SlideShare une entreprise Scribd logo
1  sur  15
Télécharger pour lire hors ligne
JOURNAL OF
                                                                            Development
                            Journal of Development Economics                ECONOMICS
ELSEVIER                         Vol. 48 (1995) 135-149




Debt relief, growth and price stability in Mexico
                      Beatriz Armendfiriz de Aghion a,*,
                      Patricia Armendfiriz de Hinestrosa b
           a   The London School of Economics, Houghton Street, London WC2A 2AE, UK
                        b Comisi6n Nacional Bancaria, Mexico City, Mexico
                         Received 15 June 1993; revised 15 September 1994



Abstract

   Inspired by the negotiation of the foreign debt of Mexico in 1989 this paper provides a
framework to show that, prior to debt relief, an LDC government which is indebted both
domestically and externally has an additional incentive not to default on its external
obligations. However, repayment of the external debt is shown to involve a delicate tradeoff
between growth and inflation: on the one hand the government increases its ability to keep
domestic interest rates relatively low thereby promoting investment and growth; on the
other hand the government worsens the budget-deficit problem thereby introducing addi-
tional inflationary pressures. The way to improve this tradeoff is by negotiating a debt relief
operation on the foreign debt.

JEL classification: F34; Oll; O16

Keywords: Debt-relief; Risk-premium; Inflation; Stabilization; Growth



1. Introduction

   In April 1989 Mexico successfully negotiated a debt-relief package with its
foreign creditors, with an immediate impact on domestic interest rates which fell
by approximately 35 percentage points. In turn, such a sharp fall in interest rates
had an undeniable positive effect on growth, and it reduced the size of the
secondary deficit thereby inducing price stability.


  * Corresponding author.

0304-3878/95/$09.50 © 1995 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved
SSD1 0304-3878(95)00032-1
B. Armend6riz de Aghion, P. Armend6riz de Hinestrosa/Journal of Development Economics 48
136                                     (1995) 135-149

   Possibly because Mexico was the first beneficiary in a long list of less
developed countries (LDCs) qualifying for debt relief under the so-called Brady
plan, 1 such positive effects have been widely acknowledged by the press,
government officials and economists alike (see, notably, Van Wijnbergen (1991)
and Ortiz (1991)). To most observers, the positive effects of debt relief have two
distinct explanations: one is the debt-overhang explanation - which had already
been pointed out long before the Mexican debt-relief operation, notably by
Krugman (1988), 2 and the other is the reduction-of-uncertainty explanation -
evidenced by the sudden fall in domestic interest rates. This distinction has
prompted a number of empirical studies (see, notably Claessens et al., 1994)
suggesting that the latter explanation had indeed been underestimated.
   This paper can be viewed as a first attempt at formalizing the reduction-of-un-
certainty explanation. More precisely, using a signalling argument ~t la Spence
(1973) we show that an L D C government which is indebted both externally and
domestically has an additional incentive not to default on its external obligations.
However, repayment of the external debt is shown to involve a delicate tradeoff
between growth and inflation: on the one hand, the government increases its
ability to keep domestic interest rates relatively low thereby promoting investment
and growth; on the other hand the government worsens the budget-deficit problem
thereby introducing additional inflationary pressures. A way to improve this
tradeoff is by negotiating a debt relief operation on the external debt.
   Previous analytical work on growth and stabilization in the LDCs has failed to
establish an explicit link between the external and the domestic debt. 3 One
notable exception is Calvo (1988). In his model, a default on the external debt by
an LDC government is viewed as a transfer of resources from foreign creditors to
domestic creditors. Domestic creditors then expect to be reimbursed with a higher
probability and thus require a lower premium to hold domestic government debt.
However, Calvo's (1988) model remains unsatisfactory in one important respect: it
does not explain why the Mexican government, like several other LDC govern-
ments after it, would seek a negotiated debt-relief settlement instead of opting for
a more drastic foreign debt reduction as triggered by a (unilateral) default.
   In this paper we argue that the main reason why Calvo's (1988) predictions are



   1 This plan was launched in March 1989 by the US Treasury Secretary Nicholas Brady. It calls for a
reduction of the external debt of middle-income countries through the use of international resources for
'enhancement' collateral on the replacement of debt instruments. (See Van Wijnbergen, 1991.)
   2 This explanation is based on the following (incentive) argument: by being granted debt relief an
LDC government has an incentive to improve its economic performance since it knows that any
additional benefit (from an improved performance) will no longer accrue (entirely) to the creditors but
to the country itself.
   3 What we do find, however, is a growing number of descriptive contributions suggesting that debt
relief could help to enhance credibility in the stabilization program. (See, for example, Dornbusch
(1988), Ortiz (1991), and Van Wijnbergen (1991) for the particular case of Mexico).
B. Armend6riz de Aghion, P. Armend~riz de Hinestrosa /Journal of Development Economics 48
                                        (1995) 135-149                                       137


Table 1
Ex-ante and ex-post real interest rates and secondary deficit in Mexico (1985-1990)
                       1985          1986           1987         1988       1989       1990
Ex-ante real a            16.55         20.90        18.77       24.10      n/a        n/a
Ex-post real b          -42.50        -71.14         52.00       44.07       14.87       16.23
Secondary deficit          0.8           2.4        - 1.8         3.5         1.7       - 1.8
(% GDP) c

a Ex-ante rates: Yearly average rates of 3-month CETES less expected inflation for the year. Source:
Rojas-Su~rez (1992).
b Ex-post interest rates of yearly average CETES. Source: Banamex.
c Source: Export-Import Bank of Japan Review (1991).


potentially misleading is because debt relief operations are viewed as a purely
resource-saving operation. What we show on the contrary is that foreign debt
reduction through a (unilateral) default should be dominated by negotiated debt
relief operations in lending support to an LDC government's efforts to bring the
economy to a high growth-low inflation equilibrium.
   The structure the paper is as follows: In Section 2 we motivate our analysis by
providing a brief account of the 1989 debt reduction agreement between Mexico
and its foreign creditors. We then introduce the basic (signalling) framework in
Section 3, and we extend the model in Section 4 to account for the potential
benefits of debt relief operations on growth and stabilization. Finally, we spell out
some concluding remarks in Section 5.



2. Mexico before and after debt relief

   In December 1987 a harsh (heterodox) stabilization programme was started in
Mexico. The programme was introduced by a team of Mexican officials with an
outstanding background in economics. 4 Yet, uncertainty about whether stabiliza-
tion was going to last kept real interest rates high. As we show in Table 1 such
(ex-ante) rates increased from 18.77 in 1987 to 24.10 in 1988. This had a drastic
impact on the secondary deficit which in 1988 was at a five-year high reaching 3.5
percent of GDP.
   In the midst of stabilization and under the Brady plan, 5 in April 1989, Mexico
negotiated a debt relief package with its external creditors. In a manner that could
accommodate all parties involved with the plan's main principle, namely, that of
debt-service reduction, the external creditors of Mexico were given the choice
between the following three options: (a) exchange their original claims against


   4 See Aspe (1993) for a detailed account of the stabilization program itself.
   5 See footnote 1 above
B. Armend6riz de Aghion, P. Armend6riz de Hinestrosa // Journal of Development Economics 48
138                                     (1995) 135-149

Table 2
Current account savings implied by debt relief in Mexico (millions of dollars)
                                         1990         1991        1992         1993        1994
Debt reduction(options(a) and ( b ) )    2252.2       1501.0      1501.0       1501.0      1501.0
New money (option(c))                     756.0        648.0       648.0         0.0         0.0

Source: Data collected by one of the authors from the Office of the Undersecretary of Finance,
Mexico.



new bonds at a floating LIBOR rate but with principal reduced by 35 percent of
original face value; (b) exchange their original claims against new bonds paying a
fixed (6.25 percent) interest rate; and (c) keep their original claims but provide
new money equivalent to 25 percent of the amount brought under this option.
Nearly half the creditors favoured the first option, over one third the second, and a
relatively small fraction the third. 6 This debt-relief operation amounted to approx-
imately 30 percent of the Mexican foreign debt (or some $13 billion of the $50
billion included in the negotiations). 7 In terms of resource transfers, which
represented some 5.5 percent of annual GDP in 1982-1988, the debt relief
operation was estimated to have reduced such transfers approximately to 2.4
percent for the period 1989-1992 (Ortiz, 1991). Table 2 replicates the resource
transfers savings implied by debt relief as estimated by Mexican officials.
   The amount of debt relief granted to Mexico was rather low, particularly when
one compares it to historical standards. 8 To most observers, however, the main
impact of debt relief was on interest rates (see, notably Claessens et al. (1994)).
When the debt reduction agreement was announced in April 1989 interest rates
collapsed. T-bills, in particular fell by 14 to 19 percentage points. 9 When the
agreement was signed in early 1990 they again started a steady downward trend.
Overall, by December 1990 interest rates were around 30 percentage points below
when compared to the period prior to the agreement. With regards to real rates,




   6 The precise figures are: 46.7% of the creditors opted for (a), 38.2% for (b) and 13.1% for (c). For
a more detailed descriptionsee, Van Wijnbergen(1991).
   7 Not all the outstandingforeign obligationsof Mexico were subjectto negotiationunder the Brady
Plan. Of the $61.3 billion outstanding,$7.3 billion was interbank debt involving Mexican banks, and
$5.1 billion had been contracted under 'special circumstances'.This left a total of $48.9 billion.
   8 Specially when one compares it to the 70% debt reduction Mexico obtained from its foreign
creditors in the Suarez-Lamont agreement back in 1942. (See Armendfirizde Aghion, 1993.) The
recent debt relief package is also modest when compared to what some other countrieshave obtainedin
the past. Germany,for example obtainedas much as 70% debt relief in the Londonagreementof 1953,
Indonesia52% in the late 1960s (Farber, 1990), and Brazil some 50 to 70% in 1943 (Eichengreenand
Portes, 1989).
   9 Rates of other instrumentslike bank acceptances fell by 8 percentage points (Banamex).
B. Armend6riz de Aghion, P. Armenddtriz de Hinestrosa /Journal of Development Economics 48
                                        (1995) 135-149                                      139

         45                                                                      DealAgreed
         40
         35     ~.
                        .   .   .   .   .   .




                                                              ~       '~
         3O                                                 ?~         .

     .= 25            ".                           /' ..               -           .~..                ! Ex-post !
     2
                                                                                                      -




     g. 2o                                                                                                  Ex-ante
         15
                                                                            ,,
         10


          0     I       t                       I       I         I          I   I    I       I   I   I

              Mar-e8 Sep-88 Mar-e9 Sep-89 Mar-90 Sep-90
                  Jun-88 Dec-88 Jun-89 Dec-89 Jun-90 Dec-90
                          Source: Rojas-Suarez (1992)
               Fig. 1. Ex-ante and ex-post real interest rate.Source: Rojas-Sufirez(1992).



