SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 49
Download to read offline
Linking Value                          Jörg
                                       Meyer-Stamer
Chain Analysis and                     jms@mesopartner.com

the ““Making                           Frank Wältring
Markets work                           fw@mesopartner.com


better for the
Poor”” Concept
Final Version                          Duisburg and Dortmund
                                       February 2007




Paper prepared for the Pilot Project
“Innovative Approaches to Private
Sector Development”
Content


1         Purpose of this paper                                                    1


2         “Making market systems work better for the poor” and “Value Chain
          Promotion”: What is it about?                                            1


3         Concepts and methodologies                                               3
3.1       M4P                                                                     3
3.1.1     Weaknesses of the M4P approach                                          6
3.2       Value Chains                                                             7
3.2.1     Types of value chains                                                    8
3.2.2     Value chains and donor interventions                                     9
3.2.3     Weaknesses of the value chain approach                                  11
3.3       Interim conclusion                                                      12


4         How to link M4P + VC: Conceptual considerations                         13
4.1       Value chains                                                            13
4.1.1     Value chain differentiation                                             13
4.1.2     Value chain and territory                                               17
4.1.3     Value chains and markets                                                19
4.2       Making markets work                                                     20
4.2.1     M4P and P4M                                                             23
4.2.2     Understanding market failure                                            24
4.3       Who are “the poor”?                                                     25


5         How to link M4P and VC analysis: Practical considerations               27
5.1       Analysis before action                                                  27
5.2       Action research                                                         29
5.2.1     Selecting a target group for a pro-poor value chain promotion project   30
5.2.2     Launching a pro-poor value chain promotion project                      31


6         Conclusion                                                              36


7         Bibliography                                                            37
III




Figures

Figure 1: The market concept of the M4P literature .................................................................3

Figure 2: Simplified structure of the pepper and cloves value chains in Sri
     Lanka..............................................................................................................................14

Figure 3: Structure of the pepper value chain in Sri Lanka ....................................................15

Figure 4: Downstream part of the cinnamon value chain in Sri Lanka ...................................16

Figure 5: The Commodity Chain of the Knitwear Industry in Santa Catarina,
     Brazil ..............................................................................................................................17

Figure 6: The Cluster and the Value Chain perspective.........................................................18

Figure 7: The 2 Pillars of Value Chain Promotion ..................................................................19

Figure 8: The Context of Poverty and Micro-Enterprise Development...................................26

Figure 9: The USAID approach to value chain promotion......................................................28

Figure 10: The spiral model of sequencing in the EU LEADER programme..........................30

Figure 11: Initial Sequence for a Pro-Poor Value Chain Initiative ..........................................32

Figure 12 ................................................................................................................................35
Summary

The main concern in development cooperation today is to achieve a bigger impact on poverty
alleviation. This refers to all arenas, including private sector development. The conceptual
discussion on private sector development has recently addressed the question of how to
create an enabling environment and make markets work, and in particular make markets
work better for the poor. At the same time, practical activities in private sector development
are addressing value chains, something that reflects realities of private companies that are
constantly battling to find markets for their products, and access to markets is often organ-
ised through value chains.

At first glance, the “Making Market Systems Work Better for the Poor” approach (M4P) and
the value chain approach appear to be incompatible. However, a closer look reveals that the
M4P literature paints a differentiated picture of markets, which is informed by the analysis of
real markets, particularly rural markets. It stands for a pragmatic approach that can give im-
portant inputs for conceptual development for value chain approaches. At the same time, it is
important not to merge the M4P and the value chain approaches, since this would compro-
mise many of their respective strengths.

Value chain projects sometimes spend a lot of time and effort on research before going into
practical activities. We suggest that there is little point in introducing M4P into a research-
focused approach to value chain development, since this might lead to enormously complex,
resource-intensive and lengthy research projects. Instead, we suggest a process-oriented
approach to value chain development that involves strong elements of action research. We
suggest that there is a good opportunity to introduce M4P elements into such an approach.



Acknowledgements

This paper has benefit tremendously from the discussions at a workshop in Hanoi in Novem-
ber 2006. We greatfully acknowledge the comments and suggestions made by Alan Johnson
and Dominic Smith (ADB/DFID M4P project), Kees van der Ree, Bas Rozemuller and Marije
Boomsma (ILO), Michael van den Berg (SNV), Ellen Kramer and Khan Nha (GTZ Poverty
Reduction project), and Thomas Finkel, Angelika Hutter, Vu Nhu Quynh and Pham Ngoc
Tram (GTZ SME project). Useful comments on earlier draft versions were given by Sabine
Becker, Shawn Cunningham, Doug Hindson and Peter Richter. The usual disclaimers apply.
1    Purpose of this paper

The initial intention behind this paper was to verify whether it makes sense to
connect the literature on value chain analysis and the literature on “Making mar-
ket systems work better for the poor” (M4P) in order to develop an analytical in-
strument that makes value chain promotion more pro-poor. In the course of the
work it became clear that the M4P concept is work in progress. Thus, this paper
turned out to be a contribution to the evolving conceptualisation of M4P as well. A
draft version of the paper was finished in the first semester of 2006. The concept
outlined in that paper was discussed with M4P and value chain practitioners in a
workshop in Hanoi in November 2006. An M4P-informed value chain analysis
was conducted in December 2006 in Vietnam’s Dak Lak province through the
Vietnamese-German project “Support for Poverty Reduction” which is managed
by the Ministry of Labour, Invalids and Social Affairs (MOLISA) and GTZ.

The paper is organised as follows. Section 2 gives a brief introduction to the two
concepts, and Section 3 has a closer look at them. In Section 4, we discuss con-
ceptual issues involved in the connection between value chain analysis and
making market systems work better for the poor. In Section 5, we outline a practi-
cal approache to analyse value chains in an action-oriented way that is informed
by both approaches.




2    “Making market systems work better for the poor” and “Value Chain
     Promotion”: What is it about?

The starting point of this paper are two lines of conceptualisation and develop-
ment practice that have recently started to converge: “Making market systems
work better for the poor (M4P)” and “Value Chain Promotion” (VCP). Both ap-
proaches address the issue of private sector development, including promotion of
small producers in rural areas, from specific angles and against specific patterns
of conceptual evolution.

M4P has evolved from the BDS discussion of the late 1990s. The BDS discus-
sion was based on the observation that the established donor approach for pri-
vate sector development was not particularly effective. One of the main deficien-
cies was the fact that it ignored existing business service markets, and indeed
often created unfair competition to existing service providers through subsidised
governmental business promotion programmes and organisations. The traditional
approach to business development was a typical example of the donor approach
analysed by Pritchett and Woolcock: “need as the problem, supply as the solu-
tion, civil service as the instrument” (Pritchett and Woolcock 2004, 193). With the
BDS approach, the pendulum swung to the other extreme, emphasising the need
2                                              Jörg Meyer-Stamer and Frank Wältring




for market development yet not clearly defining the role of government in this
process. Today, “BDS market development terminology is fading in favor of vo-
cabulary that explains how market development can help the poor benefit from
economic growth. What was understood as BDS markets are increasingly called
business service markets, commercially viable solutions, or support markets”
(Miehlbradt and McVay 2005, 2). M4P shares with BDS the emphasis on market
development, but it has at the same time a wider and a less clearly defined
scope.

VCP has in recent years evolved from the subsector approach. To some extent it
was driven by practitioners’ insight in the need to connect producers to the mar-
ket, and indeed understanding and verifying the target market before engaging in
upgrading activities with producers and manufacturers. To some extent it is in-
formed by the academic literature on global value chains, i.e. dense networks
that often involve retailers and other big corporations in industrialised countries
and a huge number of suppliers all over the world. The emergence of value
chains is primarily driven by the market. Development practitioners have ob-
served this process and spotted an opportunity. The value chain approach has
received a particularly strong impulse from the discussion on rural and agricul-
tural development, as decreasing transport and communication costs have
stimulated the emergence of value chains that connect producers of fresh fruit
and vegetables, processors and packaging houses in developing countries, and
supermarkets in industrialised countries. Research showed that poor smallhold-
ers can in principle be integrated into such value chains, thus raising the expec-
tation that value chain promotion can have a direct pro-poor effect (Dolan, Hum-
phrey and Harris-Pascal 1999).

At first glance, the rationale for connecting these two approaches may not appear
particularly convincing. First, there seems to be an intrinsic problem with the M4P
approach. Markets are about allocation, not about distribution. While “making
market systems work better” is a plausible proposition, “... for the poor” appar-
ently is not. The M4P literature overcomes this problem by looking at market
systems, i.e. the interaction between markets and other forms of allocation, nota-
bly hierarchy (i.e. through government interventions or by the activities of major
corporations). Moreover, the “better” is not to be understood in the sense of
“better for the poor than for everybody else” but rather in the sense of “better than
so far”. The M4P literature points out that markets are often rigged in a way that
benefits only a small group of already well-off, and that levelling the playing field
creates new opportunities for the not-so-rich.

Second, value chains are not primarily about markets. The literature on global
value chains has pointed out that the main reason why such chains exist is the
fact that the market rarely works properly. Transactions in global value chains
tend to be complex, information can only partially be codified, and suppliers will
often face limitations with respect to their capacity to respond to the requirements
of global buyers (Gereffi, Humphrey and Sturgeon 2005). In other words, global
value chains as relatively stable, coherent structures exist because they are su-
perior to anonymous markets. However, from a development policy angle, global
Linking Value Chain Promotion and the M4P Concept                                      3




value chains still look much more like market arrangements than like anything
else, and when it comes to promoting value chains one would try to rely on mar-
ket adjustment as much as possible.




3     Concepts and methodologies


3.1    M4P

The M4P approach has been promoted in particular by DFID, SIDA and the Asian
Development Bank. With the M4P approach, they aspire to make their private
sector development approach more pro-poor, thus aligning it with the Millenium
Development Goals.

The market concept of the M4P literature is summarised in the following figure.

Figure 1: The market concept of the M4P literature




                               Source: Presentation given by Marshall Bear, November 2005

What this figure tries to depict is the fact that the functioning of markets depends
on two sets of factors. Intangible factors (lower semicircle) include formal and in-
formal rules. Tangible factors include infrastructure and other services (upper
4                                                  Jörg Meyer-Stamer and Frank Wältring




semicircle). Both tangible and intangible factors are shaped by government, the
private sector and its organisations, the third sector, and informal networks (outer
circle).

A specific element of M4P in this respect is the focus on institutions. What is
meant by this? Let us quote the explanation given by Ferrand, Gibson and Scott
(2004, 14 f):

“What are the most important formal rules impinging on the market and the poor?
How do they impact on the market?
These include:
    Generally applicable rules such as contract, property, consumer protection, weights
    and measures, health and safety, competition and tax laws. These are not market-
    specific but may be most important in shaping markets.
    Sector-specific rules such as banking law, electricity and telecommunications acts
    and land use and ownership laws.
    Non-statutory regulations such as industry codes of good conduct, quality standards
    and registers.
What (and who) are the most important formal mechanisms for enforcement of
rules? How do they impact on the market?
This includes, for example, commercial justice institutions, government systems of regu-
lation, inspection and licensing, inland revenue authorities, company and land registries,
industry regulators, local government tax offices, and self-regulation mechanisms in busi-
ness associations.
What are the most important informal institutions impinging on the market? How
do they impact on the market?
The actual way in which rules are interpreted and applied is often shaped more by social
norms and practices as much as the letter of the law. Where formal rules and their appli-
cation are weak, the business environment is governed by the informal. For example, the
general impracticality of commercial and contract law often means that business transac-
tions become focused within established networks. In Africa, it is recognised widely that
existing networks and trust – arising from particular conditions – is a key hindrance to
trading and to collaborative business arrangements. While in Asia many networks of
small business have developed – to permit flexible production specialisation – in Africa
this is less common. Overall, when the formal rules surrounding markets are weak and
informal institutions are not supportive of business transactions, the environment for mar-
kets is significantly dysfunctional.”

In a development policy perspective, the M4P approach effectively distinguishes
three intervention levels (e.g. DFID 2005):

1. The micro level, where the focus is at creating functioning markets and effec-
   tive BDS structures.

2. The meso level, which, though it remains conceptually somewhat fuzzy, con-
   sists of para-governmental structures that are funded by external donors and
   that substitute defunct or ineffective national government structures in devel-
   oping countries.
Linking Value Chain Promotion and the M4P Concept                                  5




3. The macro level of generic framework conditions, in particular the legal
   framework and the rules and regulation that guide its delivery.

The argument of the M4P concept can be summarised in two points:

   Development-oriented interventions need to create effective markets, rather
   than distorting or substituting them in the way traditional donor interventions
   often did. This point takes the key insight of the BDS approach as its point of
   departure and applies it in a more comprehensive manner.

   Those market adjustment activities must be prioritised that have a strong pro-
   poor effect. The M4P approach emphasises the need for systematic research
   in this respect.

The first argument is close to the one made by Meyer-Stamer (2001, 23) who ar-
gues that a significant part of meso-level interventions is temporary in nature and
needs to be designed in a way that does not compromise the phasing-out of in-
terventions as a given market begins to work effectively. The M4P approach ne-
glects the corollary emphasised by Meyer-Stamer, namely that some meso-level
interventions are permanent in nature since the market will never take care of
them; typical examples include, for instance, some activities in the field of quality
assurance, certification, testing and calibration.

In the body of literature on M4P, Dorward and Kydd (2005, 16 ff) relate to this line
of reasoning. They observe that it can be entirely unrealistic, and indeed self-
defeating, to take the principle of making markets work too far. They highlight the
fact that highly fragmented markets can lead to prohibitively high transaction
costs while at the same time creating barriers to entry that reinforce critical bot-
tlenecks. One of the examples they provide is “asset specificity”. If an entrepre-
neur buys a truck to transport mangoes, but it turns out that there are not many
mangoes to be transported, she can still use the truck to transport, say, bricks.
But if an entrepreneur invests in a highly specialised canning operation for man-
goes, the absence of mangoes creates a serious problem. Therefore, in a com-
petitive market with high information cost and little direct communication between
market participants, entrepreneurs may hesitate to invest into anything that dis-
plays a high asset specificity. Dorward and Kydd present hierarchies, be they
government institutions or private sector organisations, as a necessary comple-
ment to markets. The way they conceptualise hierarchies, for instance as corpo-
rations that organise various stages in a value chain or organise outgrower op-
erations, relates to the literature on value chains, though they do not make this
connection explicit.

The M4P approach emphasises the need for analysis. According to DFID (2005,
19), “the M4P approach will draw upon the following types of data:

   Poverty reports including household surveys and PPA surveys.

   Specific market and transactions studies using participatory and other tech-
   niques to complement existing poverty data.
6                                              Jörg Meyer-Stamer and Frank Wältring




    ‘Doing Business’ and Investment Climate Surveys.

    Trade, production and price data.

    Market outcomes and data from the operation of value chains.

    The rate and direction of the evolution of key markets for the poor, especially
    the:

    –   process of market deepening and the expansion of the access frontier;

    –   crossing of key thresholds for participation, outreach, choice, economies
        of scale and sustainability; and

    –   effects of cross market linkages.”

In other words, the M4P approach involves a rather comprehensive effort in con-
ducting studies, more comprehensive indeed than the already quite comprehen-
sive “BDS market assessments” of the recent past.


3.1.1     Weaknesses of the M4P approach

The M4P approach is still at an early stage of conceptual development, and it is
still searching answers to important conceptual as well as practical issues.



Conceptual weaknesses: The market

The key issue in the concept, the market, remains fuzzy. From an economics
perspective, the different types of market failure and the reasons for their exis-
tence are not discussed in a systematic way. Similar to the BDS approach, mar-
kets are discussed in an inductive way, and the analysis of markets is informed
by concepts from a business administration perspective, not a microeconomics
perspective. The M4P discussion may have something to learn from the discus-
sion on privatisation in this respect; for instance, Brücker and Hillebrand (1996)
offer an excellent overview of market failure and options in addressing it. From a
social science perspective, the issue of “embeddedness” of markets (Granovetter
1992) in social structures is something that should be elaborated much stronger
and more consistently in the M4P literature (see also Platteau 1994).



Conceptual weaknesses: The poor

The M4P literature is somewhat blurred when it comes to “the poor”. It neither in-
troduces different levels of poverty, from relative income poverty to absolute des-
titution, nor does it explicitly explain whether it is based on a static or dynamic
concept of poverty. In fact, it avoids one of the prominent concepts in poverty re-
Linking Value Chain Promotion and the M4P Concept                                7




search, namely exclusion. This is somewhat puzzling since “making markets
work for the poor” can to some extent be translated into “integrating poor into
markets”, i.e. taking direct action to address exclusion.



Conceptual weaknesses: Government

In the way it is summarised in the most recent concept paper (DFID 2005), the
M4P concept fails to address the issue of sustainability of intervention vehicles /
structures for market alignment. It establishes high requirements on the effective-
ness of government structures, yet delivers no visible contribution to strengthen-
ing government structures. In fact, existing government structures in partner
countries are effectively sidelined with programmes like ComMark in Southern Af-
rica. In Nigeria, PrOpCom acts like any meso-institution anywhere that has de-
cided to build a powerful value chain on the basis of currently weak, fragmented
structures, very similar to what, say, Scottish Enterprise has done since 1999 in
its “Scottish Food & Drink” initiative, except that at some stage PrOpCom will
terminate, while new types of market failure will continue to emerge.



Practical issues

While emphasising the relevance of market failure and the need for market ad-
justment tools, the M4P literature so far does not provide any tools that would
permit efficient analysis of market failure. A development practitioner who needs
to prepare Terms of Reference for a consultant who is supposed to analyse mar-
ket failure is pretty much left to her own devices. The M4P literature names some
types of market failure, such as public goods and externalities, market power and
economies of scale, asymmetric information, and costs of establishing and en-
forcing agreements (DFID 2005, 6). However, we have not been able to locate a
toolkit that would guide practitioners in identifying market failure, understanding
the underlying reasons, and finding efficient and sustainable means of address-
ing it.


3.2    Value Chains

Both academic research and development practitioners have for a number of
years been addressing “value chains”. A value chain is the sequence of activities
involved in transforming raw materials into a product that is acquired by the final
customer. It includes business activities from the generation of raw materials, to
transforming them into intermediate products, to manufacturing the final product.
It includes business transactions, but also transactions between companies and
governments (e.g. the bureaucracy involved in transborder trade), and transac-
tions between companies and supporting institutions in areas like finance, train-
ing, research and development, metrology and certification, and others.
8                                              Jörg Meyer-Stamer and Frank Wältring




A value chain can be relatively straightforward, for instance in the case of the or-
ganic vegetable value chain, where rural producers, intermediates and proces-
sors / packaging houses, and wholesalers and retailers are involved. A value
chain can be extremely complex, for instance in the case of a passenger car or a
personal computer, or in fact in footwear or garments, where producers in various
countries across the globe interact.

Value chains exist at the subnational regional level, the national level, and the
global level. In subnational regions, value chains are difficult to distinguish from
“clusters”; in fact, some development agencies use the terms “cluster” and “value
chain” interchangeably. Most of the academic literature on value chains ad-
dresses them at the global level.

How are value chains different from supply chains? They are not. What is differ-
ent is the angle of analysis. The supply chain literature is rooted in industrial en-
gineering faculties and business schools. The guiding question of the supply
chain literature is: How can a company manage its supply chain more efficiently,
and create a competitive advantage through unique and more efficient supply
chain management? Examples for best practice in supply chain management in-
clude retailers like Wal-Mart and Ikea, who are not only capable of spotting low-
price / good quality producers across the globe but also highly skilled in organis-
ing the logistics along their value chain in such a way that cost efficiency is high,
lead times are short, and working capital requirements are low.

The value chain literature is rooted in development studies and sociology. It
started from the observation that agricultural and industrial development proc-
esses in developing countries increasingly are based on interaction with lead
firms in industrialised countries. The concern of this body of literature is not with
the efficiency of lead firms such as Wal-Mart or Ikea but rather with the develop-
ment prospects of companies that are dependent on Wal-Mart or Ikea for their
export sales, and that are thus integrated into the global economy in a dependent
way. The main focus is at the analysis of power structures in the world economy.


3.2.1    Types of value chains

The current state of research on value chains (in particular global value chains,
but its findings to a large extent apply to national-level value chains as well) dis-
tinguishes four types of value chains (Schmitz 2005, 6):

1. “Arm’s length market relations. Buyer and supplier do not need to develop
   close relationships because the product is standardised or easily customised.
   A range of firms can meet the buyer's requirements. When problems arise
   buyers move on to different suppliers.

2. Modular networks. Firms develop information-intensive relationships, divid-
   ing essential competences between them. The buyer provides the design and
   product specification and highly competent suppliers provide products and
Linking Value Chain Promotion and the M4P Concept                                9




   services at short notice to any kind of specification drawing on the specialisa-
   tions in their cluster. Information intensity is high, transactional dependence
   is low, and confidence in supplier competence is high.

3. Captive networks. In this case, one firm exercises a high degree of control
   over other firms in the chain. In garment and footwear chains, buyers often
   specify the characteristics of the product to be made by their suppliers, spec-
   ify the processes to be followed and inspect that these specifications are fol-
   lowed. Typically this occurs when the buyer has doubts about the compe-
   tence of the supply chain.

4. Hierarchy. The lead firm takes direct ownership of some operations in the
   chain. The case of the intra-firm trade between a trans-national company and
   its subsidiaries falls into this category.”

