul-13 Implied Volatility Beta Realized Volatility Beta -2.0 -1.5 -1.0 1.00 1.50 2.00 2.50 Vol Skew-Beta for S&P500 SVJ Skew-Beta with empirical beta 0.00 0.50 1m 3m 5m 7m 9m 11m 13m 15m 17m 19m 21m 23m T in months SVJ Skew-Beta with empirical beta Sticky local with Min-var delta Empirical bounds P&L = 2050*Beta + 2490 R² = 49% 0 1500 3000 P&L Risk-Reversal P&L vs Realized Vol Beta -1500 0 -2.0 -1.5 -1.0 -0.5 P&L Realized Volatility Beta 64
  • 65. Disclaimer The views represented herein are the author own views and do not neces- sarily represent the views of Bank of America Merrill Lynch or its affiliates 65
  • 66. References Andersen, L., Andreasen, J., (2000), “Jump-Diffusion Processes - Volatility Smile Fitting and Numerical Methods for Option Pricing ,” Review of Derivatives Research 4, 231-262 Bakshi, G., Kapadia, N., Madan, D., (2003), “Stock return characteristics, skew laws, and the differential pricing of individual equity options,” Review of Financial Studies 16 (1), 101-143 Bergomi, L., (2009), “Smile dynamics 4,” Risk, December, 94-100 Bergomi,L.,Guyon,J.,(2012),“Stochastic volatility’s orderly smiles,”Risk,May,117-123 Christoffersen, P., Jacobs, K., Mimouni, K., (2010), “Models for S&P 500 Dynam- ics: Evidence from Realized Volatility, Daily Returns and Options Prices,” Review of Financial Studies 23(8), 3141-3189 Derman, E., (1999), “Volatility Regimes,” Risk, April, 55-59 Dupire, B. (1994), “Pricing with a smile”, Risk, July, 18-20 Karasinski, P., Sepp, A., (2012), “Beta stochastic volatility model,” Risk, October, 67-73 Lewis, A., (2000), “Option valuation under stochastic volatility,” Finance Press, New- port Beach, California Lipton, A., (2002). “The vol smile problem”, Risk, February, 81-85 Ross, S., (2014). “The Recovery Theorem”, Journal of Finance, forthcoming Sepp, A., (2011), “Efficient Numerical PDE Methods to Solve Calibration and Pricing Problems in Local Stochastic Volatility Models”, Global Derivatives conference in Paris Sepp, A., (2012), “Achieving Consistent Modeling Of VIX and Equities Derivatives”, Global Derivatives conference in Barcelona Sepp, A., (2013), “Consistently Modeling Joint Dynamics of Volatility and Underlying To Enable Effective Hedging”, Global Derivatives conference in Amsterdam Sepp, A., (2013), “When You Hedge Discretely: Optimization of Sharpe Ratio for Delta-Hedging Strategy under Discrete Hedging and Transaction Costs,” The Journal of Investment Strategies 3(1), 19-59 Sepp, A., (2014), “Empirical Calibration and Minimum-Variance Delta Under Log- Normal Stochastic Volatility Dynamics,” Working paper, http://ssrn.com/abstract=2387845 Sepp, A., (2014), “Log-Normal Stochastic Volatility Model: Pricing of Vanilla Options and Econometric Estimation,” Working paper, http://ssrn.com/abstract=2522425 66