Fig. 1 shows the b e h a v i o u r of both ex-ante and ex-post real interest rates. These
fell by 35 percentage points following the a n n o u n c e m e n t of the agreement and
reassumed a steady d o w n w a r d trend after the agreement was signed.
    O n the other hand the (post debt-relief) growth rate increased to approximately
3.3 percent in 1989 and then to 4.4 percent in 1990 w h e n it reached a ten-year
record (see Table 3). A l t h o u g h other considerations can potentially account for
such a high rate of growth, 10 the impact of debt relief is undeniable. Both because
relatively lower transfer of resources 11 and, more importantly, because it implied
substantially lower interest rates 12. Moreover, the stabilization p r o g r a m m e itself
benefited from the lower interest rates as these implied a lower operational
deficit, t3 The gains in stabilization were remarkable: as s h o w n in Table 3 the
iJlflation rate fell from 114.2 percent in 1988 to 20 percent in 1989, and price
volatility was brought d o w n from 2.5 in 1988 to 1.4 in 1989.




  10 Notably progress on the stabilization front and continuation of structural reform.
  ii Particularly because Mexico did not default on its external debt throughout the eight-year period
prior to debt relief.
  12 Van Wijnbergen (1991) has estimated Mexico's prospective growth rate following debt relief to
have increased over the 1990-1994 period by approximately 2 percentage points annually. Of this
amount, he argues, one half comes from the direct effect of resource transfer alleviation, and the other
half comes from the 'indirect' effects, and in particular from the lower interest rate and higher
investment.
  13 As a matter of fact, the operational component of the government deficit improved from a deficit
of 3.5 percentage points in 1988 to a surplus of 1.8 percent in 1990 (See Table 1).
B. Armenddriz de Aghion, P. Armenddriz de Hinestrosa /Journal of Development Economics 48
140                                      (1995) 135-149

Table 3
GDP growth and inflation in Mexico (1985-1990)
                           1985        1986          1987         1988         1989         1990
GDP growth (real)           2.6         -3.8           1.9          1.2         3.3          4.4
Inflation a                57.8          86.2        131.8        114.2        20.0         26.7
Price volatility b          3.9           5.9          8.3          2.5         1.4          1.9

a CPI. Accumulated monthly inflation rate, Jan-Dec of each year.
b Yearly average percent variation in CPI from month to month.
Source: Banco de Mexico


   The above stylized facts on the Mexican debt-relief operation and its impact on
growth and price stability motivate the following model.


3. The model

   Consider a two-period economy, T = 1,2, with identical consumers and a
government. Each (representative) consumer at period T = 1 has an initial endow-
ment, y, expressed in units of output, which he can either consume or invest.
There are two investment opportunities: in real assets, k, which yield 1 + r units
of output in period 2, where r denotes the real interest rate; or in domestic
government bonds, b, which yield (1 + i)(1 - O(b))/1 + 7re units of output in
period 2. i denotes the nominal interest rate, 7r e is expected inflation, and O(b)
represents a portion of domestic government debt which is expected to be
repudiated, x4 Arbitrage between real assets and government bonds requires that
the rate of return on both these assets be equalized, that is, 15
                  (l+i)(1-O(b))
       l+r=               l+~r ~                                                                   (1)

which, for simplicity can be approximated as follows:
       i(b)=r+Tr~+O(b),                 i'(b)>O,O'(b)>O.                                           (2)
   Eq. (2) captures the following idea: bond financing can potentially increase the
probability of default, O(b). This in turn raises the nominal interest rate, i(b), and
thus crowds out investment (in the first period).


  14 This possibility cannot be ruled out when, in particular, a country is unable to raise the required
tax revenue (see, for example, Ize and Ortiz (1987)), a n d / o r when repaying the debt by creating
money involves (high) inflation costs. Historically, defaults on domestic debt have been observed in,
for example, the stabilization programs in Argentina under President Menem in 1989, and in Brazil
under President Collor in 1989 (see Cardoso and Helwege, 1992).
  15 Eq. (1) is an amended version of the Fisher equation to account for the possibility that the
government defaults on its domestic debt.
B. Armend6riz de Aghion, P. Armend~riz de Hinestrosa /Journal of Development Economics 48
                                        (1995) 135-149                                      141

   T h e r e is no i n v e s t m e n t in the s e c o n d period, that is, w e suppose that at period 2
returns f r o m p r e v i o u s period i n v e s t m e n t s are realized and that these are c o n s u m e d .
   T h e g o v e r n m e n t at period 1, on the other hand, has the f o l l o w i n g (intertem-
poral) b u d g e t constraint:
        g(l + i(b)) + d-t=              A m + Ab,                                                         (3)
w h e r e g(1 + i(b)) is (per capita) g o v e r n m e n t spending (including current spend-
ing on d o m e s t i c debt services), d is (per capita) g o v e r n m e n t debt o w e d to external
creditors, and t is the e x p e c t e d (per capita) tax revenue f r o m c o n s u m e r s ' invest-
m e n t returns in real assets. 16 The R H S o f (3) shows the w a y the g o v e r n m e n t
finances its deficit, n a m e l y through a c o m b i n a t i o n o f m o n e y creation, Am, and
through the issue o f n e w bonds, Ab. Both A m and Ab are expressed in per capita
terms. 17 Specifically, (2) says that current expenditures, g(1 + ( i ( b ) ) ) + d, are
financed through a c o m b i n a t i o n o f m o n e y creation and bonds; and that future
expenditures, e.g., d o m e s t i c debt r e p a y m e n t s in period 2, are financed through the
s e c o n d - p e r i o d taxation o f real assets. 18 W e k n o w by (2) that bond f i n a n c i n g
raises the interest rate. M o n e y financing, on the other hand, raises the (expected)
inflation rate:
                 Am       m2 - m I         g ( l + i( b ) ) + d - te - b
        7r e = - - -                                                                                      (4)
                m1            ml                          ml

      W e suppose a s y m m e t r i c information on the tax revenues. Specifically, w e
suppose t is private information. That is, the g o v e r n m e n t is assumed to be better
i n f o r m e d than the c o n s u m e r s about the size of the tax revenue, t, e x p e c t e d to be
raised in period 2. 19 M o r e o v e r , w e will consider the case where, due to the a b o v e
informational a s y m m e t r y , the g o v e r n m e n t ' s external-debt r e p a y m e n t m a y c o n v e y


  16 TO make the model as simple as possible we suppose taxation is non-distortionary.
  17 Notice that this government cannot finance the deficit by borrowing in the international capital
markets. This captures well the reality of the Latin American countries in the 1980s.
  18 In particular, we are making the simplifying assumption that the external debt is to be
repaid/defaulted upon before the domestic debt. To make the model more realistic we could have
referred to external debt service obligations instead, but this would only have complicated the notation
without actually altering our main results in any significant manner. It is not difficult for anyone
familiar with the LDC debt crisis to see how such an assumption can be justified. Typically, LDCs
throughout the 1980s could no longer borrow abroad to finance government expenditures, and
whenever a decision had to be taken regarding the external debt inherited from the past, governments
already had an outstanding domestic debt which they had issued at a floating interest rate and/or
would systematically issue new bonds to finance government expenditures (including external debt
services). In either case a domestic debt (in some instances very large, indeed) would be outstanding
after any decision had been taken regarding the external debt.
  19 This assumption is not difficult to justify. In most LDCs (and in industrialized countries too!) tax
revenues may be ex-post public information, but ex-ante government officials surely have a better
estimate. The important point to note thus is that it is asymmetric information on the expected (not the
actual) size of the deficit the main assumption which is driving the paper's main results.
B. Armend[triz de Aghion, P. Armend~riz de Hinestrosa /Journal of Development Economics 48
 142                                      (1995) 135-149

information about the size of the tax revenue, and, in turn, about the size of the
deficit. That is, we explore the possibility of a separating equilibrium to exist. 20
In such an equilibrium, as described below, repayment of the external debt is
shown to involve a delicate tradeoff between growth and inflation: on the one
hand the government increases its ability to keep domestic interest rates relatively
low thereby promoting investment and growth; on the other hand the government
worsens the budget-deficit problem thereby introducing additional inflationary
pressures. Specifically we suppose the government's objective function is 21

        max{ k ( i( b ) )   -   c(,rre)}                                                            (5)
          b

        s.t. (3) and (4).

    In words: the government maximises investment returns of a representative
consumer, k(i(b)), net of (per capita) inflation costs, c(~e), subject to (3) and (4).
    The timing of the model is as set out in Fig. 2. 22
    We now proceed to solving the above signalling model. Instead of considering
all possible equilibria we will focus on a separating equilibrium. By separating
equilibrium we mean an equilibrium where the government's repayment strategy
fully reveals information about its type. I.e., if the government repays it will signal
itself as a t-type and if it defaults it will signal itself as a t-type. More formally,
we define a separating equilibrium as a triplet (p., ~,s), where /x denotes the
consumers' beliefs and ~ (resp. s) denotes the 7-government's (resp. t-
government's) repayment strategy, such that (a) /x is Bayes-consistent with (~, s)


                            T=I                                            T=2
              I                                     I                                      ,
                               t                                      t
                   F..xtetnal debt repayment                 Tax ~ u ~    oollcet¢~l and
                   decision and bond/money                   domestic debt repaid .
                    financing decision.
                                           Fig. 2. The timing.



  20 As a first approximation to see how this possibility could emerge, it may be useful to illustrate
some common perceptions: a government's debt-repayment policy is likely to signal compliance with
IMF conditionality, and, thus, consumers may expect that the government deficit will be relatively
small; and a government's non-repayment (or default) policy may signal non-compliance with IMF
conditionality, and thus, consumers may expect that the government deficit will be relatively large. We
show below that a separating equilibrium like the one just described, exists.
  21 Notice that, for simplicity, we are (implicitly) assuming that the consumers' discount factor is
sufficiently high (i.e. close to one) that consumers are perfectly happy to substitute consumption in
period 1 for consumption in period 2. One can easily verify that our results will carry over to the case
where the consumers' discount factor is less than one.
  22 See footnote 18 above.
B. Armend{triz de Aghion, P. Armend,~riz de Hinestrosa /Journal of Development Economics 48
                                        (1995) 135-149                                       143

such that ~ = repayment and s = default; and ~ is such that ~(repayment) = t and
/,(default) = t.
    Clearly, such an equilibrium will not always exist. In particular, both for
sufficiently large and for sufficiently small values of the parameter d a pooling
instead of separating equilibrium is obtained. The reason is straightforward:
suppose d is sufficiently large. Then, a default decision does not convey informa-
tion about the (expected) tax revenue to the consumers since both a }- and a
t-government default. 23 And similarly, when d is sufficiently small, a repayment
decision does not convey any information about the (expected) tax revenue either
since both a t- and a t-government systematically repay. 24 Let us now explore the
possibility of a separating equilibrium to exist (for intermediate values of d). More
formally, we shall consider first the case of a }-government and solve the model
by backward induction. Specifically, if the government repays consumers update
their beliefs and ask for a lower interest rate, ~r(b), to hold domestic government
debt; and by repaying the government in this case gets:


        mbax{k(gr(b) ) _             (g(l+tr(b))+d--t-b)}
                                 C                                                                           (6)
                                                 ml