Recent research on global value chains has primarily looked at Type 2 and Type
3 value chains, i.e. value chains that are neither market based nor organised
within a multinational firm. Such value chains exist because the market does not
work (market failure) and an intra-firm setup would involve prohibitive transaction
costs and constant problems with principal-agent issues. Let us look at these two
issues in some more detail:

   Market failure: What is traded in global value chains are non-commodity
   products, i.e. products that are produced according to specific parameters.
   Some of these parameters are specifically defined by the buyer, for instance
   designs. A key issue here is that the buyer cannot fully codify its requirements
   but needs ongoing communication with the supplier to explain what exactly is
   wanted. Other parameters are features such as quality criteria, compliance
   with environmental or social standards, and others. So far, experience has
   shown that international standards such as ISO 9000, ISO 14000, and SA
   8000 cannot guarantee that suppliers meet the requirements of buyers, so
   that buyers tend to prefer direct interaction and control.

   Hierarchy, transaction cost, principal-agent problems: Over the past two dec-
   ades, there has been a strong tendency away from the Chandlerian model of
   company evolution, i.e. major integrated corporations, since experience
   showed that a model of a company that focused at its core competencies and
   outsourced many non-core activities was more efficient. This was due to
   lower transaction costs in coordinating inter-company relationships, some-
   thing that was more efficient that one integrated company with a bloated in-
   ternal bureaucracy, as well as the absence of the principal-agent issues
   common in big, spatially scattered corporate organisations.


3.2.2    Value chains and donor interventions

The value chain issue has been taken up be donor agencies, which perceive
them both as a risk and an opportunity. The risk lies in the fact that developing
10                                              Jörg Meyer-Stamer and Frank Wältring




country producers cannot be integrated into global markets if they cannot meet
the requirements of value chains lead firms regarding cost, quality, certification,
quantity, and timely delivery. The chance lies in the fact that connecting devel-
oping country producers to the world market can be easier if the donor agency
manages to build a direct relationship with a value chain lead firm.

In fact, donors recently have started to work directly with value chains, i.e. by en-
gaging with the lead firms / global buyers, for instance in a number of GTZ-
managed public-private partnership projects. To some extent, this was driven by
a combination of global buyer’s concern with corporate social responsibility (in
particular the desire not to appear as culprits for miserably labour conditions in
sweat shops, or being linked to child labour) and donor organisations’ concern to
improve the productivity levels in companies that are part of value chains so that
they reap greater benefits, including higher wages and better working conditions.

Various donor organisations have formulated approaches for value chain analy-
sis. While having some features in common, existing approaches to value chain
analysis demonstrate a number of specific differences. They are summarised in
the table in Annex 1. Identifying the similarities and differences within existing
value chain analysis approaches does not become obvious by casting a quick
glance. Many of them are integrated into wider market or demand assessments
or integrated into LRED, BDS, Enabling Environment, PPP, BDS or cluster de-
velopment activities.



Similarities in the approaches
There are certain similarities among the different value chain analysis ap-
proaches:

     Most of the approaches combine the analysis of the chain with the analysis of
     interventions.

     The sequence of an analysis usually includes the following steps: identifica-
     tion of the subsector, analysis of the chain linkages, analysis of the market,
     analysis of potentials, analysis of constraints, analysis of solutions, analysis
     of interventions.

     Nearly all of the approaches apply criteria that in general are including in-
     crease of competitiveness, employment effects and sustainability.

     There is a tendency especially in approaches of donors to integrate partici-
     patory elements and to use the value chain analysis also to identify potential
     partner organisations or lead firms. Often activities that have started at the
     governmental level include very study- and less participatory-based ap-
     proaches, e.g. to design a national export strategy.

     There is a trend towards incremental analysis approaches, often based on
     larger baseline studies.
Linking Value Chain Promotion and the M4P Concept                                 11




Differences in donor approaches
There are differences with respect to engaging the stakeholders and the target
group, in the way of planning interventions, with regard to the time sequence of
analysis and intervention and in the combination of value chain analysis with
other approaches. Regarding the latter point, it is common to find mixed ap-
proaches that combine and complement value chain analysis with other devel-
opment approaches (Cluster, value chains, PPP, LED, investment promotion,
OD, EE, BDS). Examples are many GTZ projects but also other donor organisa-
tions that follow a systemic approach which goes beyond the focus on interfirm-
linkages and BDS and that analyse interventions in a more integrated cross-
cutting form (e.g. Vietnam, Sri Lanka). Regarding planning and sequencing, there
are two fundamentally different types of approaches:

   Incremental approaches that analyse parts of the chain on a continuous base
   to identify further opportunities for donor intervention. Many projects that
   started with large studies subsequently focused on more specific sub-areas
   (e.g. AfE in Bangladesh with the KATALYST project). Other approaches start
   already with participatory research that involves different stakeholders
   through workshops and interviews (stakeholders usually come from the pol-
   icy, social and economic sphere) with the objective to initiate an iterative pro-
   cess of planning / implementing / assessing / planning.

   Planning approaches that follow a step-by-step procedure from information
   gathering, sub-sector selection, identification of constraints, identification of
   intervention approaches towards planning and implementing interventions.
   These approaches often take longer until they reach implementation. They
   often also do not include the stakeholders in the final planning process of in-
   terventions (AfE, IDE, …).

Finally, it is noteworthy that while all approaches focus at the need to increase
competitiveness, some are primarily looking at livelihood improvement (e.g. IDE).


3.2.3    Weaknesses of the value chain approach

The academic value chain literature addresses global value chains. It typically
looks at products that are produced in developing countries and consumed in in-
dustrialised countries, from Kenyan fresh vegetables to Mexican blue jeans to
Taiwanese computers. It analyses producers in developing countries that are al-
ready highly competitive; the fact that they are able to consistently satisfy the so-
phisticated demand of leading companies in industrialised countries bears wit-
ness of this. However, only occasionally does the value chain literature trace the
evolution of producers in developing countries and the stages that preceded their
integration into global value chains. The exact mechanisms of how producers in
developing countries become integrated into global value chains are not at all
clear. What exactly happens before producers appear on the radar screen of
global buyers, how first contact is established and how the initial interaction goes
is not well understood. In this respect, the literature is only of limited value to
12                                             Jörg Meyer-Stamer and Frank Wältring




practitioners who want to upgrade producers in developing countries so that they
appear on the radar screen of global buyers.

In the practitioner literature, there appears to be a tendency to ignore the differ-
ences between Taiwanese computer manufacturers and, say, Guatemalan
handicraft producers. There seems to be an assumption that pretty much any
producer anywhere can in principle be integrated into global value chains. This is
a repetition of a misunderstanding that came up in the discussion on cluster de-
velopment and promotion some years ago, where we have shown that concepts
that have been developed in settings with highly competitive industries cannot
easily be transferred to survivalist sectors (Altenburg and Meyer-Stamer 1999).


3.3    Interim conclusion

Value chain promotion is concerned with competitiveness of producers. It aims at
connecting producers in developing countries with markets, be it nationally or
globally. Value chain promotion, as conducted by donor agencies, is implicitly
pro-poor in that it focuses at groups of producers who will not spontaneously link
up with external buyers because of too wide a gap between their supply capacity
and the demands of buyers, which may be a result of insufficient skills, an unfa-
vourable, peripheral location, a disabling environment, or other factors.

The M4P approach is concerned with market adjustment. It is explicitly pro-poor.
It aims at improving the effectiveness of market mechanisms, so that barriers to
entry are lowered and more economic opportunities are created. Moreover, more
effective markets are expected to lead to lower prices and thus an increase in the
effective purchasing power of poor.

VCP and M4P look at development challenges from different angles. One might
expect M4P to be very generic (though the examples mentioned in the M4P lit-
erature are not), and VCP to be highly specific. However, M4P does not only look
at market adjustment from a macro-economic perspective, in the way the “ena-
bling environment” approach does. It also addresses the micro- and mesolevels.
From this angle, one can argue that VCP and M4P are complementary and can
be connected.

One element that must be highlighted is the fact that the M4P literature explicitly
addresses different markets – not only product markets, but also factor markets,
for instance the labour market. This is an element that only appears in an indirect,
implicit way in the value chain literature and practice. The labour market is un-
doubtedly one of the most important markets in terms of making the economy
more pro-poor. Distortions in the labour market are one of the most important
reasons for persistent marginalisation and poverty (Granovetter 2005), not only in
developing countries but also, for instance, in the U.S. (Rosenfeld 2002). Ad-
dressing the labour market, as well as other factors markets, in VCP in a consis-
tent and systematic way may be a promising way of making it more pro-poor.
Linking Value Chain Promotion and the M4P Concept                                     13




So the conclusion is this: M4P can inform VC work, but the two should not be
merged. M4P and VC overlap. M4P covers issues like labour markets, which are
not systematically addressed in VC. VC has an explicit focus at supranational is-
sues, which are beyond the scope of M4P.




4       How to link M4P + VC: Conceptual considerations

In this section we will highlight a number of issues that so far are not adequately
addressed in the M4P and the VCP literature. We will indicate a number of con-
cepts and strands of academic discussion that may help in creating a sounder
foundation for both approaches.


4.1       Value chains

4.1.1      Value chain differentiation

The “value chain” metaphor is valuable in more than one sense. Not only is a
chain a relatively flexible structure that will change its form frequently without
changing the basic structure. There is also one physical feature of a chain: It is
impossible to move it by pushing it. The only way to move a chain is by pulling.

Translating this metaphor takes us to the main difference between VCP and tra-
ditional approaches. The latter often had a tendency to strengthen the supply ca-
pacity of producers and small companies without having a confirmed order, i.e.
they assumed that a market would be available, which sometimes was the case
and often not. VCP starts from an understanding of the final demand and works
its way back through distribution channels to the different stages of production
and manufacturing. That is, proper VCP does this. There are also VCP interven-
tions which effectively are re-labelled sector activities, sometimes based on a
terminological and conceptual confusion around the terms sector, subsector and
value chain:

      Among development practitioners, sectors are commonly understood along
      the lines of the International Standard Industry Classification, i.e. the food
      sector, the metalworking sector, the textile sector, etc. It is also not rare to
      find that, for instance, microenterprises are addressed as a sector, and “in-
      formal sector” is a firmly established term that indicates yet a different ap-
      proach to classification. The different sector definitions reflect different inter-
      ests. The ISIC classification is guided by the interest of statistical offices to
      organise the complex reality of an economy in a way that is practical for data
      collection and presentation. The microenterprise definition is guided by the
      interests of policy makers who perceive a type of enterprise to be systemati-
      cally disadvantaged and who need criteria to define those businesses that will
      benefit, for instance, from simplified tax payments. The informal sector defini-
      tion was originally driven by the interest to highlight dismal working conditions
14                                              Jörg Meyer-Stamer and Frank Wältring




     in a particular type of business. None of these definitions makes much sense
     in the context of targeted business promotion activities, though.

     Subsectors have been defined as “all the firms that buy and sell from each
     other in order to supply a particular set of products or services to final con-
     sumers” (Lusby and Panlibuton 2002, iv). This definition is somewhere in
     between the sector terminology and the value chain concept. At first glance, it
     appears to be quite similar to the value chain definition. Unlike the value
     chain, though, it does not define economic activities from the perspective of
     the final consumer, and this establishes a crucial difference between “sub-
     sector” and “value chain”.

From a practitioner’s perspective, proper VCP, based on a genuine effort to un-
derstand the structure of a value chain starting at the final customer, has a big
disadvantage. It tends to involve a hugely complex system that is very difficult to
address for any practical purposes. This is not a new discovery. Long before the
term “value chain” in the way it is used in this paper was coined, when research-
ers were still talking about “networks”, they detected that one “sector” in one re-
gion can involve a variety of different structures that are only loosely interrelated.
Silicon Valley, for instance, is not one value chain but actually several, each with
different final customers, internal structures and challenges regarding upgrading
(Storper and Harrison 1991).

At first glance, a value chain appears to be a very straightforward affair. Simpli-
fied value chain maps usually look like the one depicted in Figure 2.

Figure 2: Simplified structure of the pepper and cloves value chains in Sri
Lanka




This figure is taken from a presentation on the experiences of a GTZ VCP project
in Sri Lanka. A more detailed, yet still simplified map of the pepper value chain
looks as depicted in Figure 3. This and the following figure have been elaborated
in stakeholder workshops of the GTZ Value Chain Project in Sri Lanka.
Linking Value Chain Promotion and the M4P Concept            15




Figure 3: Structure of the pepper value chain in Sri Lanka
16                                                Jörg Meyer-Stamer and Frank Wältring




This is still a relative straightforward picture, which is mostly due to the fact that
the distribution channels and final customers of Sri Lankan pepper are not par-
ticularly diversified. Things look quite different for the cinnamon value chain,
which serves quite different final customers.

Figure 4: Downstream part of the cinnamon value chain in Sri Lanka




Cinnamon is not only used as a kitchen spice. It is also an input for the pharma-
ceutical and fragrance industries. So far, Sri Lankan producers have not really
tapped into these markets. But as they will develop a capacity to establish link-
ages with such customers, the map of the Sri Lankan cinnamon value chain will
become significantly more complex, since different needs and demands of final
customers will lead to a segmentation of value chains inside Sri Lanka (which are
not captured in Figure 4).

Similarly, research that we conducted in Brazil in the second half of the 1990s on
a textiles and garments value chain in the Vale do Itajaí region showed a picture
of four distinct patterns of industrial organisation, feeding into five different distri-
bution channels. At first glance, one might have expected one value chain. How-
ever, the reality is much more complex. This has important consequences for any
Linking Value Chain Promotion and the M4P Concept                                 17




effort in upgrading, since different segments of the industry have quite different
requirements. In other words, in order to upgrade the textile and garments sector
in this region, one would have to launch not one but several value chain initia-
tives, each of them addressing one specific value chain. Most companies would
only be part of one value chain initiatives, while other players, such as skills de-
velopment or technology institutions, might have to be involved in four or five
value chain initiatives at the same time.

Figure 5: The Commodity Chain of the Knitwear Industry in Santa Catarina,
Brazil




                                                            Source: Meyer-Stamer 1998

What is the conclusion from this line of argument? Value chains tend to be highly
complex systems. An effort to analyse them in a systematic way will thus tend to
involve a very significant research effort. It is important to note that not only the
purpose but also the scope of VCP-related research would be different from a
typical academic GVC research project. GVC research focuses at the issue of
power imbalances in the international economy. It often takes individual retailers,
or narrowly defined final customers, as its starting point. A VCP project cannot
afford this kind of focused perspective but rather has to take a much broader
look. A GVC researcher would be satisfied with a paper that investigates the
connections between French fragrance manufacturers and Sri Lankan cinnamon
producers. For somebody who is supposed to do spice value chain promotion in
Sri Lanka, this would only be one piece of a much bigger puzzle. In other words,
value chain initiatives need to be managed carefully so that they don’t get out of
hand.


4.1.2    Value chain and territory

Value chains do not per se have a territorial dimension. Obviously, each element
has a location. But the defining feature of the value chain is the pattern of con-
nection between various producers, services and customers. The following pic-
ture captures this aspect by comparing the value chain approach with the cluster
approach. Cluster promotion and value chain promotion are not profoundly differ-
18                                               Jörg Meyer-Stamer and Frank Wältring




ent in terms of the objectives and instruments. The main difference is the clear
territorial focus in cluster promotion, whereas VCP involves a functional focus.

Figure 6: The Cluster and the Value Chain perspective




                                                                     Source: own design

Nevertheless, practical experience seems to indicate that it makes sense to have
a closer look at the territorial dimension of VCP. The purpose of a VCP analysis
is to have a very clear idea regarding the upgrading necessities of local produc-
ers that for whatever reason have become the object of a donor project or a do-
mestic development initiative. The upgrading effort would not relate to some
anonymous market but rather the very specific demands of lead firms in a given
value chain. Integrating domestic firms into global value chains involves two dif-
ferent types of challenges. One of them is related to territorial issues; the other
one are national framework factors.

Regarding national-level factors, one of the issues that often comes up in VCP
projects are supply chain issues. Exports of fresh products are hampered by the
absence of cooling facilities at the main airport. Exports of all sorts of products
are hampered by clumsy and unpredictable procedures at ports. Exporters find it
difficult and/or very costly to have their products tested and certified. Communi-
cation between suppliers and customers suffers from slow and unreliable Internet
connections. Such issues are generic in nature. They need to be addressed at
the national level. They require direct interaction with national ministries, customs
authorities, metrology institutions, and other organisations. For instance, in the
case of the GTZ VCP project in Sri Lanka, one of the major obstacles for organic
vegetable exports was the fact that vegetables were routinely fumigated at the air
cargo facility of Colombo airport. Since a fumigated vegetable is no longer an or-
ganic vegetable, changing this routine was one of the major achievements of the
project.

At the same time, it is essential to work directly with producers. This is where the
territorial angle comes in. In any value chain, it is quite unlikely that producers are
Linking Value Chain Promotion and the M4P Concept                                         19




randomly scattered across the country. More likely, they will be concentrated in
certain locations – due to climatic and soil conditions (or coincidence) in agricul-
ture, due to cluster effects in industry and services. Thus, direct interaction with
producers has by nature a strong territorial focus.

As a consequence, it is recommendable to conceptualise VCP as an activity that
rests on two pillars, i.e. national level activities and activities at the territorial level,
at least under those circumstances where the topic of integration in global value
chains, or into sophisticated national value chains, is being addressed.

Figure 7: The 2 Pillars of Value Chain Promotion




                                                                         Source: own design.

Balancing both things in one programme or project is a challenge. One would
look at one programme with two components, a national-level component and a
territorial component. However, the management of such a programme can eas-
ily get out of hand, especially if it addresses several value chains and thus nu-
merous producer locations. A plausible alternative approach is one where a VCP
project comes in at the national level to bridge the gap between territorial initia-
tives and the external or national market. For instance, the experience of GTZ in
Sri Lanka indicated a win-win game, where the national level VCP project bene-
fited from another GTZ project with a territorial focus and vice versa (Richter
2005). At the same time, the VCP project could easily look for opportunities for
interaction with other projects by other donors (e.g. a USAID spice sector project
in a different part of the country, or an ILO SME promotion project in yet another
part of the country), something that would have been difficult if both projects had
been part of one strictly managed programme.


4.1.3     Value chains and markets

We have already pointed at the fact that value chains exist because real world
markets are quite different from the ideal markets of microeconomics textbooks.
This does not mean, though, that value chains are a substitute for markets. They
are rather a mixture of different modes of coordination, where network-type coor-
20                                             Jörg Meyer-Stamer and Frank Wältring




dination is a key element yet market coordination and coordination through hier-
archy also play an important role.

From the perspective of promotion activities, the existence of close network rela-
tionships between producers and customers is the point of departure. An analysis
of a given value chain will normally detect parts of the chain that are primarily
market-coordinated, and other parts that are primarily coordinated through hier-
archies. Typical examples of market coordination in a value chain are non-
strategic services or commodity inputs. Typical examples of hierarchical coordi-
nation are on the one hand outgrower systems which are coordinated by major
companies, on the other hand services offered by (typically government-run)
supporting institutions. An analysis of a value chain needs to understand which
types of transactions are predominantly coordinated through networks, markets,
or hierarchies, and to what extent one mode of coordinated might be substituted
through a different, ultimately more efficient mode.


4.2    Making markets work

One of the features of the M4P literature is its close connection to the BDS dis-
cussion and literature. Unfortunately, BDS has never enjoyed an understanding
of markets that was firmly rooted in microeconomics concepts. BDS, and espe-
cially BDS market assessments, are the world of A C Nielsen and Philip Kotler,
not the world of NBER and Joseph Stiglitz. Fortunately, the M4P literature also
draws on other arenas of discussion, such as rural development economics
which have developed insights into the functioning, and the frequent dysfunction-
alities, of markets (Dorward and Kydd 2005). What appears to be a really nice
market in the real world often turns out to be the opposite once closely scruti-
nised. Geertz (1992) has shown that bazaars are rather dysfunctional markets,
where price formation is extremely intransparent and thus the price mechanism,
the best feature the market has to offer, does not work properly. Dorward and
Kydd (2005) point out that atomised agricultural markets in African locations are
creating such high transaction cost that they are ultimately dysfunctional, too.

What is missing in the M4P literature are references to the widely accepted in-
sight that markets are one out of three forms of coordination, the other two being
hierarchies / organisations and networks / communities. While economics re-
search has formulated the market / hierarchy / network trias of modes of coordi-
nation (Powell 1990, OECD 1992), social scientists tend to distinguish market,
organisation and community (e.g. Wiesenthal 2000). What is important in both
strands of theorising is the observation that in the real world it is highly unlikely
that any pure mode of coordination will work. When a market does not work, the
adequate answer is, in all likelihood, not more market but rather more hierarchy /
organisation.

In fact, not only do the three types usually appear in some kind of combination,
but the functionality of each of the three usually depends on the other two. For
instance, a market only works when hierarchy is present (in the shape of gov-
Linking Value Chain Promotion and the M4P Concept                                21




ernment that creates an enabling environment, for instance by securing property
rights, and in the shape of companies that internalise processes with high trans-
action costs) and when networks exist (for instance business networks, which are
another device to minimise transaction costs). Nevertheless, in any given eco-
nomic setting, transactions tend to be quite obviously predominantly organised in
markets, in hierarchies, or in networks. Job placement is a typical example. Some
countries have a sector of for-profit private job placement agencies, i.e. a market
solution. In other countries, job placement is a government monopoly, i.e. a hier-
archy solution. Yet other countries have neither, and job placement is achieved
through informal communication among business people or within social groups,
i.e. a network solution.

