SlideShare une entreprise Scribd logo
1  sur  5
Télécharger pour lire hors ligne
America’s Growing
Trade Deficit Is
Selling the Nation
Out From Under Us.
Here’s a Way to Fix
the Problem—And We
Need to Do It Now.
by Warren E. Buffett
I’M ABOUT TO DELIVER A WARNING regarding the U.S. trade deficit
and also suggest a remedy for the problem. But first I need to mention
two reasons you might want to be skeptical about what I say. To begin,
my forecasting record with respect to macroeconomics is far from
inspiring. For example, over the past two decades I was excessively
fearful of inflation. More to the point at hand, I started way back in
1987 to publicly worry about our mounting trade deficits—and, as you
know, we’ve not only survived but also thrived. So on the trade front,
score at least one “wolf” for me. Nevertheless, I am crying wolf again and
NOVEMBER 10, 2003
FORTUNE
this time backing it with Berkshire Hath-
away’s money. Through the spring of
2002, I had lived nearly 72 years without
purchasing a foreign currency. Since then
Berkshire has made significant invest-
ments in—and today holds—several cur-
rencies. I won’t give you particulars; in
fact, it is largely irrelevant which curren-
cies they are. What does matter is the un-
derlying point: To hold other currencies
is to believe that the dollar will decline.
Both as an American and as an in-
vestor, I actually hope these commit-
ments prove to be a mistake. Any prof-
its Berkshire might make from currency
trading would pale against the losses the
company and our shareholders, in other
aspects of their lives, would incur from
a plunging dollar.
But as head of Berkshire Hathaway, I
am in charge of investing its money in
ways that make sense. And my reason
for finally putting my money where my
mouth has been so long is that our trade
deficit has greatly worsened, to the point
that our country’s “net worth,” so to
speak, is now being transferred abroad
at an alarming rate.
A
perpetuation of this trans-
fer will lead to major trou-
ble. To understand why,
take a wildly fanciful trip
with me to two isolated,
side-by-side islands of equal size, Squan-
derville and Thriftville. Land is the only
capital asset on these islands, and their
communities are primitive, needing only
food and producing only food. Work-
ing eight hours a day, in fact, each in-
habitant can produce enough food to
sustain himself or herself. And for a long
time that’s how things go along. On each
island everybody works the prescribed
eight hours a day, which means that each
society is self-sufficient.
Eventually, though, the industrious
citizens of Thriftville decide to do some
serious saving and investing, and they
start to work 16 hours a day. In this mode
they continue to live off the food they
produce in eight hours of work but be-
gin exporting an equal amount to their
one and only trading outlet, Squan-
derville.
The citizens of Squanderville are ec-
static about this turn of events, since
they can now live their lives free from
toil but eat as well as ever. Oh, yes,
there’s a quid pro quo—but to the
Squanders, it seems harmless: All that
the Thrifts want in exchange for their
WA R R E N B U F F E T T
–$100
billion
$0
–$200
–$300
–$400
1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000
1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000
2003
FORTUNE
estimate
–$500
billion
$0
–$1
trillion
–$1.5
–$2
–$2.5
6/03
FORTUNE
estimate
U.S. TRADE
SURPLUS/DEFICIT
U.S. NET
INTERNATIONAL
INVESTMENT
U.S. holdings of foreign assets
minus foreign holdings of U.S. assets*
Facing up to the effects of our trade imbalance
FORTUNEGRAPHIC/SOURCE:BUREAUOFECONOMICANALYSIS,U.S.DEPARTMENTOFCOMMERCE
*Data for 1976 and later years are not strictly comparable with pre-1976 data.
Truth and consequences
Huge and growing
U.S. trade deficits …
… are inevitably putting
an ever larger slice of
America in foreign hands
food is Squanderbonds (which are denominated,
naturally, in Squanderbucks).
Over time Thriftville accumulates an enor-
mous amount of these bonds, which at their core
represent claim checks on the future output of
Squanderville. A few pundits in Squanderville
smell trouble coming. They foresee that for the Squanders both
to eat and to pay off—or simply service—the debt they’re piling
up will eventually require them to work more than eight hours a
day. But the residents of Squanderville are in no mood to listen
to such doomsaying.
Meanwhile, the citizens of Thriftville begin to get nervous.