   If, on the other hand, the government defaults consumers will update their
beliefs and ask for a higher interest rate, g0(b), to hold domestic government debt.
Thus, by defaulting the government gets


        n~x{k(~d(b))-c(g(l+~a(b))--t-b)},ml                                                                  (7)

where

                                -t-t- d
        i'd(b) - i'~(b)          m, - g                                                                      (8)

by substitution of (3) into (2). 25


  23 In this case consumers are unable to distinguish whether the government defaults because its
external debt is very large indeed or because the tax revenue is expected to be small.
  z4 In this case consumers are unable to distinguish whether the government repays because its
external debt is very small indeed or because the tax revenue is expected to be large.
  25 Specifically:

~(b) = r + H e + O(b)
        =:~~'d(b) -- i'r(b) = H2(b ) - /1"re(b)
           ~d(b) -- ~r(b) = [( g ( l + i'd(b)) --_t-- b ) / m 1] - [( g(1 + ~r(b)) + d - "t - b ) / m I ]
        =~ i'd(b ) - i'r(b) = [((~'-_t- d ) / m l ) / ( 1 -   g / m , ) ] = [ ( } - t - d ) / ( m , - g)].
B. Armend~riz de Aghion, P. Armend~riz de Hinestrosa /Journal o[ Development Economics 48
144                                     (1995) 135-149




                                                      ~/
                                                      IT(I IrOIb)
                                                         lb)

                                                                 J( Ir Ib)
                                                                 I(Irlb)
                                               Eo

                                                      I




                   Fig. 3. Repayment by a t-government in a separating equilibrium.


   A sufficient condition for a t-government to repay will thus be that (for all b):
                          (g(1 +'ir(b))+d--t-b             )
       k('i,( b ) ) - c
                                         m 1

                                ( g ( 1 + i'd(b)) -- t - - b )
           > k('id(b)) - c                                                                          (9)
                                               ml

   And the effects of repaying the external debt by a t-government when the
above condition is satisfied, e.g., for intermediate values of d, is depicted in Fig.
3.
   The i- and 7r-schedules in Fig. 3, respectively, show the relationship between
the nominal interest rate and the inflation rate as described by (2) and (4). Both
schedules are drawn for a given (optimally chosen) quantity of government bonds.
When a t-type government decides to repay, due to the signalling effect the
/-schedule shifts downwards; and due to the resource transfer effect the 7r-schedule
shifts to the right. 26 The shifting of both these schedules will therefore take us
from a point like E 0 to a point like E 1 in Fig. 3. That is, a repayment strategy
involves a relatively lower interest rate and a relatively higher inflation rate.
   Clearly, condition (9) will be violated for d sufficiently large. This is because a
repayment policy in this case involves a large 'resource-transfer effect' which is
not offset by a (positive) 'signalling effect'.
   We should note, however, that condition (9) is not sufficient for a separating
equilibrium to exist. We require something else: we need that, for the same value
of the parameters d, t, t, and g, a t-government decides to default. Again, to


  26 The relative magnitude of those shifts will depend both upon the sensitivity of the interest rate to
the government's external debt policy, and on the size of the external debt transfer.
B. Armend6riz de Aghion, P. Armend{triz de Hinestrosa /Journal of Development Economics 48
                                        (1995) 135-149                                      145


                              t                     fro Ib) ll(i Ib)

                                                      / I(IrIb)
                                             El     ~i(frlb)
                                                    0




                                                                       If
                     Fig. 4. Defaultby a t-governmentin a separatingequilibrium.


analyse how this possibility can arise we reason by backward induction: if a
t-government repays, consumers update their beliefs and ask for 7~(b) to hold
domestic government debt, and what the t-government gets is

           {                      (g(l+~r(b))+d-t-b)}
                                                                        ,                (10)
                                              ml

and if it defaults consumers will ask for 7d(b) and the t-government gets

      mbax{k(gd(b) ) _            (g(l+~d(b))-t-b)}                                      (11)
                                            ml

   A sufficient condition for a t-government to decide to default is that, for all b,

                          ( g ( 1 + ~d(b)) --t-- b)
                 -    c

                                      ml

                                  (g(l +'ir(b)) + d-t-b)
         > k('ir(b)) - c                             -                                   (12)
                                              ml

   The effects of a default by a t-government on interest rates and inflation are
shown in Fig. 4. Typically, such a government will experience a positive
resource-transfer effect and an adverse signalling effect; and both of these
combined will lead to a relatively lower inflation rate and a relatively higher
interest rate. That is, in terms of the diagram the post-default inflation and interest
rates will be at a point to the north-west of E 0 such as E 1.
   Clearly, condition (12) - and more generally the inequality (11) > (10), would
be violated for d sufficiently small because the (adverse) signalling effect will
offset the (positive) resource-saving effect. Therefore, it is only for intermediate
B. Armenddriz de Aghion, P. Armenddriz de Hinestrosa /Journal of Development Economics 48
146                                      (1995) 135-149

values of d that we can expect a separating equilibrium to exist; and a sufficient
condition is that both inequalities (9) and (12) are satisfied. Specifically, for a
separating equilibrium to exist the following is required:

              (g(1 + ~'d(b)) --t-- b)             (g(1    +~r(b))+d-t-b)
        --c                                  +c                               -
                           m1                                     ml

        >   k(~r(b)) - k(~d(b))                                                                     (13)
                 ( g + ~d(b) - ~' - b)            ( g ( 1 + ~r(b)) + d - - t - b )
                                            +c
                            ml                                    m1

which clearly holds only when the cost function is sufficiently convex. That is,
only in this case a t-government defaults - because inflation costs will otherwise
raise too quickly; and the t-government repays - because a relatively small
increase in the inflation cost will be offset by a relatively large reduction in the
interest rate. This result can now be summarized in the following:

Proposition 1. For d neither too large nor too small and for inflation costs
which are sufficiently convex, there exists a separating equilibrium where a
-t-government repays and a t-government defaults.

   Clearly, once signalling considerations are taken into account, by deciding to
repay the external debt an L D C government can potentially promote investment
and growth but at the expense of relatively high inflation; and by deciding to
default it can achieve a relatively low inflation rate but will retard growth. 27


4. Debt relief

   The idea that debt relief can potentially lend support to an LDC government's
efforts to promote growth with price stability has been around for some time
now. 28 Yet, never has the evidence been so striking as in the case of Mexico
where, as argued in Section 2, the debt relief operation was a crucial component of
the period of growth and price stability that followed. 29


  27 Note that one can easily show that the above tradeoff will arise in a more general signalling
framework which is beyond the scope of this paper. Suppose, for example, the external debt is
sufficiently small. Then, by repaying there is no positive signalling effect (i.e. this would be a pooling
equilibrium) but the transferring of resources abroad can potentially raise both inflation and interest
rates. We explore another pooling equilibrium situation below.
  28 See, notably, Krugman (1988) on debt relief and investment and Sachs (1987) on debt relief and
price stabilization in Bolivia.
  29 For more in support of this view, see Ortiz (199i).
B. Armend6riz de Aghion, P. Armend6riz de Hinestrosa /Journal of Development Economics 48
                                        (1995) 135-149                                     147


                                                   ff(i Ib) ff(i Ib)


                                                                I(EIb)




                                                                       ff
                                       Fig. 5. Debt relief.


   This section will therefore extend our basic set-up of Section 3 to account for
the Mexican debt relief experience. As illustrated in Fig. 5 the most likely effect of
debt relief is to eliminate residual uncertainty about the government deficit. In
other words, separating equilibria are likely to be eliminated because, by repaying
a sufficiently low level of external debt the government does not convey any
information about the (expected) tax revenue, and thus about the deficit. 30 Hence
the /-schedule remains unaltered. At the same time, due to a (positive) resource-
saving effect, the //-schedule shifts leftwards. The final equilibrium is at E 1
where both the interest rate and the inflation rate have fallen.
   Clearly, after debt relief the government will not default for the following
reason: if it defaults on a sufficiently small debt the (adverse) signalling effect will
come into play, thereby raising interest rates, and retarding investment and growth
(e.g., the /-schedule would shift upwards). And this may in turn explain why
creditors may be willing to grant debt relief in the first place! 3]



5. Concluding remarks

   LDCs have experienced debt crises before, yet never as in the 1980s have their
external debts interfered so evidently with efforts to bring inflation down and grow
out of recession. We have argued first that any resource-transfer saving involved
in an LDC defaulting on its external debt can potentially be offset by an adverse
signalling effect on that LDC's domestic debt market; and, second, that a


  30 Typically, this would be a pooling equilibrium.
  31 Note that debt relief in the above framework comes out naturally without the need of invoking
incentive-based arguments such as the (well-publicized) debt overhang idea (see Krugman, 1988).
B. Armenddriz de Aghion, P. Armend~riz de Hinestrosa /Journal of Development Economics 48
148                                     (1995) 135-149

(negotiated) debt-relief settlement is likely to dominate as a way for an LDC to
achieve higher rates of growth while maintaining price stability.
   Our framework could be easily extended in at least two potentially interesting
directions. Firstly, the model could incorporate considerations of exchange rate
expectations. Our conjecture is that this would essentially reinforce the case for a
negotiated debt-relief settlement: debt relief implies a lower transfer of (foreign-
currency) resources abroad, and it should thus reduce expectations of an exchange
rate depreciation. This in turn should further decrease the risk premium on
domestic (government) debt. Secondly, the model can easily accommodate incen-
tive-based arguments h la Krugman (1988), and thereby again further strengthen
our argument for (negotiated) debt relief.


6. Acknowledgments

   This research was started while the first author was a Research Associate at the
OECD Development Centre, Paris. She is particularly grateful to Helmut Reisen
for very useful conversations and insights. Both authors are grateful to Daron
Acemoglu, Patrick Bolton, Nicholas Stern, Tony Venables, participants of the
Development Economics seminar at the London School of Economics, and
especially to Philippe Aghion and an anonymous referee for very useful comments
on an earlier version. The usual disclaimer, of course, applies.