What is the origin and conceptual background of the three types? Market vs hi-
erarchy has been the subject of the classic paper by Ronald Coase1 who asked:
Why are there companies? If markets are so efficient, why not organise every-
thing via markets, i.e. have only self-employed individuals? The answer is, es-
sentially, transaction cost. Organising, say, steel production purely via a market,
involving only self-employed individuals, would create significant transaction
costs. Organising it inside a company is the more efficient solution.

Coase had companies in mind when he used the term “hierarchy”. However, it is
common to use the term in a way that not only refers to companies, but also
other organisations, in particular government.

Networks have been conceptually introduced as a third mode of organisation by
Walter Powell (1990). He pointed out that networks are not something some-
where in between market and hierarchy but rather a distinctive mode of organisa-
tion. Networks refers to formal constellations, from strategic alliances to business
associations, as well as informal constellations, for instance the dense communi-
cation networks inside industrial clusters.

The important point to make is that there are no other ideal types, i.e. no other
ways of organising economic transactions. Any economic transaction is predomi-
nantly done in a market, in a hierarchy, or in a network.

How does the discussion on M4P relate to the concept of market, hierarchy and
network? The conceptual discussion and practical work on M4P has evolved
along three distinct trajectories. Three distinct schools of thought have emerged:

1. The market focus. This perspective is linked to the Commark project in
   Southern Africa.2 It is aligned with what Altenburg and Drachenfels (2005)
   have called “the new minimalist approach to private sector development”,
   where government is supposed to limit itself to creating an enabling environ-
   ment so that markets can work effectively and efficiently. This perspective
   has no proper conceptualisation of market failure, and of interventions neces-


1   “The nature of the firm”, 1937
2   Ferrand, Gibson and Scott 2004, Centre for Development and Enterprise 2006
22                                                Jörg Meyer-Stamer and Frank Wältring




     sary to remedy market failure. Markets are expected to work provided that the
     framework conditions are right, and they are supposed to be by far the most
     efficient mode of organising economic activities. The Commark documents
     are quite explicit about the fact that functioning markets are perfectly suffi-
     cient for a thriving economy, and that hierarchy as in selective government
     interventions is creating more damage than benefit. Networks do not figure in
     these documents.

2. The markets and hierarchies focus. This perspective is linked to the work of
   authors like Dorward, Kydd and others on behalf of DFID (Dorward and Kydd
   2005, Kydd et al 2004). It is based on insights from agricultural economics. It
   highlights that fact that it is not necessarily a good idea to rely on markets
   only, since what appears as a perfect market in theory can be a transaction
   cost nightmare in practice. Markets with lots of small suppliers and customers
   are a reality in rural Africa, yet they don’t work very well since it is time con-
   suming and thus costly for customers to get a comprehensive picture of the
   variety and quality of produce that is on offer; “... market exchange in Africa is
   generally ‘costly, cumbersome, time-consuming, and unpredictable’” (Dor-
   ward and Kydd 2005, 18, quoting Fafchamps 2004). Hierarchies, for instance
   outgrower systems that are managed by a major company, can turn out to be
   significantly more wealth creating than markets under such circumstances.

3. The markets, hierarchies and network focus. This perspective has emerged
   from the work of the ADB/DFID project in Vietnam which has over time
   broadened its focus.3 Regarding hierarchy, it addressed the issue of enabling
   environment, but it also looked at contract farming, i.e. hierarchy in the private
   sector. Regarding network, it addressed issues such as collective action.

Each of the three schools of thought has it upside and its downside.

     Market focus: The upside is the sharp focus. One downside that necessarily
     comes with the focus is the appearance of a one-sided market fundamentalist
     approach. Another downside of the existing literature is the superficial way in
     which it deals with market failure and possible ways to address market failure.

     Market and hierarchy focus: The upside is the more balanced perspective,
     since this perspective acknowledges the inherent limits of markets. The
     downside is the negligence of network as the third important mode of organi-
     sation.

     Market, hierarchy and network focus: The upside is the coverage of all three
     modes of organisation, i.e. a holistic perspective that does not a priori judge
     that one mode is better than the others. The downside is that this focus re-
     flects an evolutionary process from “Making Market Systems Work for the
     Poor” to “Making Everything Work for the Poor” which, from a practical per-
     spective, is a steep task.


3    See the papers available at http://www.markets4poor.org/
Linking Value Chain Promotion and the M4P Concept                                 23




4.2.1    M4P and P4M

Another important conclusion is that it actually can make sense to look at the way
markets work, and to address their dysfunctionalities and failures rather than take
them for granted. This is particularly relevant with respect to the poor. It is more
than just a play of words to point out that "making markets work for the poor" is
the opposite of "making poor work for the market". In the past, a common ap-
proach in poverty alleviation was to address the poor rather than the markets
they tried to interact in.

A typical example of "P4M" is skills development. The usual idea in skills devel-
opment is to upgrade the skills of individuals so that they fit with employers’ re-
quirements. Sometimes, this is complemented with "life skills" training in order to
enhance the employability of individuals. In other words, the structure and
mechanisms of the labour market are taken for granted. The focus is not at
changing the way the market works, but rather at making individuals fit for the
market.

Another example of "P4M" is the creation of collateral banks or other mecha-
nisms that create securities for potential creditors who cannot fulfil the banks'
usual requirements regarding collateral, and who thus do not have access to the
capital market. On the other hand, Microfinance is an approach that fits with
"M4P" principles. Support for microfinance is based on the insight that the con-
ventional capital market often does not work for small producers and poor house-
holds.

An interim conclusion would be that M4P and P4M are not alternatives but com-
plementary approaches. For instance, making the labour market work better for
the poor does not alleviate the need to raise the level of skills and the more gen-
eral employability of poor people.

It is, however, important not ignore an important dilemma in this respect. Limiting
the perspective to markets alone compromises the “for the poor” ambition, espe-
cially if one takes a closer look at the causes of poverty. Poor people are often
excluded, which takes us to a finding that appears tautological: Markets don’t
work for excluded groups because they are excluded. Markets are embedded in
networks and other societal structures, and poor often don’t benefit from markets
because they are marginalised by those structures. Exclusion is a process that is
embedded in and reinforced by social structures. Thus, it is important to ac-
knowledge that “making markets work for the poor” is not a simple, straightfor-
ward task where limited interventions in certain markets will do the trick. It rather
involves quite fundamental interventions into societal structures – another steep
task.
24                                               Jörg Meyer-Stamer and Frank Wältring




4.2.2     Understanding market failure

Given these challenges, it is important to remind oneself that a “making markets
work” approach has persuasive advantages. One of the most important ones is
the intrinsic quality of coordination through markets: Markets work because par-
ticipants pursue their self-interest. Hierarchies are facing all sorts of problems,
such as the principal-agent problem where the power centre is constantly battling
with the challenge of making sure that the agents who receive orders or missions
fulfil them in the way the principal wants them to. Networks are also facing all
sorts of problems, such as the problem of numbers where a network that involves
a significant number of players creates a huge coordination effort and cost. Mar-
kets are coordinated in a decentralised way. They don’t require a coordination
centre. Markets tend to emerge quite spontaneously – even in places where the
framework conditions are decidedly business unfriendly, such as Somalia (Ne-
nova and Harford 2004).

Moreover, the M4P approach goes beyond the “minimalist approach”. The mini-
malist approach tries to create favourable framework conditions and then expects
markets to do their miracle in a spontaneous way. The M4P approach acknowl-
edges that markets often won’t do that, and that in particular they will not benefit
or even exclude the poor. Thus, targeted interventions are necessary to make
sure that markets work, and to make sure that they work for the poor. The M4P
approach has so far generated a significant body of research studies that ana-
lysed markets and the way they worked, or didn’t work, for the poor. What is only
slowly emerging is a set of tools that can guide practitioners in their efforts to
make markets work.

It is thus a perfectly rational response to opt for a more limited approach, and
here one that relates back to the starting point of the M4P approach, namely the
intention to better understand markets, market failure, and practical ways to make
markets work better. In this respect, the M4P literature is only partially helpful
since it does not provide a systematic treatment of market failure, i.e. imperfec-
tions that keep real world markets from operating in the way assumed by simple
microeconomics models. The following table gives an overview of the main types
of market failure.

Market failure has three main consequences:

     It generates a low level equilibrium. The examples given in the table explain
     how market failure issues can reinforce each other and thus keep rural pro-
     ducers disconnected from markets. Income stays low, investment capacity is
     low, there is little if any innovation and upgrading, and producers remain
     mired in poverty.

     It generates suboptimal delivery of critical investment, for instance into skills
     development or research and development, thus reinforcing the competitive-
     ness gap that keeps producers and companies from upgrading so that they
     might connect with dynamic markets.
Linking Value Chain Promotion and the M4P Concept                                         25




Table 1: Types of market failure
Type of mar-     Example                         Consequence
ket failure
Natural          Telecommunications in ru-       Customers in rural areas pay much higher
monopoly         ral, thinly populated areas     price for telecom services than urban
                                                 customers, perhaps have no service at
                                                 all, and suffer from delays in access to in-
                                                 novative telecom services
External         Investment in skills devel-     Companies invest less in the skills devel-
effects          opment (positive external       opment of their staff that would be desir-
                 effect)                         able from a macro perspective
                 Building a cheap high chim-
                 ney instead of installing a
                                                 Contamination of region by industrial plant
                 filter (negative external ef-
                 fect)
Indivisibility   Size of a container (mini-     Small producers cannot connect to cus-
                 mum 39 cubic meters) that      tomers because the don’t produce
                 needs to be filled by supplier enough to fill a container
Asymmetric       Information about residual      Customers don’t buy fruit or vegetables if
information      toxics and other contami-       they suspect that producers have used
                 nants in fruit and vegetables   more agrochemicals than they admit
                 in the absence of sophisti-
                 cated and costly testing
                 equipment                     Producers who don’t trust the seller don’t
                                               buy high yield seeds if they look just like
                 Features of distinct products
                                               much cheaper normal seeds
                 that look alike
Public goods     Availability of sophisticated Producers can’t convince their customers
                 and costly testing equipment that the level of residual toxics is low, and
                 in a region with small pro-   thus can’t sell their products
                 ducers




      It creates barriers to entry, thus reinforcing monopolies and the high prices
      and service delivery shortcomings that come with monopolies.

Any effort to make market systems work for the poor must be based on a thor-
ough understanding of market failure, and not just on market research conducted
by A C Nielsen. Analyses must be conducted that investigate the root causes of
market failure, since only in this way is it possible to design interventions that go
beyond fumbling with the symptoms of market failure.


4.3        Who are “the poor”?

The M4P literature is somewhat fuzzy when it comes to defining who is meant by
“the poor”. Recent literature has pointed at a number of ways to get a differenti-
ated picture of poverty. Let us mention two.
26                                               Jörg Meyer-Stamer and Frank Wältring




1. Discussions in the SEEP network led to a typology of the poor that addresses
the question: To what extent are the poor likely to be producers that are active in
markets?

Figure 8: The Context of Poverty and Micro-Enterprise Development




                                                              Source: Eiligmann (2005), 8

This perspective looks at poor producers. The main argument is that the desti-
tute, i.e. the poorest of the poor, are unlikely to enter into markets as producers. It
is important to note, though, that in the M4P literature, the term “private sector”
does not only refer to businesses but actually to all economic actors that are not
public sector, i.e. all types of producers as well as workers. Nevertheless, the
SEEP typology is helpful since it points out that only a part of the poor, namely
those who are close to the poverty line, are likely to enter markets as producers.

2. Ravaillon (2004) points out that, even with a narrow concept of poverty, growth
will not automatically benefit the poor. It is crucial to address the geographical
and sectoral pattern of growth (ibid., 16). Poverty is often concentrated in specific
regions, in particular rural regions, and in one sector, namely agriculture.

This argument is developed in a more detailed way by Janvry and Sadoulet
(2004, 4 f.), based on evidence from Latin America:

“There is increasing differentiation between two types of locations for rural pov-
erty: MRA (marginal rural areas) and FRA (favorable rural areas).

Part of the rural poor are geographically concentrated in low population density
MRA (marginal rural areas) defined as areas with either poor agro-ecological en-
Linking Value Chain Promotion and the M4P Concept                                27




dowments and/or isolated from access to markets and employment centers.
These areas consist in:

      Geographical pockets of poverty: Mexico’s Southern States, Brazil Northeast,
      Central America’s East Coast regions, and high altitudes in the Altiplano.

      Indigenous territories: Indigenous communities attached to their homelands in
      the Altiplano and the East Coast of Central America.

The other part of the rural poor are socially diffused in FRA (favorable rural ar-
eas) defined as areas with good agro-ecologies and good connections to dy-
namic product and/or labor markets. The poor in this context are:

      Individuals with low asset endowments, especially land, education, and social
      capital.

      Individuals with good asset endowments, but lacking opportunities to valorize
      these assets in the territories where they are located (lack of regional dy-
      namics, discrimination).

      Rural youth, elderly people, and disabled individuals for whom social assis-
      tance programs are needed.”

This perspective provides a much more tangible understanding of types of rural
poverty. The authors’ conclusion is: “These contrasts between favorable and un-
favorable areas (and the continuum of conditions in between) points to the rele-
vance of a regionally differentiated approach that takes into account this hetero-
geneity.” (ibid.) In other words, any pro-poor policy must have a strong territorial
focus.




5       How to link M4P and VC analysis: Practical considerations

In principle, there are two ways to approach the issue of pro-poor, market-
oriented value chain analysis:

1. Analysis can be conducted as a separate activity.

2. Analysis can be conducted as action research.

In this section, we will look at each option.


5.1      Analysis before action

An approach where thorough analysis is conducted before any action is taken is
based on an epistemological concept that is mechanistic by nature. It is based on
the assumption that most if not all of the relevant information for a developmental
28                                               Jörg Meyer-Stamer and Frank Wältring




activity can be gathered before a strategy is formulated and implemented. One
such approach is presented in a recent paper by Kula, Downing and Field (2006)
which reflects the current state of thinking in USAID’s microenterprise pro-
gramme.

Figure 9: The USAID approach to value chain promotion




                                                   Source: Kula, Downing and Field (2006)

An Analysis Before Action approach has its advantages first and foremost from
an administrative perspective. It allows for organising planning into a logical
framework, facilitates the planning of the allocation of resources over a period of
time, and appears to define clear milestones which make project management
easier for administrators who are removed from activities on the ground.

In terms of activities on the ground, though, it is difficult to discern the advantages
of an Analysis Before Action approach. It may appear to be logically structured by
delivering information that is necessary for informed decision taking. This, how-
ever, can easily turn into an illusion as the Analysis Before Action approach will
often suffer from a specific type of Catch-22, namely the problem that a lot of the
information that is crucial to define the terms of reference for the researcher who
will conduct the value chain analysis only becomes available through the value
chain analysis said researcher will conduct.

In fact, the Analysis Before Action approach suffers from a number of dilemmas:

     Select VCs before understanding them: In this approach, VCs that are to be
     promoted are selected early, before representative information is available.
     Assuming hard budget constraints, it is unrealistic to conduct a comprehen-
     sive study of all value chains that are relevant for a given regional or national
     economy. By limiting the number of VCs that are investigated, VCs are not
     chosen because they have been thoroughly investigated. Instead, VCs are
     investigated because they have been chosen.

     Quick-scan vs robust information: The Analysis Before Action approach re-
     quires substantial resources. As projects tend to suffer from budget limita-
     tions, there is an incentive for project managers to limit the scope and depth
     of the analysis, thus conducting something that is more like a quick scan
     rather than solid research. With a quick scan, though, a random selection of
     VCs is followed by a collection of random data that lead to a random decision.

     Management of expectations: Researching value chains is usually based on
     face-to-face interviews, focus group interviews and workshops. To the extent
Linking Value Chain Promotion and the M4P Concept                                    29




      that actors who need to be interviewed suffer from time constraints, there
      needs to be an incentive for them to allocate time to the task of being re-
      searched. In order to persuade them to allocate time, researchers will be
      tempted to highlight the strong possibility of future promotion activities, per-
      haps including the availability of grants. Thus, expectations are created
      among actors inside the value chain which may or may not be realistic, and
      which in any case can not be managed in a proper way, based on the strat-
      egy and logical framework of the project, since neither strategy nor logframe
      exist at this stage.

In order to understand how steep the task of conducting a solid analysis before
any action is, let us have another look at the M4P literature. As quoted in Section
3.1, a solid analysis would involve a number of elements. We also give a rough
estimate of the number of researcher days that would be needed to conduct each
task.

Table 2: Tasks involved in an M4P / Value Chain analysis
Task                                                                     Estimated days
Poverty reports including household surveys and PPA surveys                   200
Specific market and transactions studies using participatory and other        50
techniques to complement existing poverty data
‘Doing Business’ and Investment Climate Surveys                               100
Trade, production and price data                                              30
Market outcomes and data from the operation of value chains                   250
The rate and direction of the evolution of key markets for the poor           60
Total                                                                         690

In other words, the Analysis Before Action approach is, first of all, a very serious
income generation programme for consultants and researchers. Assuming that
one third of those days would involve foreign consultants at a rate of US$ 500 per
day, and two thirds domestic consultants at a rate of US$100 per day, the fees
alone would amount to a total of US$ 161,000.


5.2      Action research

Practical experience shows that successful development programmes are based
on iterative processes, not simple sequences. For instance, in the LEADER pro-
gramme to promote development in poor rural regions of the EU, the learning
process regarding sequencing has been summarised in the way illustrated in
Figure 10.
30                                              Jörg Meyer-Stamer and Frank Wältring




Figure 10: The spiral model of sequencing in the EU LEADER programme




                      Source: www.rural-europe.aeidl.be, presentation LEADER_dia6_en.pdf

This model is based on the insight that ex-ante research will only to some extent
reveal the information that is relevant to solve a given problem or realise a given
opportunity. The best way to understand the root cause of a problem is to try to
solve it. This approach leads naturally to action research, i.e. a practice where
analysis and action are closely intertwined.

An approach that introduces a strong pro-poor element into value chain analysis
needs to be based on three key insights:

1. It must involve a geographical and sectoral focus that is particularly pro-poor
   (Ravaillon 2004).

2. It needs to analyse markets beyond the lines outlined by Ferrand, Gibson and
   Scott (2004), i.e. it needs a thorough understanding of market failure.

3. It needs to address the complementarity between markets and hierarchies
   (Dorward and Kydd 2005), as well as looking at networks as highlighted by
   the literature on global value chains (Schmitz 2005), and it needs to analyse
   the interaction between the three modes of coordination. This point may ap-
   pear contrary to the argument developed in Section 4. However, one needs to
   keep in mind that a value chain per se is a mixture of market-based coordina-
   tion, hierarchy and network, so that a narrow focus at markets and market
   failure is implausible.


5.2.1    Selecting a target group for a pro-poor value chain promotion
         project

When it comes to selecting target groups who are supposed to benefit from de-
velopment interventions, we usually recommend to design mechanisms that lead
Linking Value Chain Promotion and the M4P Concept                                   31




to self-selection, i.e. draft a process where a variety of possible beneficiaries is
addressed and ultimately those benefit who undertake the strongest effort to get
involved. Unfortunately, this may not be a feasible process when it comes to pro-
poor VCP. Pro-poor VCP, like any VCP activity, needs to be based on business
principles. When it comes to integrating poor communities into VCs, a self-
selection process may mobilise communities who do not really have the potential
to become integrated into VCs. Therefore, it may be recommendable to design a
selection process that involves external expertise.

A wrong approach to select target groups for pro-poor VCP would be based on a
sequence of questions like this: Where are the poor? Is there anything they can
produce? Can we train them to improve the quality of their product? And can we
then perhaps connect them to some value chain? This would be the “wouldn’t it
be nice if” approach, as in “wouldn’t it be nice if Ikea sold Bolivian handicraft”.
Selecting poor communities and regions, based on their need and their supposed
potential, promoting them and only after that trying to connect them to VCs is a
supply-driven approach that will not work.

The only way to move a chain is by pulling. In this perspective, we see two
promising approaches to pro-poor VCP.

The problem-driven approach: The starting point is the analysis of the real
economy in a given country, based on the analysis of export data, conversations
with exporters or interviews with buyers at major domestic retailers. The question
is: Which producers in poor communities are connected to national or global VCs,
and which of them are only precariously integrated into VCs, so that an effort to
upgrade their capability (which must be coordinated with buyers from the outset)
is meaningful? A relatively quick fact-finding effort would lead to a list of potential
candidates in terms of communities, sectors and locations. Addressees for VCP
activities would then be picked from this list on the basis of poverty / pro-poor de-
velopment criteria.

The opportunity-driven approach: This approach would take the interests of
major domestic retailers, exporters or foreign buyers as the point of departure.
The question would be: What are the products that you are searching for but
cannot find? And to what extent have you identified possible producers in our
country that have a basic production capability but are not close enough to an
adequate quality and productivity level to qualify for a supplier development pro-
gramme that is managed by the buyer? The rationale of this approach would be
to help producers, preferably from poor communities, to cross the gap that sepa-
rates them from the minimum requirements of major buyers.


5.2.2    Launching a pro-poor value chain promotion project

What would the initial sequence in a pro-poor value chain initiative look like? We
have tried to visualise this in Figure 11. In this approach, the first steps are par-
ticularly important. They make or break the pro-poor impact of the initiative. The
32                                                 Jörg Meyer-Stamer and Frank Wältring




pro-poor orientation needs be part of the genetic code of the initiative, not some-
thing that is just attached like a slogan sticker.