Just how good, they ask, are the IOUs of a shiftless island? So
the Thrifts change strategy: Though they continue to hold some
bonds, they sell most of them to Squanderville residents for
Squanderbucks and use the proceeds to buy Squanderville
land. And eventually the Thrifts own all of Squanderville.
At that point, the Squanders are forced to deal with an ugly
equation: They must now not only return to working eight
hours a day in order to eat—they have nothing left to trade—but
must also work additional hours to service their debt and pay
Thriftville rent on the land so imprudently sold. In effect, Squan-
derville has been colonized by purchase rather than conquest.
It can be argued, of course, that the present value of the fu-
ture production that Squanderville must forever ship to Thrift-
ville only equates to the production Thriftville initially gave up
and that therefore both have received a fair deal. But since one
generation of Squanders gets the free ride and future generations
pay in perpetuity for it, there are—in economist talk—some
pretty dramatic “intergenerational inequities.”
Let’s think of it in terms of a family: Imagine that I, Warren
Buffett, can get the suppliers of all that I consume in my life-
time to take Buffett family IOUs that are payable, in goods and
services and with interest added, by my descendants. This sce-
nario may be viewed as effecting an even trade between the Buf-
fett family unit and its creditors. But the generations of Buffetts
following me are not likely to applaud the deal (and, heaven for-
bid, may even attempt to welsh on it).
Think again about those islands: Sooner or later the Squan-
derville government, facing ever greater payments to service debt,
would decide to embrace highly inflationary policies—that is, is-
sue more Squanderbucks to dilute the value of each. After all,
the government would reason, those irritating Squanderbonds
are simply claims on specific numbers of Squanderbucks, not on
bucks of specific value. In short, making Squanderbucks less valu-
able would ease the island’s fiscal pain.
That prospect is why I, were I a resident of Thriftville, would
opt for direct ownership of Squanderville land rather than bonds
of the island’s government. Most governments find it much harder
morally to seize foreign-owned property than they do to dilute
the purchasing power of claim checks foreigners hold. Theft by
stealth is preferred to theft by force.
S
o what does all this island hopping have to do with
the U.S.? Simply put, after World War II and up un-
til the early 1970s we operated in the industrious
Thriftville style, regularly selling more abroad than
we purchased. We concurrently invested our surplus
abroad, with the result that our net investment—that is, our hold-
ings of foreign assets less foreign holdings of U.S. assets—in-
creased (under methodology, since revised, that the govern-
ment was then using) from $37 billion in 1950 to $68 billion in
1970. In those days, to sum up, our country’s “net worth,” viewed
in totality, consisted of all the wealth within our borders plus a
modest portion of the wealth in the rest of the world.
Additionally, because the U.S. was in a net ownership position
with respect to the rest of the world, we realized net investment
income that, piled on top of our trade surplus, became a second
source of investable funds. Our fiscal situation was thus similar
to that of an individual who was both saving some of his salary
and reinvesting the dividends from his existing nest egg.
In the late 1970s the trade situation reversed, producing deficits
that initially ran about 1% of GDP. That was hardly serious, par-
ticularly because net investment income remained positive. In-
deed, with the power of compound interest working for us, our
net ownership balance hit its high in 1980 at $360 billion.
Since then, however, it’s been all downhill, with the pace of de-
cline rapidly accelerating in the past five years. Our annual trade
deficit now exceeds 4% of GDP. Equally ominous, the rest of
the world owns a staggering $2.5 trillion more of the U.S. than
we own of other countries. Some of this $2.5 trillion is invested
in claim checks—U.S. bonds, both governmental and private—
and some in such assets as property and equity securities.
In effect, our country has been behaving like an extraordinarily
rich family that possesses an immense farm. In order to consume
4% more than we produce—that’s the trade deficit—we have,
day by day, been both selling pieces of the farm and increasing
the mortgage on what we still own.
To put the $2.5 trillion of net foreign ownership in perspec-
tive, contrast it with the $12 trillion value of publicly owned
U.S. stocks or the equal amount of U.S. residential real estate
or what I would estimate as a grand total of $50 trillion in na-
tional wealth. Those comparisons show that what’s already
been transferred abroad is meaningful—in the area, for exam-
ple, of 5% of our national wealth.