References

Armendfiriz de Aghion, Beatriz, 1993, El precio de los bonos, las razones deuda-exportaci6n, y las
    moratorias en el servicio de la deuda exterior de un pais: E1 caso de M6xico, El Trimestre
    Econ6mico, June.
Aspe, Pedro, 1993, Economic transformation: The Mexican way (The MIT Press, Cambridge, MA).
Banco de Mexico, Indicadores econ6micos, various issues.
Calvo, Guillermo, 1988, Servicing the public debt: The role of expectations, American Economic
    Review, Sep.
Cardoso, Eliana and Ann Helwege, 1992, Latin America's economy: Diversity, trends, and conflicts
    (MIT Press, Cambridge, MA).
Claessens, Stijn, Daniel Oks and Sweder van Wijnbergen, 1994, Interest rates, growth and external
    debt: The macroeconomic impact of Mexico's Brady deal, Discussion paper no. 904 (CEPR,
    London).
Dombusch, Rudiger, 1988, Mexico, Economic Policy, Oct.
Eichengreen, Barry and Richard Portes, 1989, Dealing with debt: The 1930s and the 1980s, Discussion
    paper no. 300 (CEPR, London) Feb.
Export-Import Bank of Japan (EXIM) Review, 1991, Mexico: Economic reform and development
    strategy, Special issue (Fall).
Farber, Mike, 1990, Renegotiating official debts, Finance and Development, Dec.
Ize, Allan and Guillermo Ortiz, 1987, Fiscal rigidities, public debt, and capital flight, IMF Staff Papers
    34, no.2, June.
B. Armend6riz de Aghion, P. Armend,~riz de Hinestrosa /Journal of Development Economics 48
                                         (1995) 135-149                                       149

Krugman, Paul, 1988, Financing vs. forgiving a debt overhang: Some analytical notes, Journal of
    Development Economics, Dec.
Ortiz, Guillermo, 1991, Mexico beyond the debt crisis: Toward sustainable growth with price stability,
    in: M. Bruno et al., eds., Lessons of economic stabilization and its aftermath (The MIT Press,
    Cambridge, MA).
Rojas-Su~irez, Liliana, 1992, An analysis of the linkages of macroeconomic policies in Mexico, in:
    Claudio Loser and Eliot Kalter, eds., Mexico: The strategy to achieve sustained economic growth,
    Occasional paper no. 99 (IMF, Washington, DC).
Sachs, Jeffrey, 1987, The Bolivian hyperinflation and stabilization, American Economic Review 77,
    no. 2, May.
Spence, Michael, 1973, Job market signalling, Quarterly Journal of Economics 87, 355-374.
Van Wijnbergen, Sweder, 1991, The Mexican debt deal, Economic Policy, April.

Contenu connexe

Tendances

2008 Q3: The Impact of the Global Financial and Economic Crisis on Botswana
2008  	Q3: The Impact of the Global Financial and Economic Crisis on Botswana2008  	Q3: The Impact of the Global Financial and Economic Crisis on Botswana
2008 Q3: The Impact of the Global Financial and Economic Crisis on Botswanaeconsultbw
 
Economic Concerns Slide Show 2 09
Economic Concerns Slide Show 2 09Economic Concerns Slide Show 2 09
Economic Concerns Slide Show 2 09mjdeschaine
 
STOCKTAKING OF THE G-20 RESPONSES TO THE GLOBAL BANKING CRISIS
STOCKTAKING OF THE G-20 RESPONSES TO THE GLOBAL BANKING CRISISSTOCKTAKING OF THE G-20 RESPONSES TO THE GLOBAL BANKING CRISIS
STOCKTAKING OF THE G-20 RESPONSES TO THE GLOBAL BANKING CRISISPeter Ho
 
To the Point - September 8, 2011
To the Point - September 8, 2011To the Point - September 8, 2011
To the Point - September 8, 2011Swedbank
 
Global Crisis Monitor June July 2009
Global Crisis Monitor   June July 2009Global Crisis Monitor   June July 2009
Global Crisis Monitor June July 2009Alvin Chua
 
Collapse of the US Financial System in 2008 v2
Collapse of the US Financial System in 2008 v2Collapse of the US Financial System in 2008 v2
Collapse of the US Financial System in 2008 v2Abdulaziz Alsuliman
 
Is debt relief efficient
Is debt relief efficientIs debt relief efficient
Is debt relief efficientitargeting
 
Aula 04 ingles instrumental - tradução e resolução de provas
Aula 04    ingles instrumental - tradução e resolução de provasAula 04    ingles instrumental - tradução e resolução de provas
Aula 04 ingles instrumental - tradução e resolução de provasNeon Online
 
Veripath Q4 2021 Investor Letter
Veripath Q4 2021 Investor LetterVeripath Q4 2021 Investor Letter
Veripath Q4 2021 Investor LetterVeripath Partners
 
Why the U.S. Treasury Began Auctioning Treasury Bill in 1929
Why the U.S. Treasury Began Auctioning Treasury Bill in 1929Why the U.S. Treasury Began Auctioning Treasury Bill in 1929
Why the U.S. Treasury Began Auctioning Treasury Bill in 1929Peter Ho
 
Eurozone Crisis: Strategies for Risk Mitigation
Eurozone Crisis: Strategies for Risk MitigationEurozone Crisis: Strategies for Risk Mitigation
Eurozone Crisis: Strategies for Risk MitigationHarry G. Broadman
 

Tendances (16)

2008 Q3: The Impact of the Global Financial and Economic Crisis on Botswana
2008  	Q3: The Impact of the Global Financial and Economic Crisis on Botswana2008  	Q3: The Impact of the Global Financial and Economic Crisis on Botswana
2008 Q3: The Impact of the Global Financial and Economic Crisis on Botswana
 
Economic Concerns Slide Show 2 09
Economic Concerns Slide Show 2 09Economic Concerns Slide Show 2 09
Economic Concerns Slide Show 2 09
 
STOCKTAKING OF THE G-20 RESPONSES TO THE GLOBAL BANKING CRISIS
STOCKTAKING OF THE G-20 RESPONSES TO THE GLOBAL BANKING CRISISSTOCKTAKING OF THE G-20 RESPONSES TO THE GLOBAL BANKING CRISIS
STOCKTAKING OF THE G-20 RESPONSES TO THE GLOBAL BANKING CRISIS
 
To the Point - September 8, 2011
To the Point - September 8, 2011To the Point - September 8, 2011
To the Point - September 8, 2011
 
Agcapita April 2010
Agcapita April 2010Agcapita April 2010
Agcapita April 2010
 
Siep
SiepSiep
Siep
 
Global Crisis Monitor June July 2009
Global Crisis Monitor   June July 2009Global Crisis Monitor   June July 2009
Global Crisis Monitor June July 2009
 
Mexico Financial Crisis / M. F. Campuzano Ochoa
Mexico Financial Crisis / M. F. Campuzano OchoaMexico Financial Crisis / M. F. Campuzano Ochoa
Mexico Financial Crisis / M. F. Campuzano Ochoa
 
Collapse of the US Financial System in 2008 v2
Collapse of the US Financial System in 2008 v2Collapse of the US Financial System in 2008 v2
Collapse of the US Financial System in 2008 v2
 
Is debt relief efficient
Is debt relief efficientIs debt relief efficient
Is debt relief efficient
 
Policy paper final
Policy paper finalPolicy paper final
Policy paper final
 
Aula 04 ingles instrumental - tradução e resolução de provas
Aula 04    ingles instrumental - tradução e resolução de provasAula 04    ingles instrumental - tradução e resolução de provas
Aula 04 ingles instrumental - tradução e resolução de provas
 
Veripath Q4 2021 Investor Letter
Veripath Q4 2021 Investor LetterVeripath Q4 2021 Investor Letter
Veripath Q4 2021 Investor Letter
 
Why the U.S. Treasury Began Auctioning Treasury Bill in 1929
Why the U.S. Treasury Began Auctioning Treasury Bill in 1929Why the U.S. Treasury Began Auctioning Treasury Bill in 1929
Why the U.S. Treasury Began Auctioning Treasury Bill in 1929
 
Eurozone Crisis: Strategies for Risk Mitigation
Eurozone Crisis: Strategies for Risk MitigationEurozone Crisis: Strategies for Risk Mitigation
Eurozone Crisis: Strategies for Risk Mitigation
 
George perendia
George perendiaGeorge perendia
George perendia
 

Similaire à Beatriz Armendariz

MACROECONOMICS-CH15
MACROECONOMICS-CH15MACROECONOMICS-CH15
MACROECONOMICS-CH15kkjjkevin03
 
Debt relief initiative for poor countries
Debt relief initiative for poor countriesDebt relief initiative for poor countries
Debt relief initiative for poor countriesitargeting
 
To the Point, 2010 January
To the Point, 2010 JanuaryTo the Point, 2010 January
To the Point, 2010 JanuarySwedbank
 
Subnational Debt Management in Brazil and Mexico: Fernando Blanco, Lead Econo...
Subnational Debt Management in Brazil and Mexico: Fernando Blanco, Lead Econo...Subnational Debt Management in Brazil and Mexico: Fernando Blanco, Lead Econo...
Subnational Debt Management in Brazil and Mexico: Fernando Blanco, Lead Econo...World Bank Publications
 
Debt overhang past and present
Debt overhang past and presentDebt overhang past and present
Debt overhang past and presentYusuke Ikawa
 
Fiscal PoFGFDYHFDHYFDHFDFDHFDFDHFDJDlicy.ppt
Fiscal PoFGFDYHFDHYFDHFDFDHFDFDHFDJDlicy.pptFiscal PoFGFDYHFDHYFDHFDFDHFDFDHFDJDlicy.ppt
Fiscal PoFGFDYHFDHYFDHFDFDHFDFDHFDJDlicy.pptwexop40522
 
Fiscal Policy finance and business...ppt
Fiscal Policy finance and business...pptFiscal Policy finance and business...ppt
Fiscal Policy finance and business...pptNidhiBhatnagar19
 
The multilateral debt relief initiative
The multilateral debt relief initiativeThe multilateral debt relief initiative
The multilateral debt relief initiativeitargeting
 
As late as 1992, the United States was running budget deficits of ne.pdf
As late as 1992, the United States was running budget deficits of ne.pdfAs late as 1992, the United States was running budget deficits of ne.pdf
As late as 1992, the United States was running budget deficits of ne.pdfarihantmum
 
Gregory mankiw macroeconomic 7th edition chapter (15)
Gregory mankiw macroeconomic 7th edition chapter  (15)Gregory mankiw macroeconomic 7th edition chapter  (15)
Gregory mankiw macroeconomic 7th edition chapter (15)Kyaw Thiha
 
BerkeleyCTeate_Microeconomics_PublicDebt
BerkeleyCTeate_Microeconomics_PublicDebtBerkeleyCTeate_Microeconomics_PublicDebt
BerkeleyCTeate_Microeconomics_PublicDebtBerkeley Teate
 
Can the government go broke eea 2017
Can the government go broke eea 2017Can the government go broke eea 2017
Can the government go broke eea 2017pkconference
 

Similaire à Beatriz Armendariz (20)

MACROECONOMICS-CH15
MACROECONOMICS-CH15MACROECONOMICS-CH15
MACROECONOMICS-CH15
 
Debt crisis macro_ Daniel COHEN
Debt crisis macro_ Daniel COHENDebt crisis macro_ Daniel COHEN
Debt crisis macro_ Daniel COHEN
 
Debt relief initiative for poor countries
Debt relief initiative for poor countriesDebt relief initiative for poor countries
Debt relief initiative for poor countries
 
CASE Network E-briefs 12.2009 - From fiscal stimulus to fiscal crisis
CASE Network E-briefs 12.2009 - From fiscal stimulus to fiscal crisisCASE Network E-briefs 12.2009 - From fiscal stimulus to fiscal crisis
CASE Network E-briefs 12.2009 - From fiscal stimulus to fiscal crisis
 
Briefing Note DEBT #2edited
Briefing Note DEBT #2editedBriefing Note DEBT #2edited
Briefing Note DEBT #2edited
 
To the Point, 2010 January
To the Point, 2010 JanuaryTo the Point, 2010 January
To the Point, 2010 January
 
Subnational Debt Management in Brazil and Mexico: Fernando Blanco, Lead Econo...
Subnational Debt Management in Brazil and Mexico: Fernando Blanco, Lead Econo...Subnational Debt Management in Brazil and Mexico: Fernando Blanco, Lead Econo...
Subnational Debt Management in Brazil and Mexico: Fernando Blanco, Lead Econo...
 