Figure 11: Initial Sequence for a Pro-Poor Value Chain Initiative




The figure does not distinguish between the national-level and the territorial pillar
of a VCP initiative. The first four activities (initiating, scoping, assembling re-
sources, picturing the value chain) would involve a single process. During the
“picturing the value chain” stage the process would go through a bifurcation, after
which a national-level process and one or several territorial processes would run
at the same time, though not in parallel but rather informing and reinforcing each
other.

The following table looks at the particular challenges that exist in terms of assur-
ing that the pro-poor perspective is maintained in a satisfactory way. Subse-
quently, we will look at each step in more detail.

Table 3: How to consistently maintain the pro-poor perspective
Stage                 Tools
Scoping               Collect and assess the existing documentation on the structure of
                      poverty
Assemble re-          Involve individuals with a deep understanding of poverty in the given
sources               country in the core team
Picturing the value   Look for regions and locations where poor producers have a least a
chain                 vague potential to be involved in the respective value chain
Engaging              Conduct workshops in poor communities, using standard PRA tools
stakeholders
                      Make sure that facilitators understand the crucial importance of
                      proper management of expectations at this stage
Linking Value Chain Promotion and the M4P Concept                                            33




Collaborating with     As above, plus test the willingness of poor communities in different
stakeholders           locations to get seriously involved in a development effort. Never
                       forget that sometimes poverty is a comfort zone. But also address
                       the issue of risk: try to identify communities for whom the risk of fail-
                       ure of the initiative is not existential.
Participatory, action Employ a specific variation of a participatory, quick appraisal in lo-
oriented research     cations with poor producers who may have a potential to be in-
                      volved in the value chain. Make sure that the issue of market failure
                      is covered.
Quick-win activities   Make sure that there is enough capacity for ongoing facilitation of
                       the implementation of activities in poor communities.
Participatory M+E      Apply appropriate M+E tools (e.g. no tools that require writing in
                       communities with a high incidence of illiteracy)
Adjustment             As the approach becomes more robust, try to involve the more
                       complicated, less organised, less risk-tolerant poor communities.
Scaling up



Scoping

At this stage, issues like the geographical and sectoral structure of poverty need
to be addressed. The painful discussions that were mentioned above (poor vs
very poor, moderately competitive vs survivalist) must be conducted at this stage,
and decisions need to be taken in this respect. However, given the iterative
structure of the overall VCP initiative, it is important to note that there is always
room for adjustment, especially when the practical work shows that certain
groups of poor show more dedication and potential than initially expected.



Assemble resources

This point not only addresses the mobilisation of funds to conduct the value chain
initiative. It also relates to other resources that are essential, in particular knowl-
edge and connections. At this stage, it is crucial to assemble a number of “con-
nectors” who can tap into different sources of knowledge, including indigenous
and local knowledge (as opposed to relying exclusively on the data presented by
national or regional level poverty assessments).



Picturing the value chain

At this stage, the key task is to get a better understanding of the value chain that
is going to be in the focus of the initiative. This does not imply preparing a com-
prehensive report that adheres to academic standards. It is perfectly possible to
picture a value chain in through two or three well facilitated brief workshops with
key informers where simple yet powerful mapping techniques are used. Mapping
techniques like those in GTZ’s ValueLinks method are extremely useful at this
34                                               Jörg Meyer-Stamer and Frank Wältring




stage. On top of mapping the elements of the chain, it would be useful to investi-
gate market failure at the different stages of the chain.



Engaging stakeholders

For a pro-poor value chain initiative to be successful, a broad set of highly di-
verse stakeholders needs to be engaged, from top management in major corpo-
rations that are powerful nodes in value chains to poor communities in peripheral
locations. Obviously, very different communication approaches have to be used
to engage the different stakeholders:

     At the level of lead firms, an essential point is to engage with top manage-
     ment and with supply chain managers, rather than just with the Corporate
     Social Responsibility department.

     At the level of local communities, it is essential to interact not only with gov-
     ernment officials and politicians, but also with communities themselves. Stan-
     dard PRA tools like Wealth Ranking and Well-Being Ranking can be useful in
     better understanding local communities.



Collaborating with stakeholders

The purpose of this element is to verify, through discussions with the set of
stakeholders who were initially addressed, that the right stakeholders have been
involved. It also involves understanding the goals and objectives, and logic of ac-
tion, of the different stakeholders. At the local level, interacting with producers
and companies, well-established PRA tools like transects and walkovers are
useful.



Participatory, action oriented research

The purpose of this step is to analyse the value chain and to look for opportuni-
ties to integrate (more) poor producers into the value chain. It involves a set of
workshops with different stakeholders. Though to some extent workshops will
address relatively homogeneous groups of stakeholders, it is crucial to organise
workshops that bring together representatives of very different stakeholder
groups, so that key stakeholders get a first-hand understanding of other
stakeholders’ mindset and objectives. Tools that can be used at this stage in-
clude ValueLinks mapping, standard PRA and PACA tools, as well as specific
tools that look at market structures.

A possible angle is to look at barriers to entry, as many instances of market fail-
ure will ultimately manifest themselves as barriers to entry. A useful tool to inves-
tigate this is a modified version of Michael Porter’s Five Forces Analysis.
Linking Value Chain Promotion and the M4P Concept                                     35




Figure 12




The modification refers to the bottom box, which looks at barriers to diversifica-
tion (into related products, markets in neighbouring locations, or a closely related
market segment) instead of substituting products. The other four forces are di-
rectly related to market power and barriers to entry, i.e. generate information
about possible market failure. While incumbents may hesitate to highlight the bar-
riers to entry they are creating, business people are usually more than happy to
complain about the barriers to entry they are facing, and this is why the changed
bottom box is useful. This tool can be used both in interviews and in workshops
with representatives from a given subsector.



Quick-win activities

Since a value chain addresses businesses, and even very big corporations tend
to think in three-month-cycles, it is crucial that quick-win activities are identified in
the research phase which can then swiftly be implemented. When it comes to
prioritising activities, the prospect of an activity to improve the integration of poor
into the chain should be applied as one criterion.

Moreover, while brainstorming on possible activities, the stakeholders involved in
this exercise should consistently ask themselves: Can whatever we want to do be
sensibly done via the market (rather than through a hierarchy or a network)? De-
velopment practitioners appear to have a natural tendency to opt for hierarchy or
network as preferred approaches to addressing problems or opportunities, which
is unfortunate since a market-based solution, where business people pursue an
opportunity out of self-interest, is often the most sustainable solution.
36                                                   Jörg Meyer-Stamer and Frank Wältring




Participatory M+E

After the first round of activities has been implemented, the different stakeholders
need to be involved in a monitoring and evaluation effort that takes the initiative
towards the second round of activities, thus launching the iterative pattern.



Adjustment, scaling up

Apart from coming up with more (and hopefully better and more effective) activi-
ties, it is crucial to look at scaling up. Initial activities will most likely be pilot activi-
ties with a limited outreach. Once a given approach appears to be robust, it
needs to be scaled up to reach a bigger group of poor.




6      Conclusion

M4P and VCP do not fit like hand and glove. Merging them into a single ap-
proach is not desirable, since this would imply losing the focus at international
transactions in the VCP approach. M4P and VCP can fertilise each other, since
each one addresses blind spots of the other:

     The VCP approach highlights the fact that markets are only one mode of co-
     ordinating economic transactions, next to hierarchies and networks. While the
     M4P approach acknowledges this in principle, it is subject to a narrowing
     down of interventions towards enabling markets without due consideration for
     hierarchies and markets.

     The M4P concept highlights the relevance of enabling markets, a fact that
     VCP projects may lose sight of because they can easily get involved in micro-
     management of economic transactions. Moreover, the M4P concept empha-
     sises the importance of directly addressing the poor, something that is not
     explicit in VCP approaches.

Moreover, the M4P approach can fertilise a couple of arenas of technical coop-
eration, such as local and regional economic develoment, SME promotion and
agricultural development. It also has the potential to generate systemic change.
While selective activities such as VCP by their very nature have a limited impact,
M4P has the potential to induce change that affects all market participants. It thus
makes a lot of sense to further explore the contributions M4P can make to other
fields of productive sector development.
Linking Value Chain Analysis and the ““Making Markets work better for the Poor”” Concept
Linking Value Chain Analysis and the ““Making Markets work better for the Poor”” Concept
Linking Value Chain Analysis and the ““Making Markets work better for the Poor”” Concept
Linking Value Chain Analysis and the ““Making Markets work better for the Poor”” Concept
Linking Value Chain Analysis and the ““Making Markets work better for the Poor”” Concept
Linking Value Chain Analysis and the ““Making Markets work better for the Poor”” Concept
Linking Value Chain Analysis and the ““Making Markets work better for the Poor”” Concept
Linking Value Chain Analysis and the ““Making Markets work better for the Poor”” Concept
Linking Value Chain Analysis and the ““Making Markets work better for the Poor”” Concept

More Related Content

What's hot

Internship in library
Internship in libraryInternship in library
Internship in libraryAditya Ranjan
 
Public library management
Public library management Public library management
Public library management Gautam Kumar
 
Evaluation des collections (2009)
Evaluation des collections (2009)Evaluation des collections (2009)
Evaluation des collections (2009)Le Lirographe
 
Introduction to research data management
Introduction to research data managementIntroduction to research data management
Introduction to research data managementMichael Day
 
FRBR, FRAD and RDA I don't speak cataloging why should I care
FRBR, FRAD and RDA   I don't speak cataloging why should I careFRBR, FRAD and RDA   I don't speak cataloging why should I care
FRBR, FRAD and RDA I don't speak cataloging why should I careDeann Trebbe
 
Buurtzorg: humanity above bureaucracy by integrating simplification in a teal...
Buurtzorg: humanity above bureaucracy by integrating simplification in a teal...Buurtzorg: humanity above bureaucracy by integrating simplification in a teal...
Buurtzorg: humanity above bureaucracy by integrating simplification in a teal...Societat Gestió Sanitària
 
Design and development of information product by geeta gadhavi
Design and development of information product by geeta gadhaviDesign and development of information product by geeta gadhavi
Design and development of information product by geeta gadhaviGeeta Gadhavi
 
MEDLARS - Medical Literature Analysis And Retrieval System
MEDLARS - Medical Literature Analysis And Retrieval SystemMEDLARS - Medical Literature Analysis And Retrieval System
MEDLARS - Medical Literature Analysis And Retrieval SystemPALLAB DAS
 
COMMUNITY INFORMATION SERVICE 2.0: APPLICATION OF WEB 2.0 TOOLS IN DESIGNING...
COMMUNITY INFORMATION SERVICE 2.0: APPLICATION OF  WEB 2.0 TOOLS IN DESIGNING...COMMUNITY INFORMATION SERVICE 2.0: APPLICATION OF  WEB 2.0 TOOLS IN DESIGNING...
COMMUNITY INFORMATION SERVICE 2.0: APPLICATION OF WEB 2.0 TOOLS IN DESIGNING...Netaji Subhas Open University
 
Intro to rda
Intro to rdaIntro to rda
Intro to rdaAnna Enos
 
Economics of information
Economics of information Economics of information
Economics of information Shuvra Ghosh
 

What's hot (20)

Internship in library
Internship in libraryInternship in library
Internship in library
 
FRBR
FRBRFRBR
FRBR
 
Public library management
Public library management Public library management
Public library management
 
Reengineering library services
Reengineering library servicesReengineering library services
Reengineering library services
 
Evaluation des collections (2009)
Evaluation des collections (2009)Evaluation des collections (2009)
Evaluation des collections (2009)
 
Financial Management in Libraries
Financial Management in LibrariesFinancial Management in Libraries
Financial Management in Libraries
 
Special Library Management
Special Library ManagementSpecial Library Management
Special Library Management
 
Introduction to research data management
Introduction to research data managementIntroduction to research data management
Introduction to research data management
 
FRBR, FRAD and RDA I don't speak cataloging why should I care
FRBR, FRAD and RDA   I don't speak cataloging why should I careFRBR, FRAD and RDA   I don't speak cataloging why should I care
FRBR, FRAD and RDA I don't speak cataloging why should I care
 
Phase relation
Phase  relationPhase  relation
Phase relation
 
ISBD
ISBDISBD
ISBD
 
Absolute syntax
Absolute syntaxAbsolute syntax
Absolute syntax
 
Project proposal
Project proposalProject proposal
Project proposal
 
Buurtzorg: humanity above bureaucracy by integrating simplification in a teal...
Buurtzorg: humanity above bureaucracy by integrating simplification in a teal...Buurtzorg: humanity above bureaucracy by integrating simplification in a teal...
Buurtzorg: humanity above bureaucracy by integrating simplification in a teal...
 
Design and development of information product by geeta gadhavi
Design and development of information product by geeta gadhaviDesign and development of information product by geeta gadhavi
Design and development of information product by geeta gadhavi
 
MEDLARS - Medical Literature Analysis And Retrieval System
MEDLARS - Medical Literature Analysis And Retrieval SystemMEDLARS - Medical Literature Analysis And Retrieval System
MEDLARS - Medical Literature Analysis And Retrieval System
 
COMMUNITY INFORMATION SERVICE 2.0: APPLICATION OF WEB 2.0 TOOLS IN DESIGNING...
COMMUNITY INFORMATION SERVICE 2.0: APPLICATION OF  WEB 2.0 TOOLS IN DESIGNING...COMMUNITY INFORMATION SERVICE 2.0: APPLICATION OF  WEB 2.0 TOOLS IN DESIGNING...
COMMUNITY INFORMATION SERVICE 2.0: APPLICATION OF WEB 2.0 TOOLS IN DESIGNING...
 
Intro to rda
Intro to rdaIntro to rda
Intro to rda
 
Use and user study
Use and user study Use and user study
Use and user study
 
Economics of information
Economics of information Economics of information
Economics of information
 

Similar to Linking Value Chain Analysis and the ““Making Markets work better for the Poor”” Concept

Multicriteria methodology for kpi identification in outsourced projects
Multicriteria methodology for kpi identification in outsourced projectsMulticriteria methodology for kpi identification in outsourced projects
Multicriteria methodology for kpi identification in outsourced projectsEdilson Giffhorn
 
The Commercial Potential of Virtual Communities in the Wireless Internet
The Commercial Potential of Virtual Communities in the Wireless InternetThe Commercial Potential of Virtual Communities in the Wireless Internet
The Commercial Potential of Virtual Communities in the Wireless InternetThierryBusset
 
The Commercial Potential of Virtual Communities in the Wireless Internet
The Commercial Potential of Virtual Communities in the Wireless InternetThe Commercial Potential of Virtual Communities in the Wireless Internet
The Commercial Potential of Virtual Communities in the Wireless InternetThierryBusset
 
Guidance note for the Programmatic Approach (version 31-12-2011)
Guidance note for the Programmatic Approach (version 31-12-2011)Guidance note for the Programmatic Approach (version 31-12-2011)
Guidance note for the Programmatic Approach (version 31-12-2011)ICCO Cooperation
 
GTZ ValueLinks Manual
GTZ ValueLinks Manual GTZ ValueLinks Manual
GTZ ValueLinks Manual led4lgus
 
61506_Capstone_Report_DFID_FINAL_Quantifying_Governance__Indicators-4
61506_Capstone_Report_DFID_FINAL_Quantifying_Governance__Indicators-461506_Capstone_Report_DFID_FINAL_Quantifying_Governance__Indicators-4
61506_Capstone_Report_DFID_FINAL_Quantifying_Governance__Indicators-4Alexander Hamilton, PhD
 
Ipol stoa et-2012_488798_en
Ipol stoa et-2012_488798_enIpol stoa et-2012_488798_en
Ipol stoa et-2012_488798_endeselnicu
 
Kpi methodology
Kpi methodologyKpi methodology
Kpi methodologymahnath
 
MS Management Consultancy Disseration 2008 University Of Wales, United Ki...
MS Management Consultancy Disseration   2008   University Of Wales, United Ki...MS Management Consultancy Disseration   2008   University Of Wales, United Ki...
MS Management Consultancy Disseration 2008 University Of Wales, United Ki...fazal9
 
A0067927 amit sinha_thesis
A0067927 amit sinha_thesisA0067927 amit sinha_thesis
A0067927 amit sinha_thesisAmit Sinha
 
The Evolution of the UK Channel (Full Research)
The Evolution of the UK Channel (Full Research)The Evolution of the UK Channel (Full Research)
The Evolution of the UK Channel (Full Research)NetMediaEurope UK
 

Similar to Linking Value Chain Analysis and the ““Making Markets work better for the Poor”” Concept (20)

M4P Approach Synthesis (DFID and SDC), 2008
M4P Approach Synthesis (DFID and SDC), 2008M4P Approach Synthesis (DFID and SDC), 2008
M4P Approach Synthesis (DFID and SDC), 2008
 
Successful Value Chains
Successful Value ChainsSuccessful Value Chains
Successful Value Chains
 
Multicriteria methodology for kpi identification in outsourced projects
Multicriteria methodology for kpi identification in outsourced projectsMulticriteria methodology for kpi identification in outsourced projects
Multicriteria methodology for kpi identification in outsourced projects
 
Anurit phd.
Anurit phd.Anurit phd.
Anurit phd.
 
Springer heinze on_valuelinks_addis_3
Springer heinze on_valuelinks_addis_3Springer heinze on_valuelinks_addis_3
Springer heinze on_valuelinks_addis_3
 
The Commercial Potential of Virtual Communities in the Wireless Internet
The Commercial Potential of Virtual Communities in the Wireless InternetThe Commercial Potential of Virtual Communities in the Wireless Internet
The Commercial Potential of Virtual Communities in the Wireless Internet
 
The Commercial Potential of Virtual Communities in the Wireless Internet
The Commercial Potential of Virtual Communities in the Wireless InternetThe Commercial Potential of Virtual Communities in the Wireless Internet
The Commercial Potential of Virtual Communities in the Wireless Internet
 
Guidance note for the Programmatic Approach (version 31-12-2011)
Guidance note for the Programmatic Approach (version 31-12-2011)Guidance note for the Programmatic Approach (version 31-12-2011)
Guidance note for the Programmatic Approach (version 31-12-2011)
 
GTZ ValueLinks Manual
GTZ ValueLinks Manual GTZ ValueLinks Manual
GTZ ValueLinks Manual
 
61506_Capstone_Report_DFID_FINAL_Quantifying_Governance__Indicators-4
61506_Capstone_Report_DFID_FINAL_Quantifying_Governance__Indicators-461506_Capstone_Report_DFID_FINAL_Quantifying_Governance__Indicators-4
61506_Capstone_Report_DFID_FINAL_Quantifying_Governance__Indicators-4
 
Ipol stoa et-2012_488798_en
Ipol stoa et-2012_488798_enIpol stoa et-2012_488798_en
Ipol stoa et-2012_488798_en
 
Kpi methodology
Kpi methodologyKpi methodology
Kpi methodology
 
Supply chain management
Supply chain managementSupply chain management
Supply chain management
 
Supply chain management
Supply chain managementSupply chain management
Supply chain management
 
Supply chain management
Supply chain managementSupply chain management
Supply chain management
 
Supply chain management
Supply chain managementSupply chain management
Supply chain management
 
MS Management Consultancy Disseration 2008 University Of Wales, United Ki...
MS Management Consultancy Disseration   2008   University Of Wales, United Ki...MS Management Consultancy Disseration   2008   University Of Wales, United Ki...
MS Management Consultancy Disseration 2008 University Of Wales, United Ki...
 