More important, however, is that foreign ownership of our as-
sets will grow at about $500 billion per year at the present
trade-deficit level, which means that the deficit will be adding
about one percentage point annually to foreigners’ net owner-
ship of our national wealth. As that ownership grows, so will the
annual net investment income flowing out of this country. That
will leave us paying ever-increasing dividends and interest to
the world rather than being a net receiver of them, as in the
past. We have entered the world of negative compounding—
goodbye pleasure, hello pain.
We were taught in Economics 101 that countries could not
for long sustain large, ever-growing trade deficits. At a point, so
it was claimed, the spree of the consumption-happy nation would
be braked by currency-rate adjustments and by the unwillingness
of creditor countries to accept an endless flow of IOUs from the
big spenders. And that’s the way it has indeed worked for the rest
of the world, as we can see by the abrupt shutoffs of credit that
many profligate nations have suffered in recent decades.
The U.S., however, enjoys special status. In effect, we can be-
have today as we wish because our past financial behavior was so
exemplary—and because we are so rich. Neither our capacity nor
our intention to pay is questioned, and we continue to have a moun-
tain of desirable assets to trade for consumables. In other words,
Through the spring of 2002, I had lived
nearly 72 years without purchasing
a foreign currency. That has changed.
WA R R E N B U F F E T T
our national credit card allows us to charge
truly breathtaking amounts. But that card’s
credit line is not limitless.
The time to halt this trading of assets
for consumables is now, and I have a plan
to suggest for getting it done. My remedy
may sound gimmicky, and in truth it is a tariff called by another
name. But this is a tariff that retains most free-market virtues,
neither protecting specific industries nor punishing specific coun-
tries nor encouraging trade wars. This plan would increase our
exports and might well lead to increased overall world trade. And
it would balance our books without there being a significant de-
cline in the value of the dollar, which I believe is otherwise al-
most certain to occur.
W
e would achieve this balance by issuing what
I will call Import Certificates (ICs) to all U.S.
exporters in an amount equal to the dollar
value of their exports. Each exporter would,
in turn, sell the ICs to parties—either ex-
porters abroad or importers here—wanting to get goods into the
U.S. To import $1 million of goods, for example, an importer
would need ICs that were the byproduct of $1 million of ex-
ports. The inevitable result: trade balance.
Because our exports total about $80 billion a month, ICs
would be issued in huge, equivalent quantities—that is, 80 bil-
lion certificates a month—and would surely trade in an ex-
ceptionally liquid market. Competition would then determine
who among those parties wanting to sell to us would buy the
certificates and how much they would pay. (I visualize that the
certificates would be issued with a short life, possibly of six
months, so that speculators would be discouraged from accu-
mulating them.)
For illustrative purposes, let’s postulate that each IC would sell
for 10 cents—that is, 10 cents per dollar of exports behind them.
Other things being equal, this amount would mean a U.S. pro-
ducer could realize 10% more by selling his goods in the export
market than by selling them domestically, with the extra 10%
coming from his sales of ICs.
In my opinion, many exporters would view this as a reduc-
tion in cost, one that would let them cut the prices of their prod-
ucts in international markets. Commodity-type products would
particularly encourage this kind of be-
havior. If aluminum, for example, was sell-
ing for 66 cents per pound domestically
and ICs were worth 10%, domestic alu-
minum producers could sell for about 60
cents per pound (plus transportation
costs) in foreign markets and still earn
normal margins. In this scenario, the out-
put of the U.S. would become significantly
more competitive and exports would ex-
pand. Along the way, the number of jobs
would grow.
Foreigners selling to us, of course, would
face tougher economics. But that’s a prob-
lem they’re up against no matter what trade
“solution” is adopted—and make no mis-
take, a solution must come. (As Herb Stein
said, “If something cannot go on forever,
it will stop.”) In one way the IC approach
would give countries selling to us great flex-
ibility, since the plan does not penalize any
specific industry or product. In the end, the
free market would determine what would
be sold in the U.S. and who would sell it.
The ICs would determine only the aggre-
gate dollar volume of what was sold.
To see what would happen to imports,
let’s look at a car now entering the U.S. at
a cost to the importer of $20,000. Under
the new plan and the assumption that ICs
sell for 10%, the importer’s cost would rise
to $22,000. If demand for the car was ex-
ceptionally strong, the importer might
manage to pass all of this on to the Amer-
ican consumer. In the usual case, however,
competitive forces would take hold, re-
quiring the foreign manufacturer to absorb
some, if not all, of the $2,000 IC cost.