Debt overhang past and present
Debt overhang past and presentDebt overhang past and present
Debt overhang past and present
 
Ipe10
Ipe10Ipe10
Ipe10
 
The Great Recession
The  Great  RecessionThe  Great  Recession
The Great Recession
 
Fiscal Policy.ppt
Fiscal Policy.pptFiscal Policy.ppt
Fiscal Policy.ppt
 
Fiscal PoFGFDYHFDHYFDHFDFDHFDFDHFDJDlicy.ppt
Fiscal PoFGFDYHFDHYFDHFDFDHFDFDHFDJDlicy.pptFiscal PoFGFDYHFDHYFDHFDFDHFDFDHFDJDlicy.ppt
Fiscal PoFGFDYHFDHYFDHFDFDHFDFDHFDJDlicy.ppt
 
Fiscal Policy.ppt
Fiscal Policy.pptFiscal Policy.ppt
Fiscal Policy.ppt
 
Fiscal Policy finance and business...ppt
Fiscal Policy finance and business...pptFiscal Policy finance and business...ppt
Fiscal Policy finance and business...ppt
 
The multilateral debt relief initiative
The multilateral debt relief initiativeThe multilateral debt relief initiative
The multilateral debt relief initiative
 
As late as 1992, the United States was running budget deficits of ne.pdf
As late as 1992, the United States was running budget deficits of ne.pdfAs late as 1992, the United States was running budget deficits of ne.pdf
As late as 1992, the United States was running budget deficits of ne.pdf
 
Gregory mankiw macroeconomic 7th edition chapter (15)
Gregory mankiw macroeconomic 7th edition chapter  (15)Gregory mankiw macroeconomic 7th edition chapter  (15)
Gregory mankiw macroeconomic 7th edition chapter (15)
 
BerkeleyCTeate_Microeconomics_PublicDebt
BerkeleyCTeate_Microeconomics_PublicDebtBerkeleyCTeate_Microeconomics_PublicDebt
BerkeleyCTeate_Microeconomics_PublicDebt
 
Budgeting in Brazil
Budgeting in BrazilBudgeting in Brazil
Budgeting in Brazil
 
Can the government go broke eea 2017
Can the government go broke eea 2017Can the government go broke eea 2017
Can the government go broke eea 2017
 

Dernier

The Most Excellent Way | 1 Corinthians 13
The Most Excellent Way | 1 Corinthians 13The Most Excellent Way | 1 Corinthians 13
The Most Excellent Way | 1 Corinthians 13Steve Thomason
 
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptxHow to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptxmanuelaromero2013
 
Sanyam Choudhary Chemistry practical.pdf
Sanyam Choudhary Chemistry practical.pdfSanyam Choudhary Chemistry practical.pdf
Sanyam Choudhary Chemistry practical.pdfsanyamsingh5019
 
Science 7 - LAND and SEA BREEZE and its Characteristics
Science 7 - LAND and SEA BREEZE and its CharacteristicsScience 7 - LAND and SEA BREEZE and its Characteristics
Science 7 - LAND and SEA BREEZE and its CharacteristicsKarinaGenton
 
“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...
“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...
“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...Marc Dusseiller Dusjagr
 
A Critique of the Proposed National Education Policy Reform
A Critique of the Proposed National Education Policy ReformA Critique of the Proposed National Education Policy Reform
A Critique of the Proposed National Education Policy ReformChameera Dedduwage
 
Concept of Vouching. B.Com(Hons) /B.Compdf
Concept of Vouching. B.Com(Hons) /B.CompdfConcept of Vouching. B.Com(Hons) /B.Compdf
Concept of Vouching. B.Com(Hons) /B.CompdfUmakantAnnand
 
Measures of Central Tendency: Mean, Median and Mode
Measures of Central Tendency: Mean, Median and ModeMeasures of Central Tendency: Mean, Median and Mode
Measures of Central Tendency: Mean, Median and ModeThiyagu K
 
Arihant handbook biology for class 11 .pdf
Arihant handbook biology for class 11 .pdfArihant handbook biology for class 11 .pdf
Arihant handbook biology for class 11 .pdfchloefrazer622
 
Incoming and Outgoing Shipments in 1 STEP Using Odoo 17
Incoming and Outgoing Shipments in 1 STEP Using Odoo 17Incoming and Outgoing Shipments in 1 STEP Using Odoo 17
Incoming and Outgoing Shipments in 1 STEP Using Odoo 17Celine George
 
_Math 4-Q4 Week 5.pptx Steps in Collecting Data
_Math 4-Q4 Week 5.pptx Steps in Collecting Data_Math 4-Q4 Week 5.pptx Steps in Collecting Data
_Math 4-Q4 Week 5.pptx Steps in Collecting DataJhengPantaleon
 
Q4-W6-Restating Informational Text Grade 3
Q4-W6-Restating Informational Text Grade 3Q4-W6-Restating Informational Text Grade 3
Q4-W6-Restating Informational Text Grade 3JemimahLaneBuaron
 
Grant Readiness 101 TechSoup and Remy Consulting
Grant Readiness 101 TechSoup and Remy ConsultingGrant Readiness 101 TechSoup and Remy Consulting
Grant Readiness 101 TechSoup and Remy ConsultingTechSoup
 
Presiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha elections
Presiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha electionsPresiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha elections
Presiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha electionsanshu789521
 
Industrial Policy - 1948, 1956, 1973, 1977, 1980, 1991
Industrial Policy - 1948, 1956, 1973, 1977, 1980, 1991Industrial Policy - 1948, 1956, 1973, 1977, 1980, 1991
Industrial Policy - 1948, 1956, 1973, 1977, 1980, 1991RKavithamani
 
microwave assisted reaction. General introduction
microwave assisted reaction. General introductionmicrowave assisted reaction. General introduction
microwave assisted reaction. General introductionMaksud Ahmed
 
Organic Name Reactions for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptx
Organic Name Reactions  for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptxOrganic Name Reactions  for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptx
Organic Name Reactions for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptxVS Mahajan Coaching Centre
 

Dernier (20)

TataKelola dan KamSiber Kecerdasan Buatan v022.pdf
TataKelola dan KamSiber Kecerdasan Buatan v022.pdfTataKelola dan KamSiber Kecerdasan Buatan v022.pdf
TataKelola dan KamSiber Kecerdasan Buatan v022.pdf
 
The Most Excellent Way | 1 Corinthians 13
The Most Excellent Way | 1 Corinthians 13The Most Excellent Way | 1 Corinthians 13
The Most Excellent Way | 1 Corinthians 13
 
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptxHow to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
How to Make a Pirate ship Primary Education.pptx
 
Sanyam Choudhary Chemistry practical.pdf
Sanyam Choudhary Chemistry practical.pdfSanyam Choudhary Chemistry practical.pdf
Sanyam Choudhary Chemistry practical.pdf
 
Código Creativo y Arte de Software | Unidad 1
Código Creativo y Arte de Software | Unidad 1Código Creativo y Arte de Software | Unidad 1
Código Creativo y Arte de Software | Unidad 1
 
Science 7 - LAND and SEA BREEZE and its Characteristics
Science 7 - LAND and SEA BREEZE and its CharacteristicsScience 7 - LAND and SEA BREEZE and its Characteristics
Science 7 - LAND and SEA BREEZE and its Characteristics
 
“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...
“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...
“Oh GOSH! Reflecting on Hackteria's Collaborative Practices in a Global Do-It...
 
A Critique of the Proposed National Education Policy Reform
A Critique of the Proposed National Education Policy ReformA Critique of the Proposed National Education Policy Reform
A Critique of the Proposed National Education Policy Reform
 
Concept of Vouching. B.Com(Hons) /B.Compdf
Concept of Vouching. B.Com(Hons) /B.CompdfConcept of Vouching. B.Com(Hons) /B.Compdf
Concept of Vouching. B.Com(Hons) /B.Compdf
 
Measures of Central Tendency: Mean, Median and Mode
Measures of Central Tendency: Mean, Median and ModeMeasures of Central Tendency: Mean, Median and Mode
Measures of Central Tendency: Mean, Median and Mode
 
Staff of Color (SOC) Retention Efforts DDSD
Staff of Color (SOC) Retention Efforts DDSDStaff of Color (SOC) Retention Efforts DDSD
Staff of Color (SOC) Retention Efforts DDSD
 
Arihant handbook biology for class 11 .pdf
Arihant handbook biology for class 11 .pdfArihant handbook biology for class 11 .pdf
Arihant handbook biology for class 11 .pdf
 
Incoming and Outgoing Shipments in 1 STEP Using Odoo 17
Incoming and Outgoing Shipments in 1 STEP Using Odoo 17Incoming and Outgoing Shipments in 1 STEP Using Odoo 17
Incoming and Outgoing Shipments in 1 STEP Using Odoo 17
 
_Math 4-Q4 Week 5.pptx Steps in Collecting Data
_Math 4-Q4 Week 5.pptx Steps in Collecting Data_Math 4-Q4 Week 5.pptx Steps in Collecting Data
_Math 4-Q4 Week 5.pptx Steps in Collecting Data
 
Q4-W6-Restating Informational Text Grade 3
Q4-W6-Restating Informational Text Grade 3Q4-W6-Restating Informational Text Grade 3
Q4-W6-Restating Informational Text Grade 3
 
Grant Readiness 101 TechSoup and Remy Consulting
Grant Readiness 101 TechSoup and Remy ConsultingGrant Readiness 101 TechSoup and Remy Consulting
Grant Readiness 101 TechSoup and Remy Consulting
 
Presiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha elections
Presiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha electionsPresiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha elections
Presiding Officer Training module 2024 lok sabha elections
 
Industrial Policy - 1948, 1956, 1973, 1977, 1980, 1991
Industrial Policy - 1948, 1956, 1973, 1977, 1980, 1991Industrial Policy - 1948, 1956, 1973, 1977, 1980, 1991
Industrial Policy - 1948, 1956, 1973, 1977, 1980, 1991
 
microwave assisted reaction. General introduction
microwave assisted reaction. General introductionmicrowave assisted reaction. General introduction
microwave assisted reaction. General introduction
 