E marketing
E marketing E marketing
E marketing
 
A0067927 amit sinha_thesis
A0067927 amit sinha_thesisA0067927 amit sinha_thesis
A0067927 amit sinha_thesis
 
The Evolution of the UK Channel (Full Research)
The Evolution of the UK Channel (Full Research)The Evolution of the UK Channel (Full Research)
The Evolution of the UK Channel (Full Research)
 

More from led4lgus

Proceedings of the LED FUNDAMENTALS COURSE
Proceedings of the  LED FUNDAMENTALS COURSEProceedings of the  LED FUNDAMENTALS COURSE
Proceedings of the LED FUNDAMENTALS COURSEled4lgus
 
Subnational Full Toolkit
Subnational Full ToolkitSubnational Full Toolkit
Subnational Full Toolkitled4lgus
 
SMEDSEP Business Reg Licensing in RP
SMEDSEP Business Reg Licensing in RPSMEDSEP Business Reg Licensing in RP
SMEDSEP Business Reg Licensing in RPled4lgus
 
Strategy Mapping
Strategy MappingStrategy Mapping
Strategy Mappingled4lgus
 
Public Private Partnership Handbook
Public Private Partnership HandbookPublic Private Partnership Handbook
Public Private Partnership Handbookled4lgus
 
SMEDSED Organizational Review Project
SMEDSED Organizational Review ProjectSMEDSED Organizational Review Project
SMEDSED Organizational Review Projectled4lgus
 
Performance mgt using balanced scorecard
Performance mgt using balanced scorecard Performance mgt using balanced scorecard
Performance mgt using balanced scorecard led4lgus
 
Negros Tourism Marketing Agency
Negros Tourism Marketing AgencyNegros Tourism Marketing Agency
Negros Tourism Marketing Agencyled4lgus
 
Appropriate Coordinating Structures Chapter 2
Appropriate  Coordinating Structures Chapter 2Appropriate  Coordinating Structures Chapter 2
Appropriate Coordinating Structures Chapter 2led4lgus
 
Effective Financing Responses Chapter 3
Effective Financing Responses Chapter 3Effective Financing Responses Chapter 3
Effective Financing Responses Chapter 3led4lgus
 
The Compass of Local Competitiveness v0.9
The Compass of Local Competitiveness v0.9The Compass of Local Competitiveness v0.9
The Compass of Local Competitiveness v0.9led4lgus
 
Financial Challenges Chapter 5
Financial Challenges Chapter 5Financial Challenges Chapter 5
Financial Challenges Chapter 5led4lgus
 
Managing Cities as Drivers of the Economy Chapter 2
Managing Cities as  Drivers of the Economy Chapter 2Managing Cities as  Drivers of the Economy Chapter 2
Managing Cities as Drivers of the Economy Chapter 2led4lgus
 
Assessing City Competitiveness Frameworks
Assessing City Competitiveness FrameworksAssessing City Competitiveness Frameworks
Assessing City Competitiveness Frameworksled4lgus
 
Toolkit on LRED
Toolkit on LREDToolkit on LRED
Toolkit on LREDled4lgus
 
Project Programming & Prioritisation Toolkit September 2009
Project Programming & Prioritisation Toolkit September 2009Project Programming & Prioritisation Toolkit September 2009
Project Programming & Prioritisation Toolkit September 2009led4lgus
 
Local and Regional Economic Development in Leyte Province
Local and Regional Economic Development in Leyte ProvinceLocal and Regional Economic Development in Leyte Province
Local and Regional Economic Development in Leyte Provinceled4lgus
 
Strategic Local Economic Development: A Guide for Local Governments
Strategic Local Economic Development: A Guide for Local GovernmentsStrategic Local Economic Development: A Guide for Local Governments
Strategic Local Economic Development: A Guide for Local Governmentsled4lgus
 
Making Local Economic Development Strategies: A Trainer’s Manual
Making Local Economic Development  Strategies: A Trainer’s ManualMaking Local Economic Development  Strategies: A Trainer’s Manual
Making Local Economic Development Strategies: A Trainer’s Manualled4lgus
 
Pre-Feasibility Study Guideline September 2009
Pre-Feasibility Study Guideline September 2009Pre-Feasibility Study Guideline September 2009
Pre-Feasibility Study Guideline September 2009led4lgus
 

More from led4lgus (20)

Proceedings of the LED FUNDAMENTALS COURSE
Proceedings of the  LED FUNDAMENTALS COURSEProceedings of the  LED FUNDAMENTALS COURSE
Proceedings of the LED FUNDAMENTALS COURSE
 
Subnational Full Toolkit
Subnational Full ToolkitSubnational Full Toolkit
Subnational Full Toolkit
 
SMEDSEP Business Reg Licensing in RP
SMEDSEP Business Reg Licensing in RPSMEDSEP Business Reg Licensing in RP
SMEDSEP Business Reg Licensing in RP
 
Strategy Mapping
Strategy MappingStrategy Mapping
Strategy Mapping
 
Public Private Partnership Handbook
Public Private Partnership HandbookPublic Private Partnership Handbook
Public Private Partnership Handbook
 
SMEDSED Organizational Review Project
SMEDSED Organizational Review ProjectSMEDSED Organizational Review Project
SMEDSED Organizational Review Project
 
Performance mgt using balanced scorecard
Performance mgt using balanced scorecard Performance mgt using balanced scorecard
Performance mgt using balanced scorecard
 
Negros Tourism Marketing Agency
Negros Tourism Marketing AgencyNegros Tourism Marketing Agency
Negros Tourism Marketing Agency
 
Appropriate Coordinating Structures Chapter 2
Appropriate  Coordinating Structures Chapter 2Appropriate  Coordinating Structures Chapter 2
Appropriate Coordinating Structures Chapter 2
 
Effective Financing Responses Chapter 3
Effective Financing Responses Chapter 3Effective Financing Responses Chapter 3
Effective Financing Responses Chapter 3
 
The Compass of Local Competitiveness v0.9
The Compass of Local Competitiveness v0.9The Compass of Local Competitiveness v0.9
The Compass of Local Competitiveness v0.9
 
Financial Challenges Chapter 5
Financial Challenges Chapter 5Financial Challenges Chapter 5
Financial Challenges Chapter 5
 
Managing Cities as Drivers of the Economy Chapter 2
Managing Cities as  Drivers of the Economy Chapter 2Managing Cities as  Drivers of the Economy Chapter 2
Managing Cities as Drivers of the Economy Chapter 2
 
Assessing City Competitiveness Frameworks
Assessing City Competitiveness FrameworksAssessing City Competitiveness Frameworks
Assessing City Competitiveness Frameworks
 
Toolkit on LRED
Toolkit on LREDToolkit on LRED
Toolkit on LRED
 
Project Programming & Prioritisation Toolkit September 2009
Project Programming & Prioritisation Toolkit September 2009Project Programming & Prioritisation Toolkit September 2009
Project Programming & Prioritisation Toolkit September 2009
 
Local and Regional Economic Development in Leyte Province
Local and Regional Economic Development in Leyte ProvinceLocal and Regional Economic Development in Leyte Province
Local and Regional Economic Development in Leyte Province
 
Strategic Local Economic Development: A Guide for Local Governments
Strategic Local Economic Development: A Guide for Local GovernmentsStrategic Local Economic Development: A Guide for Local Governments
Strategic Local Economic Development: A Guide for Local Governments
 
Making Local Economic Development Strategies: A Trainer’s Manual
Making Local Economic Development  Strategies: A Trainer’s ManualMaking Local Economic Development  Strategies: A Trainer’s Manual
Making Local Economic Development Strategies: A Trainer’s Manual
 
Pre-Feasibility Study Guideline September 2009
Pre-Feasibility Study Guideline September 2009Pre-Feasibility Study Guideline September 2009
Pre-Feasibility Study Guideline September 2009
 

Recently uploaded

Top 10 Traditional Indian Handicrafts.pptx
Top 10 Traditional Indian Handicrafts.pptxTop 10 Traditional Indian Handicrafts.pptx
Top 10 Traditional Indian Handicrafts.pptxdishha99
 
Study Consultants in Lahore || 📞03094429236
Study Consultants in Lahore || 📞03094429236Study Consultants in Lahore || 📞03094429236
Study Consultants in Lahore || 📞03094429236Sherazi Tours
 
08448380779 Call Girls In Shahdara Women Seeking Men
08448380779 Call Girls In Shahdara Women Seeking Men08448380779 Call Girls In Shahdara Women Seeking Men
08448380779 Call Girls In Shahdara Women Seeking MenDelhi Call girls
 
08448380779 Call Girls In Bhikaji Cama Palace Women Seeking Men
08448380779 Call Girls In Bhikaji Cama Palace Women Seeking Men08448380779 Call Girls In Bhikaji Cama Palace Women Seeking Men
08448380779 Call Girls In Bhikaji Cama Palace Women Seeking MenDelhi Call girls
 
08448380779 Call Girls In Chirag Enclave Women Seeking Men
08448380779 Call Girls In Chirag Enclave Women Seeking Men08448380779 Call Girls In Chirag Enclave Women Seeking Men
08448380779 Call Girls In Chirag Enclave Women Seeking MenDelhi Call girls
 
Night 7k Call Girls Noida Sector 93 Escorts Call Me: 8448380779
Night 7k Call Girls Noida Sector 93 Escorts Call Me: 8448380779Night 7k Call Girls Noida Sector 93 Escorts Call Me: 8448380779
Night 7k Call Girls Noida Sector 93 Escorts Call Me: 8448380779Delhi Call girls
 
Genesis 1:6 || Meditate the Scripture daily verse by verse
Genesis 1:6  ||  Meditate the Scripture daily verse by verseGenesis 1:6  ||  Meditate the Scripture daily verse by verse
Genesis 1:6 || Meditate the Scripture daily verse by versemaricelcanoynuay
 
Experience the Magic of Saint Martin and Sint Maarten with Find American Rent...
Experience the Magic of Saint Martin and Sint Maarten with Find American Rent...Experience the Magic of Saint Martin and Sint Maarten with Find American Rent...
Experience the Magic of Saint Martin and Sint Maarten with Find American Rent...Find American Rentals
 
Hire 💕 8617697112 Chamba Call Girls Service Call Girls Agency
Hire 💕 8617697112 Chamba Call Girls Service Call Girls AgencyHire 💕 8617697112 Chamba Call Girls Service Call Girls Agency
Hire 💕 8617697112 Chamba Call Girls Service Call Girls AgencyNitya salvi
 
BERMUDA Triangle the mystery of life.pptx
BERMUDA Triangle the mystery of life.pptxBERMUDA Triangle the mystery of life.pptx
BERMUDA Triangle the mystery of life.pptxseri bangash
 
visa consultant | 📞📞 03094429236 || Best Study Visa Consultant
visa consultant | 📞📞 03094429236 || Best Study Visa Consultantvisa consultant | 📞📞 03094429236 || Best Study Visa Consultant
visa consultant | 📞📞 03094429236 || Best Study Visa ConsultantSherazi Tours
 
Visa Consultant in Lahore || 📞03094429236
Visa Consultant in Lahore || 📞03094429236Visa Consultant in Lahore || 📞03094429236
Visa Consultant in Lahore || 📞03094429236Sherazi Tours
 
best weekend places near delhi where you should visit.pdf
best weekend places near delhi where you should visit.pdfbest weekend places near delhi where you should visit.pdf
best weekend places near delhi where you should visit.pdftour guide
 
💕📲09602870969💓Girl Escort Services Udaipur Call Girls in Chittorgarh Haldighati
💕📲09602870969💓Girl Escort Services Udaipur Call Girls in Chittorgarh Haldighati💕📲09602870969💓Girl Escort Services Udaipur Call Girls in Chittorgarh Haldighati
💕📲09602870969💓Girl Escort Services Udaipur Call Girls in Chittorgarh HaldighatiApsara Of India
 
08448380779 Call Girls In Chhattarpur Women Seeking Men
08448380779 Call Girls In Chhattarpur Women Seeking Men08448380779 Call Girls In Chhattarpur Women Seeking Men
08448380779 Call Girls In Chhattarpur Women Seeking MenDelhi Call girls
 
🔥HOT🔥📲9602870969🔥Prostitute Service in Udaipur Call Girls in City Palace Lake...
🔥HOT🔥📲9602870969🔥Prostitute Service in Udaipur Call Girls in City Palace Lake...🔥HOT🔥📲9602870969🔥Prostitute Service in Udaipur Call Girls in City Palace Lake...
🔥HOT🔥📲9602870969🔥Prostitute Service in Udaipur Call Girls in City Palace Lake...Apsara Of India
 
Hire 💕 8617697112 Champawat Call Girls Service Call Girls Agency
Hire 💕 8617697112 Champawat Call Girls Service Call Girls AgencyHire 💕 8617697112 Champawat Call Girls Service Call Girls Agency
Hire 💕 8617697112 Champawat Call Girls Service Call Girls AgencyNitya salvi
 

Recently uploaded (20)

Top 10 Traditional Indian Handicrafts.pptx
Top 10 Traditional Indian Handicrafts.pptxTop 10 Traditional Indian Handicrafts.pptx
Top 10 Traditional Indian Handicrafts.pptx
 
Study Consultants in Lahore || 📞03094429236
Study Consultants in Lahore || 📞03094429236Study Consultants in Lahore || 📞03094429236
Study Consultants in Lahore || 📞03094429236
 
08448380779 Call Girls In Shahdara Women Seeking Men
08448380779 Call Girls In Shahdara Women Seeking Men08448380779 Call Girls In Shahdara Women Seeking Men
08448380779 Call Girls In Shahdara Women Seeking Men
 
08448380779 Call Girls In Bhikaji Cama Palace Women Seeking Men
08448380779 Call Girls In Bhikaji Cama Palace Women Seeking Men08448380779 Call Girls In Bhikaji Cama Palace Women Seeking Men
08448380779 Call Girls In Bhikaji Cama Palace Women Seeking Men
 
08448380779 Call Girls In Chirag Enclave Women Seeking Men
08448380779 Call Girls In Chirag Enclave Women Seeking Men08448380779 Call Girls In Chirag Enclave Women Seeking Men
08448380779 Call Girls In Chirag Enclave Women Seeking Men
 
Night 7k Call Girls Noida Sector 93 Escorts Call Me: 8448380779
Night 7k Call Girls Noida Sector 93 Escorts Call Me: 8448380779Night 7k Call Girls Noida Sector 93 Escorts Call Me: 8448380779
Night 7k Call Girls Noida Sector 93 Escorts Call Me: 8448380779
 
Call Girls In Munirka 📱 9999965857 🤩 Delhi 🫦 HOT AND SEXY VVIP 🍎 SERVICE
Call Girls In Munirka 📱  9999965857  🤩 Delhi 🫦 HOT AND SEXY VVIP 🍎 SERVICECall Girls In Munirka 📱  9999965857  🤩 Delhi 🫦 HOT AND SEXY VVIP 🍎 SERVICE
Call Girls In Munirka 📱 9999965857 🤩 Delhi 🫦 HOT AND SEXY VVIP 🍎 SERVICE
 
Genesis 1:6 || Meditate the Scripture daily verse by verse
Genesis 1:6  ||  Meditate the Scripture daily verse by verseGenesis 1:6  ||  Meditate the Scripture daily verse by verse
Genesis 1:6 || Meditate the Scripture daily verse by verse
 
Experience the Magic of Saint Martin and Sint Maarten with Find American Rent...
Experience the Magic of Saint Martin and Sint Maarten with Find American Rent...Experience the Magic of Saint Martin and Sint Maarten with Find American Rent...
Experience the Magic of Saint Martin and Sint Maarten with Find American Rent...
 
Hire 💕 8617697112 Chamba Call Girls Service Call Girls Agency
Hire 💕 8617697112 Chamba Call Girls Service Call Girls AgencyHire 💕 8617697112 Chamba Call Girls Service Call Girls Agency
Hire 💕 8617697112 Chamba Call Girls Service Call Girls Agency
 
BERMUDA Triangle the mystery of life.pptx
BERMUDA Triangle the mystery of life.pptxBERMUDA Triangle the mystery of life.pptx
BERMUDA Triangle the mystery of life.pptx
 
Rohini Sector 18 Call Girls Delhi 9999965857 @Sabina Saikh No Advance
Rohini Sector 18 Call Girls Delhi 9999965857 @Sabina Saikh No AdvanceRohini Sector 18 Call Girls Delhi 9999965857 @Sabina Saikh No Advance
Rohini Sector 18 Call Girls Delhi 9999965857 @Sabina Saikh No Advance
 
visa consultant | 📞📞 03094429236 || Best Study Visa Consultant
visa consultant | 📞📞 03094429236 || Best Study Visa Consultantvisa consultant | 📞📞 03094429236 || Best Study Visa Consultant
visa consultant | 📞📞 03094429236 || Best Study Visa Consultant
 
Call Girls Service !! New Friends Colony!! @9999965857 Delhi 🫦 No Advance VV...
Call Girls Service !! New Friends Colony!! @9999965857 Delhi 🫦 No Advance  VV...Call Girls Service !! New Friends Colony!! @9999965857 Delhi 🫦 No Advance  VV...
Call Girls Service !! New Friends Colony!! @9999965857 Delhi 🫦 No Advance VV...
 
Visa Consultant in Lahore || 📞03094429236
Visa Consultant in Lahore || 📞03094429236Visa Consultant in Lahore || 📞03094429236
Visa Consultant in Lahore || 📞03094429236
 
best weekend places near delhi where you should visit.pdf
best weekend places near delhi where you should visit.pdfbest weekend places near delhi where you should visit.pdf
best weekend places near delhi where you should visit.pdf
 
💕📲09602870969💓Girl Escort Services Udaipur Call Girls in Chittorgarh Haldighati
💕📲09602870969💓Girl Escort Services Udaipur Call Girls in Chittorgarh Haldighati💕📲09602870969💓Girl Escort Services Udaipur Call Girls in Chittorgarh Haldighati
💕📲09602870969💓Girl Escort Services Udaipur Call Girls in Chittorgarh Haldighati
 
08448380779 Call Girls In Chhattarpur Women Seeking Men
08448380779 Call Girls In Chhattarpur Women Seeking Men08448380779 Call Girls In Chhattarpur Women Seeking Men
08448380779 Call Girls In Chhattarpur Women Seeking Men
 
🔥HOT🔥📲9602870969🔥Prostitute Service in Udaipur Call Girls in City Palace Lake...
🔥HOT🔥📲9602870969🔥Prostitute Service in Udaipur Call Girls in City Palace Lake...🔥HOT🔥📲9602870969🔥Prostitute Service in Udaipur Call Girls in City Palace Lake...
🔥HOT🔥📲9602870969🔥Prostitute Service in Udaipur Call Girls in City Palace Lake...
 
Hire 💕 8617697112 Champawat Call Girls Service Call Girls Agency
Hire 💕 8617697112 Champawat Call Girls Service Call Girls AgencyHire 💕 8617697112 Champawat Call Girls Service Call Girls Agency
Hire 💕 8617697112 Champawat Call Girls Service Call Girls Agency
 

Linking Value Chain Analysis and the ““Making Markets work better for the Poor”” Concept