Organic Name Reactions for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptx
Organic Name Reactions  for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptxOrganic Name Reactions  for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptx
Organic Name Reactions for the students and aspirants of Chemistry12th.pptx
 

Beatriz Armendariz

  • 1. JOURNAL OF Development Journal of Development Economics ECONOMICS ELSEVIER Vol. 48 (1995) 135-149 Debt relief, growth and price stability in Mexico Beatriz Armendfiriz de Aghion a,*, Patricia Armendfiriz de Hinestrosa b a The London School of Economics, Houghton Street, London WC2A 2AE, UK b Comisi6n Nacional Bancaria, Mexico City, Mexico Received 15 June 1993; revised 15 September 1994 Abstract Inspired by the negotiation of the foreign debt of Mexico in 1989 this paper provides a framework to show that, prior to debt relief, an LDC government which is indebted both domestically and externally has an additional incentive not to default on its external obligations. However, repayment of the external debt is shown to involve a delicate tradeoff between growth and inflation: on the one hand the government increases its ability to keep domestic interest rates relatively low thereby promoting investment and growth; on the other hand the government worsens the budget-deficit problem thereby introducing addi- tional inflationary pressures. The way to improve this tradeoff is by negotiating a debt relief operation on the foreign debt. JEL classification: F34; Oll; O16 Keywords: Debt-relief; Risk-premium; Inflation; Stabilization; Growth 1. Introduction In April 1989 Mexico successfully negotiated a debt-relief package with its foreign creditors, with an immediate impact on domestic interest rates which fell by approximately 35 percentage points. In turn, such a sharp fall in interest rates had an undeniable positive effect on growth, and it reduced the size of the secondary deficit thereby inducing price stability. * Corresponding author. 0304-3878/95/$09.50 © 1995 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved SSD1 0304-3878(95)00032-1
  • 2. B. Armend6riz de Aghion, P. Armend6riz de Hinestrosa/Journal of Development Economics 48 136 (1995) 135-149 Possibly because Mexico was the first beneficiary in a long list of less developed countries (LDCs) qualifying for debt relief under the so-called Brady plan, 1 such positive effects have been widely acknowledged by the press, government officials and economists alike (see, notably, Van Wijnbergen (1991) and Ortiz (1991)). To most observers, the positive effects of debt relief have two distinct explanations: one is the debt-overhang explanation - which had already been pointed out long before the Mexican debt-relief operation, notably by Krugman (1988), 2 and the other is the reduction-of-uncertainty explanation - evidenced by the sudden fall in domestic interest rates. This distinction has prompted a number of empirical studies (see, notably Claessens et al., 1994) suggesting that the latter explanation had indeed been underestimated. This paper can be viewed as a first attempt at formalizing the reduction-of-un- certainty explanation. More precisely, using a signalling argument ~t la Spence (1973) we show that an L D C government which is indebted both externally and domestically has an additional incentive not to default on its external obligations. However, repayment of the external debt is shown to involve a delicate tradeoff between growth and inflation: on the one hand, the government increases its ability to keep domestic interest rates relatively low thereby promoting investment and growth; on the other hand the government worsens the budget-deficit problem thereby introducing additional inflationary pressures. A way to improve this tradeoff is by negotiating a debt relief operation on the external debt. Previous analytical work on growth and stabilization in the LDCs has failed to establish an explicit link between the external and the domestic debt. 3 One notable exception is Calvo (1988). In his model, a default on the external debt by an LDC government is viewed as a transfer of resources from foreign creditors to domestic creditors. Domestic creditors then expect to be reimbursed with a higher probability and thus require a lower premium to hold domestic government debt. However, Calvo's (1988) model remains unsatisfactory in one important respect: it does not explain why the Mexican government, like several other LDC govern- ments after it, would seek a negotiated debt-relief settlement instead of opting for a more drastic foreign debt reduction as triggered by a (unilateral) default. In this paper we argue that the main reason why Calvo's (1988) predictions are 1 This plan was launched in March 1989 by the US Treasury Secretary Nicholas Brady. It calls for a reduction of the external debt of middle-income countries through the use of international resources for 'enhancement' collateral on the replacement of debt instruments. (See Van Wijnbergen, 1991.) 2 This explanation is based on the following (incentive) argument: by being granted debt relief an LDC government has an incentive to improve its economic performance since it knows that any additional benefit (from an improved performance) will no longer accrue (entirely) to the creditors but to the country itself. 3 What we do find, however, is a growing number of descriptive contributions suggesting that debt relief could help to enhance credibility in the stabilization program. (See, for example, Dornbusch (1988), Ortiz (1991), and Van Wijnbergen (1991) for the particular case of Mexico).
  • 3. B. Armend6riz de Aghion, P. Armend~riz de Hinestrosa /Journal of Development Economics 48 (1995) 135-149 137 Table 1 Ex-ante and ex-post real interest rates and secondary deficit in Mexico (1985-1990) 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 Ex-ante real a 16.55 20.90 18.77 24.10 n/a n/a Ex-post real b -42.50 -71.14 52.00 44.07 14.87 16.23 Secondary deficit 0.8 2.4 - 1.8 3.5 1.7 - 1.8 (% GDP) c a Ex-ante rates: Yearly average rates of 3-month CETES less expected inflation for the year. Source: Rojas-Su~rez (1992). b Ex-post interest rates of yearly average CETES. Source: Banamex. c Source: Export-Import Bank of Japan Review (1991). potentially misleading is because debt relief operations are viewed as a purely resource-saving operation. What we show on the contrary is that foreign debt reduction through a (unilateral) default should be dominated by negotiated debt relief operations in lending support to an LDC government's efforts to bring the economy to a high growth-low inflation equilibrium. The structure the paper is as follows: In Section 2 we motivate our analysis by providing a brief account of the 1989 debt reduction agreement between Mexico and its foreign creditors. We then introduce the basic (signalling) framework in Section 3, and we extend the model in Section 4 to account for the potential benefits of debt relief operations on growth and stabilization. Finally, we spell out some concluding remarks in Section 5. 2. Mexico before and after debt relief In December 1987 a harsh (heterodox) stabilization programme was started in Mexico. The programme was introduced by a team of Mexican officials with an outstanding background in economics. 4 Yet, uncertainty about whether stabiliza- tion was going to last kept real interest rates high. As we show in Table 1 such (ex-ante) rates increased from 18.77 in 1987 to 24.10 in 1988. This had a drastic impact on the secondary deficit which in 1988 was at a five-year high reaching 3.5 percent of GDP. In the midst of stabilization and under the Brady plan, 5 in April 1989, Mexico negotiated a debt relief package with its external creditors. In a manner that could accommodate all parties involved with the plan's main principle, namely, that of debt-service reduction, the external creditors of Mexico were given the choice between the following three options: (a) exchange their original claims against 4 See Aspe (1993) for a detailed account of the stabilization program itself. 5 See footnote 1 above
  • 4. B. Armend6riz de Aghion, P. Armend6riz de Hinestrosa // Journal of Development Economics 48 138 (1995) 135-149 Table 2 Current account savings implied by debt relief in Mexico (millions of dollars) 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 Debt reduction(options(a) and ( b ) ) 2252.2 1501.0 1501.0 1501.0 1501.0 New money (option(c)) 756.0 648.0 648.0 0.0 0.0 Source: Data collected by one of the authors from the Office of the Undersecretary of Finance, Mexico. new bonds at a floating LIBOR rate but with principal reduced by 35 percent of original face value; (b) exchange their original claims against new bonds paying a fixed (6.25 percent) interest rate; and (c) keep their original claims but provide new money equivalent to 25 percent of the amount brought under this option. Nearly half the creditors favoured the first option, over one third the second, and a relatively small fraction the third. 6 This debt-relief operation amounted to approx- imately 30 percent of the Mexican foreign debt (or some $13 billion of the $50 billion included in the negotiations). 7 In terms of resource transfers, which represented some 5.5 percent of annual GDP in 1982-1988, the debt relief operation was estimated to have reduced such transfers approximately to 2.4 percent for the period 1989-1992 (Ortiz, 1991). Table 2 replicates the resource transfers savings implied by debt relief as estimated by Mexican officials. The amount of debt relief granted to Mexico was rather low, particularly when one compares it to historical standards. 8 To most observers, however, the main impact of debt relief was on interest rates (see, notably Claessens et al. (1994)). When the debt reduction agreement was announced in April 1989 interest rates collapsed. T-bills, in particular fell by 14 to 19 percentage points. 9 When the agreement was signed in early 1990 they again started a steady downward trend. Overall, by December 1990 interest rates were around 30 percentage points below when compared to the period prior to the agreement. With regards to real rates, 6 The precise figures are: 46.7% of the creditors opted for (a), 38.2% for (b) and 13.1% for (c). For a more detailed descriptionsee, Van Wijnbergen(1991). 7 Not all the outstandingforeign obligationsof Mexico were subjectto negotiationunder the Brady Plan. Of the $61.3 billion outstanding,$7.3 billion was interbank debt involving Mexican banks, and $5.1 billion had been contracted under 'special circumstances'.This left a total of $48.9 billion. 8 Specially when one compares it to the 70% debt reduction Mexico obtained from its foreign creditors in the Suarez-Lamont agreement back in 1942. (See Armendfirizde Aghion, 1993.) The recent debt relief package is also modest when compared to what some other countrieshave obtainedin the past. Germany,for example obtainedas much as 70% debt relief in the Londonagreementof 1953, Indonesia52% in the late 1960s (Farber, 1990), and Brazil some 50 to 70% in 1943 (Eichengreenand Portes, 1989). 9 Rates of other instrumentslike bank acceptances fell by 8 percentage points (Banamex).