  • 1. Linking Value Jörg Meyer-Stamer Chain Analysis and jms@mesopartner.com the ““Making Frank Wältring Markets work fw@mesopartner.com better for the Poor”” Concept Final Version Duisburg and Dortmund February 2007 Paper prepared for the Pilot Project “Innovative Approaches to Private Sector Development”
  • 2. Content 1 Purpose of this paper 1 2 “Making market systems work better for the poor” and “Value Chain Promotion”: What is it about? 1 3 Concepts and methodologies 3 3.1 M4P 3 3.1.1 Weaknesses of the M4P approach 6 3.2 Value Chains 7 3.2.1 Types of value chains 8 3.2.2 Value chains and donor interventions 9 3.2.3 Weaknesses of the value chain approach 11 3.3 Interim conclusion 12 4 How to link M4P + VC: Conceptual considerations 13 4.1 Value chains 13 4.1.1 Value chain differentiation 13 4.1.2 Value chain and territory 17 4.1.3 Value chains and markets 19 4.2 Making markets work 20 4.2.1 M4P and P4M 23 4.2.2 Understanding market failure 24 4.3 Who are “the poor”? 25 5 How to link M4P and VC analysis: Practical considerations 27 5.1 Analysis before action 27 5.2 Action research 29 5.2.1 Selecting a target group for a pro-poor value chain promotion project 30 5.2.2 Launching a pro-poor value chain promotion project 31 6 Conclusion 36 7 Bibliography 37
  • 3. III Figures Figure 1: The market concept of the M4P literature .................................................................3 Figure 2: Simplified structure of the pepper and cloves value chains in Sri Lanka..............................................................................................................................14 Figure 3: Structure of the pepper value chain in Sri Lanka ....................................................15 Figure 4: Downstream part of the cinnamon value chain in Sri Lanka ...................................16 Figure 5: The Commodity Chain of the Knitwear Industry in Santa Catarina, Brazil ..............................................................................................................................17 Figure 6: The Cluster and the Value Chain perspective.........................................................18 Figure 7: The 2 Pillars of Value Chain Promotion ..................................................................19 Figure 8: The Context of Poverty and Micro-Enterprise Development...................................26 Figure 9: The USAID approach to value chain promotion......................................................28 Figure 10: The spiral model of sequencing in the EU LEADER programme..........................30 Figure 11: Initial Sequence for a Pro-Poor Value Chain Initiative ..........................................32 Figure 12 ................................................................................................................................35
  • 4. Summary The main concern in development cooperation today is to achieve a bigger impact on poverty alleviation. This refers to all arenas, including private sector development. The conceptual discussion on private sector development has recently addressed the question of how to create an enabling environment and make markets work, and in particular make markets work better for the poor. At the same time, practical activities in private sector development are addressing value chains, something that reflects realities of private companies that are constantly battling to find markets for their products, and access to markets is often organ- ised through value chains. At first glance, the “Making Market Systems Work Better for the Poor” approach (M4P) and the value chain approach appear to be incompatible. However, a closer look reveals that the M4P literature paints a differentiated picture of markets, which is informed by the analysis of real markets, particularly rural markets. It stands for a pragmatic approach that can give im- portant inputs for conceptual development for value chain approaches. At the same time, it is important not to merge the M4P and the value chain approaches, since this would compro- mise many of their respective strengths. Value chain projects sometimes spend a lot of time and effort on research before going into practical activities. We suggest that there is little point in introducing M4P into a research- focused approach to value chain development, since this might lead to enormously complex, resource-intensive and lengthy research projects. Instead, we suggest a process-oriented approach to value chain development that involves strong elements of action research. We suggest that there is a good opportunity to introduce M4P elements into such an approach. Acknowledgements This paper has benefit tremendously from the discussions at a workshop in Hanoi in Novem- ber 2006. We greatfully acknowledge the comments and suggestions made by Alan Johnson and Dominic Smith (ADB/DFID M4P project), Kees van der Ree, Bas Rozemuller and Marije Boomsma (ILO), Michael van den Berg (SNV), Ellen Kramer and Khan Nha (GTZ Poverty Reduction project), and Thomas Finkel, Angelika Hutter, Vu Nhu Quynh and Pham Ngoc Tram (GTZ SME project). Useful comments on earlier draft versions were given by Sabine Becker, Shawn Cunningham, Doug Hindson and Peter Richter. The usual disclaimers apply.
  • 5. 1 Purpose of this paper The initial intention behind this paper was to verify whether it makes sense to connect the literature on value chain analysis and the literature on “Making mar- ket systems work better for the poor” (M4P) in order to develop an analytical in- strument that makes value chain promotion more pro-poor. In the course of the work it became clear that the M4P concept is work in progress. Thus, this paper turned out to be a contribution to the evolving conceptualisation of M4P as well. A draft version of the paper was finished in the first semester of 2006. The concept outlined in that paper was discussed with M4P and value chain practitioners in a workshop in Hanoi in November 2006. An M4P-informed value chain analysis was conducted in December 2006 in Vietnam’s Dak Lak province through the Vietnamese-German project “Support for Poverty Reduction” which is managed by the Ministry of Labour, Invalids and Social Affairs (MOLISA) and GTZ. The paper is organised as follows. Section 2 gives a brief introduction to the two concepts, and Section 3 has a closer look at them. In Section 4, we discuss con- ceptual issues involved in the connection between value chain analysis and making market systems work better for the poor. In Section 5, we outline a practi- cal approache to analyse value chains in an action-oriented way that is informed by both approaches. 2 “Making market systems work better for the poor” and “Value Chain Promotion”: What is it about? The starting point of this paper are two lines of conceptualisation and develop- ment practice that have recently started to converge: “Making market systems work better for the poor (M4P)” and “Value Chain Promotion” (VCP). Both ap- proaches address the issue of private sector development, including promotion of small producers in rural areas, from specific angles and against specific patterns of conceptual evolution. M4P has evolved from the BDS discussion of the late 1990s. The BDS discus- sion was based on the observation that the established donor approach for pri- vate sector development was not particularly effective. One of the main deficien- cies was the fact that it ignored existing business service markets, and indeed often created unfair competition to existing service providers through subsidised governmental business promotion programmes and organisations. The traditional approach to business development was a typical example of the donor approach analysed by Pritchett and Woolcock: “need as the problem, supply as the solu- tion, civil service as the instrument” (Pritchett and Woolcock 2004, 193). With the BDS approach, the pendulum swung to the other extreme, emphasising the need
  • 6. 2 Jörg Meyer-Stamer and Frank Wältring for market development yet not clearly defining the role of government in this process. Today, “BDS market development terminology is fading in favor of vo- cabulary that explains how market development can help the poor benefit from economic growth. What was understood as BDS markets are increasingly called business service markets, commercially viable solutions, or support markets” (Miehlbradt and McVay 2005, 2). M4P shares with BDS the emphasis on market development, but it has at the same time a wider and a less clearly defined scope. VCP has in recent years evolved from the subsector approach. To some extent it was driven by practitioners’ insight in the need to connect producers to the mar- ket, and indeed understanding and verifying the target market before engaging in upgrading activities with producers and manufacturers. To some extent it is in- formed by the academic literature on global value chains, i.e. dense networks that often involve retailers and other big corporations in industrialised countries and a huge number of suppliers all over the world. The emergence of value chains is primarily driven by the market. Development practitioners have ob- served this process and spotted an opportunity. The value chain approach has received a particularly strong impulse from the discussion on rural and agricul- tural development, as decreasing transport and communication costs have stimulated the emergence of value chains that connect producers of fresh fruit and vegetables, processors and packaging houses in developing countries, and supermarkets in industrialised countries. Research showed that poor smallhold- ers can in principle be integrated into such value chains, thus raising the expec- tation that value chain promotion can have a direct pro-poor effect (Dolan, Hum- phrey and Harris-Pascal 1999). At first glance, the rationale for connecting these two approaches may not appear particularly convincing. First, there seems to be an intrinsic problem with the M4P approach. Markets are about allocation, not about distribution. While “making market systems work better” is a plausible proposition, “... for the poor” appar- ently is not. The M4P literature overcomes this problem by looking at market systems, i.e. the interaction between markets and other forms of allocation, nota- bly hierarchy (i.e. through government interventions or by the activities of major corporations). Moreover, the “better” is not to be understood in the sense of “better for the poor than for everybody else” but rather in the sense of “better than so far”. The M4P literature points out that markets are often rigged in a way that benefits only a small group of already well-off, and that levelling the playing field creates new opportunities for the not-so-rich. Second, value chains are not primarily about markets. The literature on global value chains has pointed out that the main reason why such chains exist is the fact that the market rarely works properly. Transactions in global value chains tend to be complex, information can only partially be codified, and suppliers will often face limitations with respect to their capacity to respond to the requirements of global buyers (Gereffi, Humphrey and Sturgeon 2005). In other words, global value chains as relatively stable, coherent structures exist because they are su- perior to anonymous markets. However, from a development policy angle, global
  • 7. Linking Value Chain Promotion and the M4P Concept 3 value chains still look much more like market arrangements than like anything else, and when it comes to promoting value chains one would try to rely on mar- ket adjustment as much as possible. 3 Concepts and methodologies 3.1 M4P The M4P approach has been promoted in particular by DFID, SIDA and the Asian Development Bank. With the M4P approach, they aspire to make their private sector development approach more pro-poor, thus aligning it with the Millenium Development Goals. The market concept of the M4P literature is summarised in the following figure. Figure 1: The market concept of the M4P literature Source: Presentation given by Marshall Bear, November 2005 What this figure tries to depict is the fact that the functioning of markets depends on two sets of factors. Intangible factors (lower semicircle) include formal and in- formal rules. Tangible factors include infrastructure and other services (upper
  • 8. 4 Jörg Meyer-Stamer and Frank Wältring semicircle). Both tangible and intangible factors are shaped by government, the private sector and its organisations, the third sector, and informal networks (outer circle). A specific element of M4P in this respect is the focus on institutions. What is meant by this? Let us quote the explanation given by Ferrand, Gibson and Scott (2004, 14 f): “What are the most important formal rules impinging on the market and the poor? How do they impact on the market? These include: Generally applicable rules such as contract, property, consumer protection, weights and measures, health and safety, competition and tax laws. These are not market- specific but may be most important in shaping markets. Sector-specific rules such as banking law, electricity and telecommunications acts and land use and ownership laws. Non-statutory regulations such as industry codes of good conduct, quality standards and registers. What (and who) are the most important formal mechanisms for enforcement of rules? How do they impact on the market? This includes, for example, commercial justice institutions, government systems of regu- lation, inspection and licensing, inland revenue authorities, company and land registries, industry regulators, local government tax offices, and self-regulation mechanisms in busi- ness associations. What are the most important informal institutions impinging on the market? How do they impact on the market? The actual way in which rules are interpreted and applied is often shaped more by social norms and practices as much as the letter of the law. Where formal rules and their appli- cation are weak, the business environment is governed by the informal. For example, the general impracticality of commercial and contract law often means that business transac- tions become focused within established networks. In Africa, it is recognised widely that existing networks and trust – arising from particular conditions – is a key hindrance to trading and to collaborative business arrangements. While in Asia many networks of small business have developed – to permit flexible production specialisation – in Africa this is less common. Overall, when the formal rules surrounding markets are weak and informal institutions are not supportive of business transactions, the environment for mar- kets is significantly dysfunctional.” In a development policy perspective, the M4P approach effectively distinguishes three intervention levels (e.g. DFID 2005): 1. The micro level, where the focus is at creating functioning markets and effec- tive BDS structures. 2. The meso level, which, though it remains conceptually somewhat fuzzy, con- sists of para-governmental structures that are funded by external donors and that substitute defunct or ineffective national government structures in devel- oping countries.
  • 9. Linking Value Chain Promotion and the M4P Concept 5 3. The macro level of generic framework conditions, in particular the legal framework and the rules and regulation that guide its delivery. The argument of the M4P concept can be summarised in two points: Development-oriented interventions need to create effective markets, rather than distorting or substituting them in the way traditional donor interventions often did. This point takes the key insight of the BDS approach as its point of departure and applies it in a more comprehensive manner. Those market adjustment activities must be prioritised that have a strong pro- poor effect. The M4P approach emphasises the need for systematic research in this respect. The first argument is close to the one made by Meyer-Stamer (2001, 23) who ar- gues that a significant part of meso-level interventions is temporary in nature and needs to be designed in a way that does not compromise the phasing-out of in- terventions as a given market begins to work effectively. The M4P approach ne- glects the corollary emphasised by Meyer-Stamer, namely that some meso-level interventions are permanent in nature since the market will never take care of them; typical examples include, for instance, some activities in the field of quality assurance, certification, testing and calibration. In the body of literature on M4P, Dorward and Kydd (2005, 16 ff) relate to this line of reasoning. They observe that it can be entirely unrealistic, and indeed self- defeating, to take the principle of making markets work too far. They highlight the fact that highly fragmented markets can lead to prohibitively high transaction costs while at the same time creating barriers to entry that reinforce critical bot- tlenecks. One of the examples they provide is “asset specificity”. If an entrepre- neur buys a truck to transport mangoes, but it turns out that there are not many mangoes to be transported, she can still use the truck to transport, say, bricks. But if an entrepreneur invests in a highly specialised canning operation for man- goes, the absence of mangoes creates a serious problem. Therefore, in a com- petitive market with high information cost and little direct communication between market participants, entrepreneurs may hesitate to invest into anything that dis- plays a high asset specificity. Dorward and Kydd present hierarchies, be they government institutions or private sector organisations, as a necessary comple- ment to markets. The way they conceptualise hierarchies, for instance as corpo- rations that organise various stages in a value chain or organise outgrower op- erations, relates to the literature on value chains, though they do not make this connection explicit. The M4P approach emphasises the need for analysis. According to DFID (2005, 19), “the M4P approach will draw upon the following types of data: Poverty reports including household surveys and PPA surveys. Specific market and transactions studies using participatory and other tech- niques to complement existing poverty data.
  • 10. 6 Jörg Meyer-Stamer and Frank Wältring ‘Doing Business’ and Investment Climate Surveys. Trade, production and price data. Market outcomes and data from the operation of value chains. The rate and direction of the evolution of key markets for the poor, especially the: – process of market deepening and the expansion of the access frontier; – crossing of key thresholds for participation, outreach, choice, economies of scale and sustainability; and – effects of cross market linkages.” In other words, the M4P approach involves a rather comprehensive effort in con- ducting studies, more comprehensive indeed than the already quite comprehen- sive “BDS market assessments” of the recent past. 3.1.1 Weaknesses of the M4P approach The M4P approach is still at an early stage of conceptual development, and it is still searching answers to important conceptual as well as practical issues. Conceptual weaknesses: The market The key issue in the concept, the market, remains fuzzy. From an economics perspective, the different types of market failure and the reasons for their exis- tence are not discussed in a systematic way. Similar to the BDS approach, mar- kets are discussed in an inductive way, and the analysis of markets is informed by concepts from a business administration perspective, not a microeconomics perspective. The M4P discussion may have something to learn from the discus- sion on privatisation in this respect; for instance, Brücker and Hillebrand (1996) offer an excellent overview of market failure and options in addressing it. From a social science perspective, the issue of “embeddedness” of markets (Granovetter 1992) in social structures is something that should be elaborated much stronger and more consistently in the M4P literature (see also Platteau 1994). Conceptual weaknesses: The poor The M4P literature is somewhat blurred when it comes to “the poor”. It neither in- troduces different levels of poverty, from relative income poverty to absolute des- titution, nor does it explicitly explain whether it is based on a static or dynamic concept of poverty. In fact, it avoids one of the prominent concepts in poverty re-
  • 11. Linking Value Chain Promotion and the M4P Concept 7 search, namely exclusion. This is somewhat puzzling since “making markets work for the poor” can to some extent be translated into “integrating poor into markets”, i.e. taking direct action to address exclusion. Conceptual weaknesses: Government In the way it is summarised in the most recent concept paper (DFID 2005), the M4P concept fails to address the issue of sustainability of intervention vehicles / structures for market alignment. It establishes high requirements on the effective- ness of government structures, yet delivers no visible contribution to strengthen- ing government structures. In fact, existing government structures in partner countries are effectively sidelined with programmes like ComMark in Southern Af- rica. In Nigeria, PrOpCom acts like any meso-institution anywhere that has de- cided to build a powerful value chain on the basis of currently weak, fragmented structures, very similar to what, say, Scottish Enterprise has done since 1999 in its “Scottish Food & Drink” initiative, except that at some stage PrOpCom will terminate, while new types of market failure will continue to emerge. Practical issues While emphasising the relevance of market failure and the need for market ad- justment tools, the M4P literature so far does not provide any tools that would permit efficient analysis of market failure. A development practitioner who needs to prepare Terms of Reference for a consultant who is supposed to analyse mar- ket failure is pretty much left to her own devices. The M4P literature names some types of market failure, such as public goods and externalities, market power and economies of scale, asymmetric information, and costs of establishing and en- forcing agreements (DFID 2005, 6). However, we have not been able to locate a toolkit that would guide practitioners in identifying market failure, understanding the underlying reasons, and finding efficient and sustainable means of address- ing it. 3.2 Value Chains Both academic research and development practitioners have for a number of years been addressing “value chains”. A value chain is the sequence of activities involved in transforming raw materials into a product that is acquired by the final customer. It includes business activities from the generation of raw materials, to transforming them into intermediate products, to manufacturing the final product. It includes business transactions, but also transactions between companies and governments (e.g. the bureaucracy involved in transborder trade), and transac- tions between companies and supporting institutions in areas like finance, train- ing, research and development, metrology and certification, and others.
  • 12. 8 Jörg Meyer-Stamer and Frank Wältring A value chain can be relatively straightforward, for instance in the case of the or- ganic vegetable value chain, where rural producers, intermediates and proces- sors / packaging houses, and wholesalers and retailers are involved. A value chain can be extremely complex, for instance in the case of a passenger car or a personal computer, or in fact in footwear or garments, where producers in various countries across the globe interact. Value chains exist at the subnational regional level, the national level, and the global level. In subnational regions, value chains are difficult to distinguish from “clusters”; in fact, some development agencies use the terms “cluster” and “value chain” interchangeably. Most of the academic literature on value chains ad- dresses them at the global level. How are value chains different from supply chains? They are not. What is differ- ent is the angle of analysis. The supply chain literature is rooted in industrial en- gineering faculties and business schools. The guiding question of the supply chain literature is: How can a company manage its supply chain more efficiently, and create a competitive advantage through unique and more efficient supply chain management? Examples for best practice in supply chain management in- clude retailers like Wal-Mart and Ikea, who are not only capable of spotting low- price / good quality producers across the globe but also highly skilled in organis- ing the logistics along their value chain in such a way that cost efficiency is high, lead times are short, and working capital requirements are low. The value chain literature is rooted in development studies and sociology. It started from the observation that agricultural and industrial development proc- esses in developing countries increasingly are based on interaction with lead firms in industrialised countries. The concern of this body of literature is not with the efficiency of lead firms such as Wal-Mart or Ikea but rather with the develop- ment prospects of companies that are dependent on Wal-Mart or Ikea for their export sales, and that are thus integrated into the global economy in a dependent way. The main focus is at the analysis of power structures in the world economy. 3.2.1 Types of value chains The current state of research on value chains (in particular global value chains, but its findings to a large extent apply to national-level value chains as well) dis- tinguishes four types of value chains (Schmitz 2005, 6): 1. “Arm’s length market relations. Buyer and supplier do not need to develop close relationships because the product is standardised or easily customised. A range of firms can meet the buyer's requirements. When problems arise buyers move on to different suppliers. 2. Modular networks. Firms develop information-intensive relationships, divid- ing essential competences between them. The buyer provides the design and product specification and highly competent suppliers provide products and
  • 13. Linking Value Chain Promotion and the M4P Concept 9 services at short notice to any kind of specification drawing on the specialisa- tions in their cluster. Information intensity is high, transactional dependence is low, and confidence in supplier competence is high. 3. Captive networks. In this case, one firm exercises a high degree of control over other firms in the chain. In garment and footwear chains, buyers often specify the characteristics of the product to be made by their suppliers, spec- ify the processes to be followed and inspect that these specifications are fol- lowed. Typically this occurs when the buyer has doubts about the compe- tence of the supply chain. 4. Hierarchy. The lead firm takes direct ownership of some operations in the chain. The case of the intra-firm trade between a trans-national company and its subsidiaries falls into this category.” Recent research on global value chains has primarily looked at Type 2 and Type 3 value chains, i.e. value chains that are neither market based nor organised within a multinational firm. Such value chains exist because the market does not work (market failure) and an intra-firm setup would involve prohibitive transaction costs and constant problems with principal-agent issues. Let us look at these two issues in some more detail: Market failure: What is traded in global value chains are non-commodity products, i.e. products that are produced according to specific parameters. Some of these parameters are specifically defined by the buyer, for instance designs. A key issue here is that the buyer cannot fully codify its requirements but needs ongoing communication with the supplier to explain what exactly is wanted. Other parameters are features such as quality criteria, compliance with environmental or social standards, and others. So far, experience has shown that international standards such as ISO 9000, ISO 14000, and SA 8000 cannot guarantee that suppliers meet the requirements of buyers, so that buyers tend to prefer direct interaction and control. Hierarchy, transaction cost, principal-agent problems: Over the past two dec- ades, there has been a strong tendency away from the Chandlerian model of company evolution, i.e. major integrated corporations, since experience showed that a model of a company that focused at its core competencies and outsourced many non-core activities was more efficient. This was due to lower transaction costs in coordinating inter-company relationships, some- thing that was more efficient that one integrated company with a bloated in- ternal bureaucracy, as well as the absence of the principal-agent issues common in big, spatially scattered corporate organisations. 3.2.2 Value chains and donor interventions The value chain issue has been taken up be donor agencies, which perceive them both as a risk and an opportunity. The risk lies in the fact that developing
  • 14. 10 Jörg Meyer-Stamer and Frank Wältring country producers cannot be integrated into global markets if they cannot meet the requirements of value chains lead firms regarding cost, quality, certification, quantity, and timely delivery. The chance lies in the fact that connecting devel- oping country producers to the world market can be easier if the donor agency manages to build a direct relationship with a value chain lead firm. In fact, donors recently have started to work directly with value chains, i.e. by en- gaging with the lead firms / global buyers, for instance in a number of GTZ- managed public-private partnership projects. To some extent, this was driven by a combination of global buyer’s concern with corporate social responsibility (in particular the desire not to appear as culprits for miserably labour conditions in sweat shops, or being linked to child labour) and donor organisations’ concern to improve the productivity levels in companies that are part of value chains so that they reap greater benefits, including higher wages and better working conditions. Various donor organisations have formulated approaches for value chain analy- sis. While having some features in common, existing approaches to value chain analysis demonstrate a number of specific differences. They are summarised in the table in Annex 1. Identifying the similarities and differences within existing value chain analysis approaches does not become obvious by casting a quick glance. Many of them are integrated into wider market or demand assessments or integrated into LRED, BDS, Enabling Environment, PPP, BDS or cluster de- velopment activities. Similarities in the approaches There are certain similarities among the different value chain analysis ap- proaches: Most of the approaches combine the analysis of the chain with the analysis of interventions. The sequence of an analysis usually includes the following steps: identifica- tion of the subsector, analysis of the chain linkages, analysis of the market, analysis of potentials, analysis of constraints, analysis of solutions, analysis of interventions. Nearly all of the approaches apply criteria that in general are including in- crease of competitiveness, employment effects and sustainability. There is a tendency especially in approaches of donors to integrate partici- patory elements and to use the value chain analysis also to identify potential partner organisations or lead firms. Often activities that have started at the governmental level include very study- and less participatory-based ap- proaches, e.g. to design a national export strategy. There is a trend towards incremental analysis approaches, often based on larger baseline studies.