  • 5. B. Armend6riz de Aghion, P. Armenddtriz de Hinestrosa /Journal of Development Economics 48 (1995) 135-149 139 45 DealAgreed 40 35 ~. . . . . . . ~ '~ 3O ?~ . .= 25 ". /' .. - .~.. ! Ex-post ! 2 - g. 2o Ex-ante 15 ,, 10 0 I t I I I I I I I I I Mar-e8 Sep-88 Mar-e9 Sep-89 Mar-90 Sep-90 Jun-88 Dec-88 Jun-89 Dec-89 Jun-90 Dec-90 Source: Rojas-Suarez (1992) Fig. 1. Ex-ante and ex-post real interest rate.Source: Rojas-Sufirez(1992). Fig. 1 shows the b e h a v i o u r of both ex-ante and ex-post real interest rates. These fell by 35 percentage points following the a n n o u n c e m e n t of the agreement and reassumed a steady d o w n w a r d trend after the agreement was signed. O n the other hand the (post debt-relief) growth rate increased to approximately 3.3 percent in 1989 and then to 4.4 percent in 1990 w h e n it reached a ten-year record (see Table 3). A l t h o u g h other considerations can potentially account for such a high rate of growth, 10 the impact of debt relief is undeniable. Both because relatively lower transfer of resources 11 and, more importantly, because it implied substantially lower interest rates 12. Moreover, the stabilization p r o g r a m m e itself benefited from the lower interest rates as these implied a lower operational deficit, t3 The gains in stabilization were remarkable: as s h o w n in Table 3 the iJlflation rate fell from 114.2 percent in 1988 to 20 percent in 1989, and price volatility was brought d o w n from 2.5 in 1988 to 1.4 in 1989. 10 Notably progress on the stabilization front and continuation of structural reform. ii Particularly because Mexico did not default on its external debt throughout the eight-year period prior to debt relief. 12 Van Wijnbergen (1991) has estimated Mexico's prospective growth rate following debt relief to have increased over the 1990-1994 period by approximately 2 percentage points annually. Of this amount, he argues, one half comes from the direct effect of resource transfer alleviation, and the other half comes from the 'indirect' effects, and in particular from the lower interest rate and higher investment. 13 As a matter of fact, the operational component of the government deficit improved from a deficit of 3.5 percentage points in 1988 to a surplus of 1.8 percent in 1990 (See Table 1).
  • 6. B. Armenddriz de Aghion, P. Armenddriz de Hinestrosa /Journal of Development Economics 48 140 (1995) 135-149 Table 3 GDP growth and inflation in Mexico (1985-1990) 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 GDP growth (real) 2.6 -3.8 1.9 1.2 3.3 4.4 Inflation a 57.8 86.2 131.8 114.2 20.0 26.7 Price volatility b 3.9 5.9 8.3 2.5 1.4 1.9 a CPI. Accumulated monthly inflation rate, Jan-Dec of each year. b Yearly average percent variation in CPI from month to month. Source: Banco de Mexico The above stylized facts on the Mexican debt-relief operation and its impact on growth and price stability motivate the following model. 3. The model Consider a two-period economy, T = 1,2, with identical consumers and a government. Each (representative) consumer at period T = 1 has an initial endow- ment, y, expressed in units of output, which he can either consume or invest. There are two investment opportunities: in real assets, k, which yield 1 + r units of output in period 2, where r denotes the real interest rate; or in domestic government bonds, b, which yield (1 + i)(1 - O(b))/1 + 7re units of output in period 2. i denotes the nominal interest rate, 7r e is expected inflation, and O(b) represents a portion of domestic government debt which is expected to be repudiated, x4 Arbitrage between real assets and government bonds requires that the rate of return on both these assets be equalized, that is, 15 (l+i)(1-O(b)) l+r= l+~r ~ (1) which, for simplicity can be approximated as follows: i(b)=r+Tr~+O(b), i'(b)>O,O'(b)>O. (2) Eq. (2) captures the following idea: bond financing can potentially increase the probability of default, O(b). This in turn raises the nominal interest rate, i(b), and thus crowds out investment (in the first period). 14 This possibility cannot be ruled out when, in particular, a country is unable to raise the required tax revenue (see, for example, Ize and Ortiz (1987)), a n d / o r when repaying the debt by creating money involves (high) inflation costs. Historically, defaults on domestic debt have been observed in, for example, the stabilization programs in Argentina under President Menem in 1989, and in Brazil under President Collor in 1989 (see Cardoso and Helwege, 1992). 15 Eq. (1) is an amended version of the Fisher equation to account for the possibility that the government defaults on its domestic debt.
  • 7. B. Armend6riz de Aghion, P. Armend~riz de Hinestrosa /Journal of Development Economics 48 (1995) 135-149 141 T h e r e is no i n v e s t m e n t in the s e c o n d period, that is, w e suppose that at period 2 returns f r o m p r e v i o u s period i n v e s t m e n t s are realized and that these are c o n s u m e d . T h e g o v e r n m e n t at period 1, on the other hand, has the f o l l o w i n g (intertem- poral) b u d g e t constraint: g(l + i(b)) + d-t= A m + Ab, (3) w h e r e g(1 + i(b)) is (per capita) g o v e r n m e n t spending (including current spend- ing on d o m e s t i c debt services), d is (per capita) g o v e r n m e n t debt o w e d to external creditors, and t is the e x p e c t e d (per capita) tax revenue f r o m c o n s u m e r s ' invest- m e n t returns in real assets. 16 The R H S o f (3) shows the w a y the g o v e r n m e n t finances its deficit, n a m e l y through a c o m b i n a t i o n o f m o n e y creation, Am, and through the issue o f n e w bonds, Ab. Both A m and Ab are expressed in per capita terms. 17 Specifically, (2) says that current expenditures, g(1 + ( i ( b ) ) ) + d, are financed through a c o m b i n a t i o n o f m o n e y creation and bonds; and that future expenditures, e.g., d o m e s t i c debt r e p a y m e n t s in period 2, are financed through the s e c o n d - p e r i o d taxation o f real assets. 18 W e k n o w by (2) that bond f i n a n c i n g raises the interest rate. M o n e y financing, on the other hand, raises the (expected) inflation rate: Am m2 - m I g ( l + i( b ) ) + d - te - b 7r e = - - - (4) m1 ml ml W e suppose a s y m m e t r i c information on the tax revenues. Specifically, w e suppose t is private information. That is, the g o v e r n m e n t is assumed to be better i n f o r m e d than the c o n s u m e r s about the size of the tax revenue, t, e x p e c t e d to be raised in period 2. 19 M o r e o v e r , w e will consider the case where, due to the a b o v e informational a s y m m e t r y , the g o v e r n m e n t ' s external-debt r e p a y m e n t m a y c o n v e y 16 TO make the model as simple as possible we suppose taxation is non-distortionary. 17 Notice that this government cannot finance the deficit by borrowing in the international capital markets. This captures well the reality of the Latin American countries in the 1980s. 18 In particular, we are making the simplifying assumption that the external debt is to be repaid/defaulted upon before the domestic debt. To make the model more realistic we could have referred to external debt service obligations instead, but this would only have complicated the notation without actually altering our main results in any significant manner. It is not difficult for anyone familiar with the LDC debt crisis to see how such an assumption can be justified. Typically, LDCs throughout the 1980s could no longer borrow abroad to finance government expenditures, and whenever a decision had to be taken regarding the external debt inherited from the past, governments already had an outstanding domestic debt which they had issued at a floating interest rate and/or would systematically issue new bonds to finance government expenditures (including external debt services). In either case a domestic debt (in some instances very large, indeed) would be outstanding after any decision had been taken regarding the external debt. 19 This assumption is not difficult to justify. In most LDCs (and in industrialized countries too!) tax revenues may be ex-post public information, but ex-ante government officials surely have a better estimate. The important point to note thus is that it is asymmetric information on the expected (not the actual) size of the deficit the main assumption which is driving the paper's main results.
  • 8. B. Armend[triz de Aghion, P. Armend~riz de Hinestrosa /Journal of Development Economics 48 142 (1995) 135-149 information about the size of the tax revenue, and, in turn, about the size of the deficit. That is, we explore the possibility of a separating equilibrium to exist. 20 In such an equilibrium, as described below, repayment of the external debt is shown to involve a delicate tradeoff between growth and inflation: on the one hand the government increases its ability to keep domestic interest rates relatively low thereby promoting investment and growth; on the other hand the government worsens the budget-deficit problem thereby introducing additional inflationary pressures. Specifically we suppose the government's objective function is 21 max{ k ( i( b ) ) - c(,rre)} (5) b s.t. (3) and (4). In words: the government maximises investment returns of a representative consumer, k(i(b)), net of (per capita) inflation costs, c(~e), subject to (3) and (4). The timing of the model is as set out in Fig. 2. 22 We now proceed to solving the above signalling model. Instead of considering all possible equilibria we will focus on a separating equilibrium. By separating equilibrium we mean an equilibrium where the government's repayment strategy fully reveals information about its type. I.e., if the government repays it will signal itself as a t-type and if it defaults it will signal itself as a t-type. More formally, we define a separating equilibrium as a triplet (p., ~,s), where /x denotes the consumers' beliefs and ~ (resp. s) denotes the 7-government's (resp. t- government's) repayment strategy, such that (a) /x is Bayes-consistent with (~, s) T=I T=2 I I , t t F..xtetnal debt repayment Tax ~ u ~ oollcet¢~l and decision and bond/money domestic debt repaid . financing decision. Fig. 2. The timing. 20 As a first approximation to see how this possibility could emerge, it may be useful to illustrate some common perceptions: a government's debt-repayment policy is likely to signal compliance with IMF conditionality, and, thus, consumers may expect that the government deficit will be relatively small; and a government's non-repayment (or default) policy may signal non-compliance with IMF conditionality, and thus, consumers may expect that the government deficit will be relatively large. We show below that a separating equilibrium like the one just described, exists. 21 Notice that, for simplicity, we are (implicitly) assuming that the consumers' discount factor is sufficiently high (i.e. close to one) that consumers are perfectly happy to substitute consumption in period 1 for consumption in period 2. One can easily verify that our results will carry over to the case where the consumers' discount factor is less than one. 22 See footnote 18 above.
  • 9. B. Armend{triz de Aghion, P. Armend,~riz de Hinestrosa /Journal of Development Economics 48 (1995) 135-149 143 such that ~ = repayment and s = default; and ~ is such that ~(repayment) = t and /,(default) = t. Clearly, such an equilibrium will not always exist. In particular, both for sufficiently large and for sufficiently small values of the parameter d a pooling instead of separating equilibrium is obtained. The reason is straightforward: suppose d is sufficiently large. Then, a default decision does not convey informa- tion about the (expected) tax revenue to the consumers since both a }- and a t-government default. 23 And similarly, when d is sufficiently small, a repayment decision does not convey any information about the (expected) tax revenue either since both a t- and a t-government systematically repay. 24 Let us now explore the possibility of a separating equilibrium to exist (for intermediate values of d). More formally, we shall consider first the case of a }-government and solve the model by backward induction. Specifically, if the government repays consumers update their beliefs and ask for a lower interest rate, ~r(b), to hold domestic government debt; and by repaying the government in this case gets: mbax{k(gr(b) ) _ (g(l+tr(b))+d--t-b)} C (6) ml If, on the other hand, the government defaults consumers will update their beliefs and ask for a higher interest rate, g0(b), to hold domestic government debt. Thus, by defaulting the government gets n~x{k(~d(b))-c(g(l+~a(b))--t-b)},ml (7) where -t-t- d i'd(b) - i'~(b) m, - g (8) by substitution of (3) into (2). 25 23 In this case consumers are unable to distinguish whether the government defaults because its external debt is very large indeed or because the tax revenue is expected to be small. z4 In this case consumers are unable to distinguish whether the government repays because its external debt is very small indeed or because the tax revenue is expected to be large. 25 Specifically: ~(b) = r + H e + O(b) =:~~'d(b) -- i'r(b) = H2(b ) - /1"re(b) ~d(b) -- ~r(b) = [( g ( l + i'd(b)) --_t-- b ) / m 1] - [( g(1 + ~r(b)) + d - "t - b ) / m I ] =~ i'd(b ) - i'r(b) = [((~'-_t- d ) / m l ) / ( 1 - g / m , ) ] = [ ( } - t - d ) / ( m , - g)].