  • 15. Linking Value Chain Promotion and the M4P Concept 11 Differences in donor approaches There are differences with respect to engaging the stakeholders and the target group, in the way of planning interventions, with regard to the time sequence of analysis and intervention and in the combination of value chain analysis with other approaches. Regarding the latter point, it is common to find mixed ap- proaches that combine and complement value chain analysis with other devel- opment approaches (Cluster, value chains, PPP, LED, investment promotion, OD, EE, BDS). Examples are many GTZ projects but also other donor organisa- tions that follow a systemic approach which goes beyond the focus on interfirm- linkages and BDS and that analyse interventions in a more integrated cross- cutting form (e.g. Vietnam, Sri Lanka). Regarding planning and sequencing, there are two fundamentally different types of approaches: Incremental approaches that analyse parts of the chain on a continuous base to identify further opportunities for donor intervention. Many projects that started with large studies subsequently focused on more specific sub-areas (e.g. AfE in Bangladesh with the KATALYST project). Other approaches start already with participatory research that involves different stakeholders through workshops and interviews (stakeholders usually come from the pol- icy, social and economic sphere) with the objective to initiate an iterative pro- cess of planning / implementing / assessing / planning. Planning approaches that follow a step-by-step procedure from information gathering, sub-sector selection, identification of constraints, identification of intervention approaches towards planning and implementing interventions. These approaches often take longer until they reach implementation. They often also do not include the stakeholders in the final planning process of in- terventions (AfE, IDE, …). Finally, it is noteworthy that while all approaches focus at the need to increase competitiveness, some are primarily looking at livelihood improvement (e.g. IDE). 3.2.3 Weaknesses of the value chain approach The academic value chain literature addresses global value chains. It typically looks at products that are produced in developing countries and consumed in in- dustrialised countries, from Kenyan fresh vegetables to Mexican blue jeans to Taiwanese computers. It analyses producers in developing countries that are al- ready highly competitive; the fact that they are able to consistently satisfy the so- phisticated demand of leading companies in industrialised countries bears wit- ness of this. However, only occasionally does the value chain literature trace the evolution of producers in developing countries and the stages that preceded their integration into global value chains. The exact mechanisms of how producers in developing countries become integrated into global value chains are not at all clear. What exactly happens before producers appear on the radar screen of global buyers, how first contact is established and how the initial interaction goes is not well understood. In this respect, the literature is only of limited value to
  • 16. 12 Jörg Meyer-Stamer and Frank Wältring practitioners who want to upgrade producers in developing countries so that they appear on the radar screen of global buyers. In the practitioner literature, there appears to be a tendency to ignore the differ- ences between Taiwanese computer manufacturers and, say, Guatemalan handicraft producers. There seems to be an assumption that pretty much any producer anywhere can in principle be integrated into global value chains. This is a repetition of a misunderstanding that came up in the discussion on cluster de- velopment and promotion some years ago, where we have shown that concepts that have been developed in settings with highly competitive industries cannot easily be transferred to survivalist sectors (Altenburg and Meyer-Stamer 1999). 3.3 Interim conclusion Value chain promotion is concerned with competitiveness of producers. It aims at connecting producers in developing countries with markets, be it nationally or globally. Value chain promotion, as conducted by donor agencies, is implicitly pro-poor in that it focuses at groups of producers who will not spontaneously link up with external buyers because of too wide a gap between their supply capacity and the demands of buyers, which may be a result of insufficient skills, an unfa- vourable, peripheral location, a disabling environment, or other factors. The M4P approach is concerned with market adjustment. It is explicitly pro-poor. It aims at improving the effectiveness of market mechanisms, so that barriers to entry are lowered and more economic opportunities are created. Moreover, more effective markets are expected to lead to lower prices and thus an increase in the effective purchasing power of poor. VCP and M4P look at development challenges from different angles. One might expect M4P to be very generic (though the examples mentioned in the M4P lit- erature are not), and VCP to be highly specific. However, M4P does not only look at market adjustment from a macro-economic perspective, in the way the “ena- bling environment” approach does. It also addresses the micro- and mesolevels. From this angle, one can argue that VCP and M4P are complementary and can be connected. One element that must be highlighted is the fact that the M4P literature explicitly addresses different markets – not only product markets, but also factor markets, for instance the labour market. This is an element that only appears in an indirect, implicit way in the value chain literature and practice. The labour market is un- doubtedly one of the most important markets in terms of making the economy more pro-poor. Distortions in the labour market are one of the most important reasons for persistent marginalisation and poverty (Granovetter 2005), not only in developing countries but also, for instance, in the U.S. (Rosenfeld 2002). Ad- dressing the labour market, as well as other factors markets, in VCP in a consis- tent and systematic way may be a promising way of making it more pro-poor.
  • 17. Linking Value Chain Promotion and the M4P Concept 13 So the conclusion is this: M4P can inform VC work, but the two should not be merged. M4P and VC overlap. M4P covers issues like labour markets, which are not systematically addressed in VC. VC has an explicit focus at supranational is- sues, which are beyond the scope of M4P. 4 How to link M4P + VC: Conceptual considerations In this section we will highlight a number of issues that so far are not adequately addressed in the M4P and the VCP literature. We will indicate a number of con- cepts and strands of academic discussion that may help in creating a sounder foundation for both approaches. 4.1 Value chains 4.1.1 Value chain differentiation The “value chain” metaphor is valuable in more than one sense. Not only is a chain a relatively flexible structure that will change its form frequently without changing the basic structure. There is also one physical feature of a chain: It is impossible to move it by pushing it. The only way to move a chain is by pulling. Translating this metaphor takes us to the main difference between VCP and tra- ditional approaches. The latter often had a tendency to strengthen the supply ca- pacity of producers and small companies without having a confirmed order, i.e. they assumed that a market would be available, which sometimes was the case and often not. VCP starts from an understanding of the final demand and works its way back through distribution channels to the different stages of production and manufacturing. That is, proper VCP does this. There are also VCP interven- tions which effectively are re-labelled sector activities, sometimes based on a terminological and conceptual confusion around the terms sector, subsector and value chain: Among development practitioners, sectors are commonly understood along the lines of the International Standard Industry Classification, i.e. the food sector, the metalworking sector, the textile sector, etc. It is also not rare to find that, for instance, microenterprises are addressed as a sector, and “in- formal sector” is a firmly established term that indicates yet a different ap- proach to classification. The different sector definitions reflect different inter- ests. The ISIC classification is guided by the interest of statistical offices to organise the complex reality of an economy in a way that is practical for data collection and presentation. The microenterprise definition is guided by the interests of policy makers who perceive a type of enterprise to be systemati- cally disadvantaged and who need criteria to define those businesses that will benefit, for instance, from simplified tax payments. The informal sector defini- tion was originally driven by the interest to highlight dismal working conditions
  • 18. 14 Jörg Meyer-Stamer and Frank Wältring in a particular type of business. None of these definitions makes much sense in the context of targeted business promotion activities, though. Subsectors have been defined as “all the firms that buy and sell from each other in order to supply a particular set of products or services to final con- sumers” (Lusby and Panlibuton 2002, iv). This definition is somewhere in between the sector terminology and the value chain concept. At first glance, it appears to be quite similar to the value chain definition. Unlike the value chain, though, it does not define economic activities from the perspective of the final consumer, and this establishes a crucial difference between “sub- sector” and “value chain”. From a practitioner’s perspective, proper VCP, based on a genuine effort to un- derstand the structure of a value chain starting at the final customer, has a big disadvantage. It tends to involve a hugely complex system that is very difficult to address for any practical purposes. This is not a new discovery. Long before the term “value chain” in the way it is used in this paper was coined, when research- ers were still talking about “networks”, they detected that one “sector” in one re- gion can involve a variety of different structures that are only loosely interrelated. Silicon Valley, for instance, is not one value chain but actually several, each with different final customers, internal structures and challenges regarding upgrading (Storper and Harrison 1991). At first glance, a value chain appears to be a very straightforward affair. Simpli- fied value chain maps usually look like the one depicted in Figure 2. Figure 2: Simplified structure of the pepper and cloves value chains in Sri Lanka This figure is taken from a presentation on the experiences of a GTZ VCP project in Sri Lanka. A more detailed, yet still simplified map of the pepper value chain looks as depicted in Figure 3. This and the following figure have been elaborated in stakeholder workshops of the GTZ Value Chain Project in Sri Lanka.
  • 19. Linking Value Chain Promotion and the M4P Concept 15 Figure 3: Structure of the pepper value chain in Sri Lanka
  • 20. 16 Jörg Meyer-Stamer and Frank Wältring This is still a relative straightforward picture, which is mostly due to the fact that the distribution channels and final customers of Sri Lankan pepper are not par- ticularly diversified. Things look quite different for the cinnamon value chain, which serves quite different final customers. Figure 4: Downstream part of the cinnamon value chain in Sri Lanka Cinnamon is not only used as a kitchen spice. It is also an input for the pharma- ceutical and fragrance industries. So far, Sri Lankan producers have not really tapped into these markets. But as they will develop a capacity to establish link- ages with such customers, the map of the Sri Lankan cinnamon value chain will become significantly more complex, since different needs and demands of final customers will lead to a segmentation of value chains inside Sri Lanka (which are not captured in Figure 4). Similarly, research that we conducted in Brazil in the second half of the 1990s on a textiles and garments value chain in the Vale do Itajaí region showed a picture of four distinct patterns of industrial organisation, feeding into five different distri- bution channels. At first glance, one might have expected one value chain. How- ever, the reality is much more complex. This has important consequences for any
  • 21. Linking Value Chain Promotion and the M4P Concept 17 effort in upgrading, since different segments of the industry have quite different requirements. In other words, in order to upgrade the textile and garments sector in this region, one would have to launch not one but several value chain initia- tives, each of them addressing one specific value chain. Most companies would only be part of one value chain initiatives, while other players, such as skills de- velopment or technology institutions, might have to be involved in four or five value chain initiatives at the same time. Figure 5: The Commodity Chain of the Knitwear Industry in Santa Catarina, Brazil Source: Meyer-Stamer 1998 What is the conclusion from this line of argument? Value chains tend to be highly complex systems. An effort to analyse them in a systematic way will thus tend to involve a very significant research effort. It is important to note that not only the purpose but also the scope of VCP-related research would be different from a typical academic GVC research project. GVC research focuses at the issue of power imbalances in the international economy. It often takes individual retailers, or narrowly defined final customers, as its starting point. A VCP project cannot afford this kind of focused perspective but rather has to take a much broader look. A GVC researcher would be satisfied with a paper that investigates the connections between French fragrance manufacturers and Sri Lankan cinnamon producers. For somebody who is supposed to do spice value chain promotion in Sri Lanka, this would only be one piece of a much bigger puzzle. In other words, value chain initiatives need to be managed carefully so that they don’t get out of hand. 4.1.2 Value chain and territory Value chains do not per se have a territorial dimension. Obviously, each element has a location. But the defining feature of the value chain is the pattern of con- nection between various producers, services and customers. The following pic- ture captures this aspect by comparing the value chain approach with the cluster approach. Cluster promotion and value chain promotion are not profoundly differ-
  • 22. 18 Jörg Meyer-Stamer and Frank Wältring ent in terms of the objectives and instruments. The main difference is the clear territorial focus in cluster promotion, whereas VCP involves a functional focus. Figure 6: The Cluster and the Value Chain perspective Source: own design Nevertheless, practical experience seems to indicate that it makes sense to have a closer look at the territorial dimension of VCP. The purpose of a VCP analysis is to have a very clear idea regarding the upgrading necessities of local produc- ers that for whatever reason have become the object of a donor project or a do- mestic development initiative. The upgrading effort would not relate to some anonymous market but rather the very specific demands of lead firms in a given value chain. Integrating domestic firms into global value chains involves two dif- ferent types of challenges. One of them is related to territorial issues; the other one are national framework factors. Regarding national-level factors, one of the issues that often comes up in VCP projects are supply chain issues. Exports of fresh products are hampered by the absence of cooling facilities at the main airport. Exports of all sorts of products are hampered by clumsy and unpredictable procedures at ports. Exporters find it difficult and/or very costly to have their products tested and certified. Communi- cation between suppliers and customers suffers from slow and unreliable Internet connections. Such issues are generic in nature. They need to be addressed at the national level. They require direct interaction with national ministries, customs authorities, metrology institutions, and other organisations. For instance, in the case of the GTZ VCP project in Sri Lanka, one of the major obstacles for organic vegetable exports was the fact that vegetables were routinely fumigated at the air cargo facility of Colombo airport. Since a fumigated vegetable is no longer an or- ganic vegetable, changing this routine was one of the major achievements of the project. At the same time, it is essential to work directly with producers. This is where the territorial angle comes in. In any value chain, it is quite unlikely that producers are
  • 23. Linking Value Chain Promotion and the M4P Concept 19 randomly scattered across the country. More likely, they will be concentrated in certain locations – due to climatic and soil conditions (or coincidence) in agricul- ture, due to cluster effects in industry and services. Thus, direct interaction with producers has by nature a strong territorial focus. As a consequence, it is recommendable to conceptualise VCP as an activity that rests on two pillars, i.e. national level activities and activities at the territorial level, at least under those circumstances where the topic of integration in global value chains, or into sophisticated national value chains, is being addressed. Figure 7: The 2 Pillars of Value Chain Promotion Source: own design. Balancing both things in one programme or project is a challenge. One would look at one programme with two components, a national-level component and a territorial component. However, the management of such a programme can eas- ily get out of hand, especially if it addresses several value chains and thus nu- merous producer locations. A plausible alternative approach is one where a VCP project comes in at the national level to bridge the gap between territorial initia- tives and the external or national market. For instance, the experience of GTZ in Sri Lanka indicated a win-win game, where the national level VCP project bene- fited from another GTZ project with a territorial focus and vice versa (Richter 2005). At the same time, the VCP project could easily look for opportunities for interaction with other projects by other donors (e.g. a USAID spice sector project in a different part of the country, or an ILO SME promotion project in yet another part of the country), something that would have been difficult if both projects had been part of one strictly managed programme. 4.1.3 Value chains and markets We have already pointed at the fact that value chains exist because real world markets are quite different from the ideal markets of microeconomics textbooks. This does not mean, though, that value chains are a substitute for markets. They are rather a mixture of different modes of coordination, where network-type coor-
  • 24. 20 Jörg Meyer-Stamer and Frank Wältring dination is a key element yet market coordination and coordination through hier- archy also play an important role. From the perspective of promotion activities, the existence of close network rela- tionships between producers and customers is the point of departure. An analysis of a given value chain will normally detect parts of the chain that are primarily market-coordinated, and other parts that are primarily coordinated through hier- archies. Typical examples of market coordination in a value chain are non- strategic services or commodity inputs. Typical examples of hierarchical coordi- nation are on the one hand outgrower systems which are coordinated by major companies, on the other hand services offered by (typically government-run) supporting institutions. An analysis of a value chain needs to understand which types of transactions are predominantly coordinated through networks, markets, or hierarchies, and to what extent one mode of coordinated might be substituted through a different, ultimately more efficient mode. 4.2 Making markets work One of the features of the M4P literature is its close connection to the BDS dis- cussion and literature. Unfortunately, BDS has never enjoyed an understanding of markets that was firmly rooted in microeconomics concepts. BDS, and espe- cially BDS market assessments, are the world of A C Nielsen and Philip Kotler, not the world of NBER and Joseph Stiglitz. Fortunately, the M4P literature also draws on other arenas of discussion, such as rural development economics which have developed insights into the functioning, and the frequent dysfunction- alities, of markets (Dorward and Kydd 2005). What appears to be a really nice market in the real world often turns out to be the opposite once closely scruti- nised. Geertz (1992) has shown that bazaars are rather dysfunctional markets, where price formation is extremely intransparent and thus the price mechanism, the best feature the market has to offer, does not work properly. Dorward and Kydd (2005) point out that atomised agricultural markets in African locations are creating such high transaction cost that they are ultimately dysfunctional, too. What is missing in the M4P literature are references to the widely accepted in- sight that markets are one out of three forms of coordination, the other two being hierarchies / organisations and networks / communities. While economics re- search has formulated the market / hierarchy / network trias of modes of coordi- nation (Powell 1990, OECD 1992), social scientists tend to distinguish market, organisation and community (e.g. Wiesenthal 2000). What is important in both strands of theorising is the observation that in the real world it is highly unlikely that any pure mode of coordination will work. When a market does not work, the adequate answer is, in all likelihood, not more market but rather more hierarchy / organisation. In fact, not only do the three types usually appear in some kind of combination, but the functionality of each of the three usually depends on the other two. For instance, a market only works when hierarchy is present (in the shape of gov-
  • 25. Linking Value Chain Promotion and the M4P Concept 21 ernment that creates an enabling environment, for instance by securing property rights, and in the shape of companies that internalise processes with high trans- action costs) and when networks exist (for instance business networks, which are another device to minimise transaction costs). Nevertheless, in any given eco- nomic setting, transactions tend to be quite obviously predominantly organised in markets, in hierarchies, or in networks. Job placement is a typical example. Some countries have a sector of for-profit private job placement agencies, i.e. a market solution. In other countries, job placement is a government monopoly, i.e. a hier- archy solution. Yet other countries have neither, and job placement is achieved through informal communication among business people or within social groups, i.e. a network solution. What is the origin and conceptual background of the three types? Market vs hi- erarchy has been the subject of the classic paper by Ronald Coase1 who asked: Why are there companies? If markets are so efficient, why not organise every- thing via markets, i.e. have only self-employed individuals? The answer is, es- sentially, transaction cost. Organising, say, steel production purely via a market, involving only self-employed individuals, would create significant transaction costs. Organising it inside a company is the more efficient solution. Coase had companies in mind when he used the term “hierarchy”. However, it is common to use the term in a way that not only refers to companies, but also other organisations, in particular government. Networks have been conceptually introduced as a third mode of organisation by Walter Powell (1990). He pointed out that networks are not something some- where in between market and hierarchy but rather a distinctive mode of organisa- tion. Networks refers to formal constellations, from strategic alliances to business associations, as well as informal constellations, for instance the dense communi- cation networks inside industrial clusters. The important point to make is that there are no other ideal types, i.e. no other ways of organising economic transactions. Any economic transaction is predomi- nantly done in a market, in a hierarchy, or in a network. How does the discussion on M4P relate to the concept of market, hierarchy and network? The conceptual discussion and practical work on M4P has evolved along three distinct trajectories. Three distinct schools of thought have emerged: 1. The market focus. This perspective is linked to the Commark project in Southern Africa.2 It is aligned with what Altenburg and Drachenfels (2005) have called “the new minimalist approach to private sector development”, where government is supposed to limit itself to creating an enabling environ- ment so that markets can work effectively and efficiently. This perspective has no proper conceptualisation of market failure, and of interventions neces- 1 “The nature of the firm”, 1937 2 Ferrand, Gibson and Scott 2004, Centre for Development and Enterprise 2006
  • 26. 22 Jörg Meyer-Stamer and Frank Wältring sary to remedy market failure. Markets are expected to work provided that the framework conditions are right, and they are supposed to be by far the most efficient mode of organising economic activities. The Commark documents are quite explicit about the fact that functioning markets are perfectly suffi- cient for a thriving economy, and that hierarchy as in selective government interventions is creating more damage than benefit. Networks do not figure in these documents. 2. The markets and hierarchies focus. This perspective is linked to the work of authors like Dorward, Kydd and others on behalf of DFID (Dorward and Kydd 2005, Kydd et al 2004). It is based on insights from agricultural economics. It highlights that fact that it is not necessarily a good idea to rely on markets only, since what appears as a perfect market in theory can be a transaction cost nightmare in practice. Markets with lots of small suppliers and customers are a reality in rural Africa, yet they don’t work very well since it is time con- suming and thus costly for customers to get a comprehensive picture of the variety and quality of produce that is on offer; “... market exchange in Africa is generally ‘costly, cumbersome, time-consuming, and unpredictable’” (Dor- ward and Kydd 2005, 18, quoting Fafchamps 2004). Hierarchies, for instance outgrower systems that are managed by a major company, can turn out to be significantly more wealth creating than markets under such circumstances. 3. The markets, hierarchies and network focus. This perspective has emerged from the work of the ADB/DFID project in Vietnam which has over time broadened its focus.3 Regarding hierarchy, it addressed the issue of enabling environment, but it also looked at contract farming, i.e. hierarchy in the private sector. Regarding network, it addressed issues such as collective action. Each of the three schools of thought has it upside and its downside. Market focus: The upside is the sharp focus. One downside that necessarily comes with the focus is the appearance of a one-sided market fundamentalist approach. Another downside of the existing literature is the superficial way in which it deals with market failure and possible ways to address market failure. Market and hierarchy focus: The upside is the more balanced perspective, since this perspective acknowledges the inherent limits of markets. The downside is the negligence of network as the third important mode of organi- sation. Market, hierarchy and network focus: The upside is the coverage of all three modes of organisation, i.e. a holistic perspective that does not a priori judge that one mode is better than the others. The downside is that this focus re- flects an evolutionary process from “Making Market Systems Work for the Poor” to “Making Everything Work for the Poor” which, from a practical per- spective, is a steep task. 3 See the papers available at http://www.markets4poor.org/
  • 27. Linking Value Chain Promotion and the M4P Concept 23 4.2.1 M4P and P4M Another important conclusion is that it actually can make sense to look at the way markets work, and to address their dysfunctionalities and failures rather than take them for granted. This is particularly relevant with respect to the poor. It is more than just a play of words to point out that "making markets work for the poor" is the opposite of "making poor work for the market". In the past, a common ap- proach in poverty alleviation was to address the poor rather than the markets they tried to interact in. A typical example of "P4M" is skills development. The usual idea in skills devel- opment is to upgrade the skills of individuals so that they fit with employers’ re- quirements. Sometimes, this is complemented with "life skills" training in order to enhance the employability of individuals. In other words, the structure and mechanisms of the labour market are taken for granted. The focus is not at changing the way the market works, but rather at making individuals fit for the market. Another example of "P4M" is the creation of collateral banks or other mecha- nisms that create securities for potential creditors who cannot fulfil the banks' usual requirements regarding collateral, and who thus do not have access to the capital market. On the other hand, Microfinance is an approach that fits with "M4P" principles. Support for microfinance is based on the insight that the con- ventional capital market often does not work for small producers and poor house- holds. An interim conclusion would be that M4P and P4M are not alternatives but com- plementary approaches. For instance, making the labour market work better for the poor does not alleviate the need to raise the level of skills and the more gen- eral employability of poor people. It is, however, important not ignore an important dilemma in this respect. Limiting the perspective to markets alone compromises the “for the poor” ambition, espe- cially if one takes a closer look at the causes of poverty. Poor people are often excluded, which takes us to a finding that appears tautological: Markets don’t work for excluded groups because they are excluded. Markets are embedded in networks and other societal structures, and poor often don’t benefit from markets because they are marginalised by those structures. Exclusion is a process that is embedded in and reinforced by social structures. Thus, it is important to ac- knowledge that “making markets work for the poor” is not a simple, straightfor- ward task where limited interventions in certain markets will do the trick. It rather involves quite fundamental interventions into societal structures – another steep task.
  • 28. 24 Jörg Meyer-Stamer and Frank Wältring 4.2.2 Understanding market failure Given these challenges, it is important to remind oneself that a “making markets work” approach has persuasive advantages. One of the most important ones is the intrinsic quality of coordination through markets: Markets work because par- ticipants pursue their self-interest. Hierarchies are facing all sorts of problems, such as the principal-agent problem where the power centre is constantly battling with the challenge of making sure that the agents who receive orders or missions fulfil them in the way the principal wants them to. Networks are also facing all sorts of problems, such as the problem of numbers where a network that involves a significant number of players creates a huge coordination effort and cost. Mar- kets are coordinated in a decentralised way. They don’t require a coordination centre. Markets tend to emerge quite spontaneously – even in places where the framework conditions are decidedly business unfriendly, such as Somalia (Ne- nova and Harford 2004). Moreover, the M4P approach goes beyond the “minimalist approach”. The mini- malist approach tries to create favourable framework conditions and then expects markets to do their miracle in a spontaneous way. The M4P approach acknowl- edges that markets often won’t do that, and that in particular they will not benefit or even exclude the poor. Thus, targeted interventions are necessary to make sure that markets work, and to make sure that they work for the poor. The M4P approach has so far generated a significant body of research studies that ana- lysed markets and the way they worked, or didn’t work, for the poor. What is only slowly emerging is a set of tools that can guide practitioners in their efforts to make markets work. It is thus a perfectly rational response to opt for a more limited approach, and here one that relates back to the starting point of the M4P approach, namely the intention to better understand markets, market failure, and practical ways to make markets work better. In this respect, the M4P literature is only partially helpful since it does not provide a systematic treatment of market failure, i.e. imperfec- tions that keep real world markets from operating in the way assumed by simple microeconomics models. The following table gives an overview of the main types of market failure. Market failure has three main consequences: It generates a low level equilibrium. The examples given in the table explain how market failure issues can reinforce each other and thus keep rural pro- ducers disconnected from markets. Income stays low, investment capacity is low, there is little if any innovation and upgrading, and producers remain mired in poverty. It generates suboptimal delivery of critical investment, for instance into skills development or research and development, thus reinforcing the competitive- ness gap that keeps producers and companies from upgrading so that they might connect with dynamic markets.
  • 29. Linking Value Chain Promotion and the M4P Concept 25 Table 1: Types of market failure Type of mar- Example Consequence ket failure Natural Telecommunications in ru- Customers in rural areas pay much higher monopoly ral, thinly populated areas price for telecom services than urban customers, perhaps have no service at all, and suffer from delays in access to in- novative telecom services External Investment in skills devel- Companies invest less in the skills devel- effects opment (positive external opment of their staff that would be desir- effect) able from a macro perspective Building a cheap high chim- ney instead of installing a Contamination of region by industrial plant filter (negative external ef- fect) Indivisibility Size of a container (mini- Small producers cannot connect to cus- mum 39 cubic meters) that tomers because the don’t produce needs to be filled by supplier enough to fill a container Asymmetric Information about residual Customers don’t buy fruit or vegetables if information toxics and other contami- they suspect that producers have used nants in fruit and vegetables more agrochemicals than they admit in the absence of sophisti- cated and costly testing equipment Producers who don’t trust the seller don’t buy high yield seeds if they look just like Features of distinct products much cheaper normal seeds that look alike Public goods Availability of sophisticated Producers can’t convince their customers and costly testing equipment that the level of residual toxics is low, and in a region with small pro- thus can’t sell their products ducers It creates barriers to entry, thus reinforcing monopolies and the high prices and service delivery shortcomings that come with monopolies. Any effort to make market systems work for the poor must be based on a thor- ough understanding of market failure, and not just on market research conducted by A C Nielsen. Analyses must be conducted that investigate the root causes of market failure, since only in this way is it possible to design interventions that go beyond fumbling with the symptoms of market failure. 4.3 Who are “the poor”? The M4P literature is somewhat fuzzy when it comes to defining who is meant by “the poor”. Recent literature has pointed at a number of ways to get a differenti- ated picture of poverty. Let us mention two.
  • 30. 26 Jörg Meyer-Stamer and Frank Wältring 1. Discussions in the SEEP network led to a typology of the poor that addresses the question: To what extent are the poor likely to be producers that are active in markets? Figure 8: The Context of Poverty and Micro-Enterprise Development Source: Eiligmann (2005), 8 This perspective looks at poor producers. The main argument is that the desti- tute, i.e. the poorest of the poor, are unlikely to enter into markets as producers. It is important to note, though, that in the M4P literature, the term “private sector” does not only refer to businesses but actually to all economic actors that are not public sector, i.e. all types of producers as well as workers. Nevertheless, the SEEP typology is helpful since it points out that only a part of the poor, namely those who are close to the poverty line, are likely to enter markets as producers. 2. Ravaillon (2004) points out that, even with a narrow concept of poverty, growth will not automatically benefit the poor. It is crucial to address the geographical and sectoral pattern of growth (ibid., 16). Poverty is often concentrated in specific regions, in particular rural regions, and in one sector, namely agriculture. This argument is developed in a more detailed way by Janvry and Sadoulet (2004, 4 f.), based on evidence from Latin America: “There is increasing differentiation between two types of locations for rural pov- erty: MRA (marginal rural areas) and FRA (favorable rural areas). Part of the rural poor are geographically concentrated in low population density MRA (marginal rural areas) defined as areas with either poor agro-ecological en-
  • 31. Linking Value Chain Promotion and the M4P Concept 27 dowments and/or isolated from access to markets and employment centers. These areas consist in: Geographical pockets of poverty: Mexico’s Southern States, Brazil Northeast, Central America’s East Coast regions, and high altitudes in the Altiplano. Indigenous territories: Indigenous communities attached to their homelands in the Altiplano and the East Coast of Central America. The other part of the rural poor are socially diffused in FRA (favorable rural ar- eas) defined as areas with good agro-ecologies and good connections to dy- namic product and/or labor markets. The poor in this context are: Individuals with low asset endowments, especially land, education, and social capital. Individuals with good asset endowments, but lacking opportunities to valorize these assets in the territories where they are located (lack of regional dy- namics, discrimination). Rural youth, elderly people, and disabled individuals for whom social assis- tance programs are needed.” This perspective provides a much more tangible understanding of types of rural poverty. The authors’ conclusion is: “These contrasts between favorable and un- favorable areas (and the continuum of conditions in between) points to the rele- vance of a regionally differentiated approach that takes into account this hetero- geneity.” (ibid.) In other words, any pro-poor policy must have a strong territorial focus. 5 How to link M4P and VC analysis: Practical considerations In principle, there are two ways to approach the issue of pro-poor, market- oriented value chain analysis: 1. Analysis can be conducted as a separate activity. 2. Analysis can be conducted as action research. In this section, we will look at each option. 5.1 Analysis before action An approach where thorough analysis is conducted before any action is taken is based on an epistemological concept that is mechanistic by nature. It is based on the assumption that most if not all of the relevant information for a developmental
  • 32. 28 Jörg Meyer-Stamer and Frank Wältring activity can be gathered before a strategy is formulated and implemented. One such approach is presented in a recent paper by Kula, Downing and Field (2006) which reflects the current state of thinking in USAID’s microenterprise pro- gramme. Figure 9: The USAID approach to value chain promotion Source: Kula, Downing and Field (2006) An Analysis Before Action approach has its advantages first and foremost from an administrative perspective. It allows for organising planning into a logical framework, facilitates the planning of the allocation of resources over a period of time, and appears to define clear milestones which make project management easier for administrators who are removed from activities on the ground. In terms of activities on the ground, though, it is difficult to discern the advantages of an Analysis Before Action approach. It may appear to be logically structured by delivering information that is necessary for informed decision taking. This, how- ever, can easily turn into an illusion as the Analysis Before Action approach will often suffer from a specific type of Catch-22, namely the problem that a lot of the information that is crucial to define the terms of reference for the researcher who will conduct the value chain analysis only becomes available through the value chain analysis said researcher will conduct. In fact, the Analysis Before Action approach suffers from a number of dilemmas: Select VCs before understanding them: In this approach, VCs that are to be promoted are selected early, before representative information is available. Assuming hard budget constraints, it is unrealistic to conduct a comprehen- sive study of all value chains that are relevant for a given regional or national economy. By limiting the number of VCs that are investigated, VCs are not chosen because they have been thoroughly investigated. Instead, VCs are investigated because they have been chosen. Quick-scan vs robust information: The Analysis Before Action approach re- quires substantial resources. As projects tend to suffer from budget limita- tions, there is an incentive for project managers to limit the scope and depth of the analysis, thus conducting something that is more like a quick scan rather than solid research. With a quick scan, though, a random selection of VCs is followed by a collection of random data that lead to a random decision. Management of expectations: Researching value chains is usually based on face-to-face interviews, focus group interviews and workshops. To the extent
  • 33. Linking Value Chain Promotion and the M4P Concept 29 that actors who need to be interviewed suffer from time constraints, there needs to be an incentive for them to allocate time to the task of being re- searched. In order to persuade them to allocate time, researchers will be tempted to highlight the strong possibility of future promotion activities, per- haps including the availability of grants. Thus, expectations are created among actors inside the value chain which may or may not be realistic, and which in any case can not be managed in a proper way, based on the strat- egy and logical framework of the project, since neither strategy nor logframe exist at this stage. In order to understand how steep the task of conducting a solid analysis before any action is, let us have another look at the M4P literature. As quoted in Section 3.1, a solid analysis would involve a number of elements. We also give a rough estimate of the number of researcher days that would be needed to conduct each task. Table 2: Tasks involved in an M4P / Value Chain analysis Task Estimated days Poverty reports including household surveys and PPA surveys 200 Specific market and transactions studies using participatory and other 50 techniques to complement existing poverty data ‘Doing Business’ and Investment Climate Surveys 100 Trade, production and price data 30 Market outcomes and data from the operation of value chains 250 The rate and direction of the evolution of key markets for the poor 60 Total 690 In other words, the Analysis Before Action approach is, first of all, a very serious income generation programme for consultants and researchers. Assuming that one third of those days would involve foreign consultants at a rate of US$ 500 per day, and two thirds domestic consultants at a rate of US$100 per day, the fees alone would amount to a total of US$ 161,000. 5.2 Action research Practical experience shows that successful development programmes are based on iterative processes, not simple sequences. For instance, in the LEADER pro- gramme to promote development in poor rural regions of the EU, the learning process regarding sequencing has been summarised in the way illustrated in Figure 10.
  • 34. 30 Jörg Meyer-Stamer and Frank Wältring Figure 10: The spiral model of sequencing in the EU LEADER programme Source: www.rural-europe.aeidl.be, presentation LEADER_dia6_en.pdf This model is based on the insight that ex-ante research will only to some extent reveal the information that is relevant to solve a given problem or realise a given opportunity. The best way to understand the root cause of a problem is to try to solve it. This approach leads naturally to action research, i.e. a practice where analysis and action are closely intertwined. An approach that introduces a strong pro-poor element into value chain analysis needs to be based on three key insights: 1. It must involve a geographical and sectoral focus that is particularly pro-poor (Ravaillon 2004). 2. It needs to analyse markets beyond the lines outlined by Ferrand, Gibson and Scott (2004), i.e. it needs a thorough understanding of market failure. 3. It needs to address the complementarity between markets and hierarchies (Dorward and Kydd 2005), as well as looking at networks as highlighted by the literature on global value chains (Schmitz 2005), and it needs to analyse the interaction between the three modes of coordination. This point may ap- pear contrary to the argument developed in Section 4. However, one needs to keep in mind that a value chain per se is a mixture of market-based coordina- tion, hierarchy and network, so that a narrow focus at markets and market failure is implausible. 5.2.1 Selecting a target group for a pro-poor value chain promotion project When it comes to selecting target groups who are supposed to benefit from de- velopment interventions, we usually recommend to design mechanisms that lead
  • 35. Linking Value Chain Promotion and the M4P Concept 31 to self-selection, i.e. draft a process where a variety of possible beneficiaries is addressed and ultimately those benefit who undertake the strongest effort to get involved. Unfortunately, this may not be a feasible process when it comes to pro- poor VCP. Pro-poor VCP, like any VCP activity, needs to be based on business principles. When it comes to integrating poor communities into VCs, a self- selection process may mobilise communities who do not really have the potential to become integrated into VCs. Therefore, it may be recommendable to design a selection process that involves external expertise. A wrong approach to select target groups for pro-poor VCP would be based on a sequence of questions like this: Where are the poor? Is there anything they can produce? Can we train them to improve the quality of their product? And can we then perhaps connect them to some value chain? This would be the “wouldn’t it be nice if” approach, as in “wouldn’t it be nice if Ikea sold Bolivian handicraft”. Selecting poor communities and regions, based on their need and their supposed potential, promoting them and only after that trying to connect them to VCs is a supply-driven approach that will not work. The only way to move a chain is by pulling. In this perspective, we see two promising approaches to pro-poor VCP. The problem-driven approach: The starting point is the analysis of the real economy in a given country, based on the analysis of export data, conversations with exporters or interviews with buyers at major domestic retailers. The question is: Which producers in poor communities are connected to national or global VCs, and which of them are only precariously integrated into VCs, so that an effort to upgrade their capability (which must be coordinated with buyers from the outset) is meaningful? A relatively quick fact-finding effort would lead to a list of potential candidates in terms of communities, sectors and locations. Addressees for VCP activities would then be picked from this list on the basis of poverty / pro-poor de- velopment criteria. The opportunity-driven approach: This approach would take the interests of major domestic retailers, exporters or foreign buyers as the point of departure. The question would be: What are the products that you are searching for but cannot find? And to what extent have you identified possible producers in our country that have a basic production capability but are not close enough to an adequate quality and productivity level to qualify for a supplier development pro- gramme that is managed by the buyer? The rationale of this approach would be to help producers, preferably from poor communities, to cross the gap that sepa- rates them from the minimum requirements of major buyers. 5.2.2 Launching a pro-poor value chain promotion project What would the initial sequence in a pro-poor value chain initiative look like? We have tried to visualise this in Figure 11. In this approach, the first steps are par- ticularly important. They make or break the pro-poor impact of the initiative. The
  • 36. 32 Jörg Meyer-Stamer and Frank Wältring pro-poor orientation needs be part of the genetic code of the initiative, not some- thing that is just attached like a slogan sticker. Figure 11: Initial Sequence for a Pro-Poor Value Chain Initiative The figure does not distinguish between the national-level and the territorial pillar of a VCP initiative. The first four activities (initiating, scoping, assembling re- sources, picturing the value chain) would involve a single process. During the “picturing the value chain” stage the process would go through a bifurcation, after which a national-level process and one or several territorial processes would run at the same time, though not in parallel but rather informing and reinforcing each other. The following table looks at the particular challenges that exist in terms of assur- ing that the pro-poor perspective is maintained in a satisfactory way. Subse- quently, we will look at each step in more detail. Table 3: How to consistently maintain the pro-poor perspective Stage Tools Scoping Collect and assess the existing documentation on the structure of poverty Assemble re- Involve individuals with a deep understanding of poverty in the given sources country in the core team Picturing the value Look for regions and locations where poor producers have a least a chain vague potential to be involved in the respective value chain Engaging Conduct workshops in poor communities, using standard PRA tools stakeholders Make sure that facilitators understand the crucial importance of proper management of expectations at this stage
  • 37. Linking Value Chain Promotion and the M4P Concept 33 Collaborating with As above, plus test the willingness of poor communities in different stakeholders locations to get seriously involved in a development effort. Never forget that sometimes poverty is a comfort zone. But also address the issue of risk: try to identify communities for whom the risk of fail- ure of the initiative is not existential. Participatory, action Employ a specific variation of a participatory, quick appraisal in lo- oriented research cations with poor producers who may have a potential to be in- volved in the value chain. Make sure that the issue of market failure is covered. Quick-win activities Make sure that there is enough capacity for ongoing facilitation of the implementation of activities in poor communities. Participatory M+E Apply appropriate M+E tools (e.g. no tools that require writing in communities with a high incidence of illiteracy) Adjustment As the approach becomes more robust, try to involve the more complicated, less organised, less risk-tolerant poor communities. Scaling up Scoping At this stage, issues like the geographical and sectoral structure of poverty need to be addressed. The painful discussions that were mentioned above (poor vs very poor, moderately competitive vs survivalist) must be conducted at this stage, and decisions need to be taken in this respect. However, given the iterative structure of the overall VCP initiative, it is important to note that there is always room for adjustment, especially when the practical work shows that certain groups of poor show more dedication and potential than initially expected. Assemble resources This point not only addresses the mobilisation of funds to conduct the value chain initiative. It also relates to other resources that are essential, in particular knowl- edge and connections. At this stage, it is crucial to assemble a number of “con- nectors” who can tap into different sources of knowledge, including indigenous and local knowledge (as opposed to relying exclusively on the data presented by national or regional level poverty assessments). Picturing the value chain At this stage, the key task is to get a better understanding of the value chain that is going to be in the focus of the initiative. This does not imply preparing a com- prehensive report that adheres to academic standards. It is perfectly possible to picture a value chain in through two or three well facilitated brief workshops with key informers where simple yet powerful mapping techniques are used. Mapping techniques like those in GTZ’s ValueLinks method are extremely useful at this
  • 38. 34 Jörg Meyer-Stamer and Frank Wältring stage. On top of mapping the elements of the chain, it would be useful to investi- gate market failure at the different stages of the chain. Engaging stakeholders For a pro-poor value chain initiative to be successful, a broad set of highly di- verse stakeholders needs to be engaged, from top management in major corpo- rations that are powerful nodes in value chains to poor communities in peripheral locations. Obviously, very different communication approaches have to be used to engage the different stakeholders: At the level of lead firms, an essential point is to engage with top manage- ment and with supply chain managers, rather than just with the Corporate Social Responsibility department. At the level of local communities, it is essential to interact not only with gov- ernment officials and politicians, but also with communities themselves. Stan- dard PRA tools like Wealth Ranking and Well-Being Ranking can be useful in better understanding local communities. Collaborating with stakeholders The purpose of this element is to verify, through discussions with the set of stakeholders who were initially addressed, that the right stakeholders have been involved. It also involves understanding the goals and objectives, and logic of ac- tion, of the different stakeholders. At the local level, interacting with producers and companies, well-established PRA tools like transects and walkovers are useful. Participatory, action oriented research The purpose of this step is to analyse the value chain and to look for opportuni- ties to integrate (more) poor producers into the value chain. It involves a set of workshops with different stakeholders. Though to some extent workshops will address relatively homogeneous groups of stakeholders, it is crucial to organise workshops that bring together representatives of very different stakeholder groups, so that key stakeholders get a first-hand understanding of other stakeholders’ mindset and objectives. Tools that can be used at this stage in- clude ValueLinks mapping, standard PRA and PACA tools, as well as specific tools that look at market structures. A possible angle is to look at barriers to entry, as many instances of market fail- ure will ultimately manifest themselves as barriers to entry. A useful tool to inves- tigate this is a modified version of Michael Porter’s Five Forces Analysis.
  • 39. Linking Value Chain Promotion and the M4P Concept 35 Figure 12 The modification refers to the bottom box, which looks at barriers to diversifica- tion (into related products, markets in neighbouring locations, or a closely related market segment) instead of substituting products. The other four forces are di- rectly related to market power and barriers to entry, i.e. generate information about possible market failure. While incumbents may hesitate to highlight the bar- riers to entry they are creating, business people are usually more than happy to complain about the barriers to entry they are facing, and this is why the changed bottom box is useful. This tool can be used both in interviews and in workshops with representatives from a given subsector. Quick-win activities Since a value chain addresses businesses, and even very big corporations tend to think in three-month-cycles, it is crucial that quick-win activities are identified in the research phase which can then swiftly be implemented. When it comes to prioritising activities, the prospect of an activity to improve the integration of poor into the chain should be applied as one criterion. Moreover, while brainstorming on possible activities, the stakeholders involved in this exercise should consistently ask themselves: Can whatever we want to do be sensibly done via the market (rather than through a hierarchy or a network)? De- velopment practitioners appear to have a natural tendency to opt for hierarchy or network as preferred approaches to addressing problems or opportunities, which is unfortunate since a market-based solution, where business people pursue an opportunity out of self-interest, is often the most sustainable solution.
  • 40. 36 Jörg Meyer-Stamer and Frank Wältring Participatory M+E After the first round of activities has been implemented, the different stakeholders need to be involved in a monitoring and evaluation effort that takes the initiative towards the second round of activities, thus launching the iterative pattern. Adjustment, scaling up Apart from coming up with more (and hopefully better and more effective) activi- ties, it is crucial to look at scaling up. Initial activities will most likely be pilot activi- ties with a limited outreach. Once a given approach appears to be robust, it needs to be scaled up to reach a bigger group of poor. 6 Conclusion M4P and VCP do not fit like hand and glove. Merging them into a single ap- proach is not desirable, since this would imply losing the focus at international transactions in the VCP approach. M4P and VCP can fertilise each other, since each one addresses blind spots of the other: The VCP approach highlights the fact that markets are only one mode of co- ordinating economic transactions, next to hierarchies and networks. While the M4P approach acknowledges this in principle, it is subject to a narrowing down of interventions towards enabling markets without due consideration for hierarchies and markets. The M4P concept highlights the relevance of enabling markets, a fact that VCP projects may lose sight of because they can easily get involved in micro- management of economic transactions. Moreover, the M4P concept empha- sises the importance of directly addressing the poor, something that is not explicit in VCP approaches. Moreover, the M4P approach can fertilise a couple of arenas of technical coop- eration, such as local and regional economic develoment, SME promotion and agricultural development. It also has the potential to generate systemic change. While selective activities such as VCP by their very nature have a limited impact, M4P has the potential to induce change that affects all market participants. It thus makes a lot of sense to further explore the contributions M4P can make to other fields of productive sector development.