  • 10. B. Armend~riz de Aghion, P. Armend~riz de Hinestrosa /Journal o[ Development Economics 48 144 (1995) 135-149 ~/ IT(I IrOIb) lb) J( Ir Ib) I(Irlb) Eo I Fig. 3. Repayment by a t-government in a separating equilibrium. A sufficient condition for a t-government to repay will thus be that (for all b): (g(1 +'ir(b))+d--t-b ) k('i,( b ) ) - c m 1 ( g ( 1 + i'd(b)) -- t - - b ) > k('id(b)) - c (9) ml And the effects of repaying the external debt by a t-government when the above condition is satisfied, e.g., for intermediate values of d, is depicted in Fig. 3. The i- and 7r-schedules in Fig. 3, respectively, show the relationship between the nominal interest rate and the inflation rate as described by (2) and (4). Both schedules are drawn for a given (optimally chosen) quantity of government bonds. When a t-type government decides to repay, due to the signalling effect the /-schedule shifts downwards; and due to the resource transfer effect the 7r-schedule shifts to the right. 26 The shifting of both these schedules will therefore take us from a point like E 0 to a point like E 1 in Fig. 3. That is, a repayment strategy involves a relatively lower interest rate and a relatively higher inflation rate. Clearly, condition (9) will be violated for d sufficiently large. This is because a repayment policy in this case involves a large 'resource-transfer effect' which is not offset by a (positive) 'signalling effect'. We should note, however, that condition (9) is not sufficient for a separating equilibrium to exist. We require something else: we need that, for the same value of the parameters d, t, t, and g, a t-government decides to default. Again, to 26 The relative magnitude of those shifts will depend both upon the sensitivity of the interest rate to the government's external debt policy, and on the size of the external debt transfer.
  • 11. B. Armend6riz de Aghion, P. Armend{triz de Hinestrosa /Journal of Development Economics 48 (1995) 135-149 145 t fro Ib) ll(i Ib) / I(IrIb) El ~i(frlb) 0 If Fig. 4. Defaultby a t-governmentin a separatingequilibrium. analyse how this possibility can arise we reason by backward induction: if a t-government repays, consumers update their beliefs and ask for 7~(b) to hold domestic government debt, and what the t-government gets is { (g(l+~r(b))+d-t-b)} , (10) ml and if it defaults consumers will ask for 7d(b) and the t-government gets mbax{k(gd(b) ) _ (g(l+~d(b))-t-b)} (11) ml A sufficient condition for a t-government to decide to default is that, for all b, ( g ( 1 + ~d(b)) --t-- b) - c ml (g(l +'ir(b)) + d-t-b) > k('ir(b)) - c - (12) ml The effects of a default by a t-government on interest rates and inflation are shown in Fig. 4. Typically, such a government will experience a positive resource-transfer effect and an adverse signalling effect; and both of these combined will lead to a relatively lower inflation rate and a relatively higher interest rate. That is, in terms of the diagram the post-default inflation and interest rates will be at a point to the north-west of E 0 such as E 1. Clearly, condition (12) - and more generally the inequality (11) > (10), would be violated for d sufficiently small because the (adverse) signalling effect will offset the (positive) resource-saving effect. Therefore, it is only for intermediate
  • 12. B. Armenddriz de Aghion, P. Armenddriz de Hinestrosa /Journal of Development Economics 48 146 (1995) 135-149 values of d that we can expect a separating equilibrium to exist; and a sufficient condition is that both inequalities (9) and (12) are satisfied. Specifically, for a separating equilibrium to exist the following is required: (g(1 + ~'d(b)) --t-- b) (g(1 +~r(b))+d-t-b) --c +c - m1 ml > k(~r(b)) - k(~d(b)) (13) ( g + ~d(b) - ~' - b) ( g ( 1 + ~r(b)) + d - - t - b ) +c ml m1 which clearly holds only when the cost function is sufficiently convex. That is, only in this case a t-government defaults - because inflation costs will otherwise raise too quickly; and the t-government repays - because a relatively small increase in the inflation cost will be offset by a relatively large reduction in the interest rate. This result can now be summarized in the following: Proposition 1. For d neither too large nor too small and for inflation costs which are sufficiently convex, there exists a separating equilibrium where a -t-government repays and a t-government defaults. Clearly, once signalling considerations are taken into account, by deciding to repay the external debt an L D C government can potentially promote investment and growth but at the expense of relatively high inflation; and by deciding to default it can achieve a relatively low inflation rate but will retard growth. 27 4. Debt relief The idea that debt relief can potentially lend support to an LDC government's efforts to promote growth with price stability has been around for some time now. 28 Yet, never has the evidence been so striking as in the case of Mexico where, as argued in Section 2, the debt relief operation was a crucial component of the period of growth and price stability that followed. 29 27 Note that one can easily show that the above tradeoff will arise in a more general signalling framework which is beyond the scope of this paper. Suppose, for example, the external debt is sufficiently small. Then, by repaying there is no positive signalling effect (i.e. this would be a pooling equilibrium) but the transferring of resources abroad can potentially raise both inflation and interest rates. We explore another pooling equilibrium situation below. 28 See, notably, Krugman (1988) on debt relief and investment and Sachs (1987) on debt relief and price stabilization in Bolivia. 29 For more in support of this view, see Ortiz (199i).
  • 13. B. Armend6riz de Aghion, P. Armend6riz de Hinestrosa /Journal of Development Economics 48 (1995) 135-149 147 ff(i Ib) ff(i Ib) I(EIb) ff Fig. 5. Debt relief. This section will therefore extend our basic set-up of Section 3 to account for the Mexican debt relief experience. As illustrated in Fig. 5 the most likely effect of debt relief is to eliminate residual uncertainty about the government deficit. In other words, separating equilibria are likely to be eliminated because, by repaying a sufficiently low level of external debt the government does not convey any information about the (expected) tax revenue, and thus about the deficit. 30 Hence the /-schedule remains unaltered. At the same time, due to a (positive) resource- saving effect, the //-schedule shifts leftwards. The final equilibrium is at E 1 where both the interest rate and the inflation rate have fallen. Clearly, after debt relief the government will not default for the following reason: if it defaults on a sufficiently small debt the (adverse) signalling effect will come into play, thereby raising interest rates, and retarding investment and growth (e.g., the /-schedule would shift upwards). And this may in turn explain why creditors may be willing to grant debt relief in the first place! 3] 5. Concluding remarks LDCs have experienced debt crises before, yet never as in the 1980s have their external debts interfered so evidently with efforts to bring inflation down and grow out of recession. We have argued first that any resource-transfer saving involved in an LDC defaulting on its external debt can potentially be offset by an adverse signalling effect on that LDC's domestic debt market; and, second, that a 30 Typically, this would be a pooling equilibrium. 31 Note that debt relief in the above framework comes out naturally without the need of invoking incentive-based arguments such as the (well-publicized) debt overhang idea (see Krugman, 1988).
  • 14. B. Armenddriz de Aghion, P. Armend~riz de Hinestrosa /Journal of Development Economics 48 148 (1995) 135-149 (negotiated) debt-relief settlement is likely to dominate as a way for an LDC to achieve higher rates of growth while maintaining price stability. Our framework could be easily extended in at least two potentially interesting directions. Firstly, the model could incorporate considerations of exchange rate expectations. Our conjecture is that this would essentially reinforce the case for a negotiated debt-relief settlement: debt relief implies a lower transfer of (foreign- currency) resources abroad, and it should thus reduce expectations of an exchange rate depreciation. This in turn should further decrease the risk premium on domestic (government) debt. Secondly, the model can easily accommodate incen- tive-based arguments h la Krugman (1988), and thereby again further strengthen our argument for (negotiated) debt relief. 6. Acknowledgments This research was started while the first author was a Research Associate at the OECD Development Centre, Paris. She is particularly grateful to Helmut Reisen for very useful conversations and insights. Both authors are grateful to Daron Acemoglu, Patrick Bolton, Nicholas Stern, Tony Venables, participants of the Development Economics seminar at the London School of Economics, and especially to Philippe Aghion and an anonymous referee for very useful comments on an earlier version. The usual disclaimer, of course, applies. References Armendfiriz de Aghion, Beatriz, 1993, El precio de los bonos, las razones deuda-exportaci6n, y las moratorias en el servicio de la deuda exterior de un pais: E1 caso de M6xico, El Trimestre Econ6mico, June. Aspe, Pedro, 1993, Economic transformation: The Mexican way (The MIT Press, Cambridge, MA). Banco de Mexico, Indicadores econ6micos, various issues. Calvo, Guillermo, 1988, Servicing the public debt: The role of expectations, American Economic Review, Sep. Cardoso, Eliana and Ann Helwege, 1992, Latin America's economy: Diversity, trends, and conflicts (MIT Press, Cambridge, MA). Claessens, Stijn, Daniel Oks and Sweder van Wijnbergen, 1994, Interest rates, growth and external debt: The macroeconomic impact of Mexico's Brady deal, Discussion paper no. 904 (CEPR, London). Dombusch, Rudiger, 1988, Mexico, Economic Policy, Oct. Eichengreen, Barry and Richard Portes, 1989, Dealing with debt: The 1930s and the 1980s, Discussion paper no. 300 (CEPR, London) Feb. Export-Import Bank of Japan (EXIM) Review, 1991, Mexico: Economic reform and development strategy, Special issue (Fall). Farber, Mike, 1990, Renegotiating official debts, Finance and Development, Dec. Ize, Allan and Guillermo Ortiz, 1987, Fiscal rigidities, public debt, and capital flight, IMF Staff Papers 34, no.2, June.
  • 15. B. Armend6riz de Aghion, P. Armend,~riz de Hinestrosa /Journal of Development Economics 48 (1995) 135-149 149 Krugman, Paul, 1988, Financing vs. forgiving a debt overhang: Some analytical notes, Journal of Development Economics, Dec. Ortiz, Guillermo, 1991, Mexico beyond the debt crisis: Toward sustainable growth with price stability, in: M. Bruno et al., eds., Lessons of economic stabilization and its aftermath (The MIT Press, Cambridge, MA). Rojas-Su~irez, Liliana, 1992, An analysis of the linkages of macroeconomic policies in Mexico, in: Claudio Loser and Eliot Kalter, eds., Mexico: The strategy to achieve sustained economic growth, Occasional paper no. 99 (IMF, Washington, DC). Sachs, Jeffrey, 1987, The Bolivian hyperinflation and stabilization, American Economic Review 77, no. 2, May. Spence, Michael, 1973, Job market signalling, Quarterly Journal of Economics 87, 355-374. Van Wijnbergen, Sweder, 1991, The Mexican debt deal, Economic Policy, April.