An ominous fact: The rest of the world
owns a staggering $2.5 trillion more of the
U.S. than we own of other countries.
WA R R E N B U F F E T T
HOW OFTEN HAVE YOU SEEN A COMMENT LIKE THIS IN ARTICLES ABOUT
the U.S. dollar? “Analysts say that what really worries them is that foreigners will
start moving out of the dollar.”
Next time you see something like that, dismiss it. The fact is that foreigners—
as a whole—cannot ditch their dollars. Indeed, because our trade deficit is
constantly putting new dollars into the hands of foreigners, they have to just as
constantly increase their U.S. investments.
It’s true, of course, that the rest of the world can choose which U.S. assets to
hold. They can decide, for example, to sell U.S. bonds to buy U.S. stocks. Or
they can make a move into real estate, as the Japanese did in the 1980s.
Moreover, any of those moves, particularly if they are carried out by anxious
sellers or buyers, can influence the price of the dollar.
But imagine that the Japanese both want to get out of their U.S. real estate
and entirely away from dollar assets. They can’t accomplish that by selling their
real estate to Americans, because they will get paid in dollars. And if they sell
their real estate to non-Americans—say, the French, for euros—the property will
remain in the hands of foreigners. With either kind of sale, the dollar assets held
by the rest of the world will not (except for any concurrent shift in the price of the
dollar) have changed.
The bottom line is that other nations simply can’t disinvest in the U.S. unless
they, as a universe, buy more goods and services from us than we buy from
them. That state of affairs would be called an American trade surplus, and we
don’t have one.
You can dream up some radical plots for changing the situation. For example,
the rest of the world could send the U.S. massive foreign aid that would serve to
offset our trade deficit. But under any realistic view of things, our huge trade
deficit guarantees that the rest of the world must not only hold the American
assets it owns but consistently add to them. And that’s why, of course, our
national net worth is gradually shifting away from our shores.
Why Foreigners
Can’t Ditch Their Dollars
T
here is no free lunch in the IC plan: It would have
certain serious negative consequences for U.S. cit-
izens. Prices of most imported products would in-
crease, and so would the prices of certain competi-
tive products manufactured domestically. The cost
of the ICs, either in whole or in part, would therefore typically
act as a tax on consumers.
That is a serious drawback. But there would be drawbacks also
to the dollar continuing to lose value or to our increasing tariffs
on specific products or instituting quotas on them—courses of
action that in my opinion offer a smaller chance of success. Above
all, the pain of higher prices on goods imported today dims be-
side the pain we will eventually suffer if we drift along and trade
away ever larger portions of our country’s net worth.
I believe that ICs would produce, rather promptly, a U.S. trade
equilibrium well above present export levels but below present
import levels. The certificates would moderately aid all our in-
dustries in world competition, even as the free market determined
which of them ultimately met the test of “comparative advantage.”
This plan would not be copied by nations that are net exporters,
because their ICs would be valueless. Would major exporting coun-
tries retaliate in other ways? Would this start another Smoot-Haw-
ley tariff war? Hardly. At the time of Smoot-Hawley we ran an un-
reasonable trade surplus that we wished to maintain. We now run
a damaging deficit that the whole world knows we must correct.
For decades the world has struggled with a shifting maze of
punitive tariffs, export subsidies, quotas, dollar-locked curren-
cies, and the like. Many of these import-inhibiting and export-
encouraging devices have long been employed by major export-
ing countries trying to amass ever larger surpluses—yet
significant trade wars have not erupted. Surely one will not be
precipitated by a proposal that simply aims at balancing the books
of the world’s largest trade debtor. Major exporting countries
have behaved quite rationally in the past and they will continue
to do so—though, as always, it may be in their interest to attempt
to convince us that they will behave otherwise.
T
he likely outcome of an IC plan is that the exporting
nations—after some initial posturing—will turn their
ingenuity to encouraging imports from us. Take the
position of China, which today sells us about $140 bil-
lion of goods and services annually while purchas-
ing only $25 billion. Were ICs to exist, one course for China would
be simply to fill the gap by buying 115 billion certificates annu-
ally. But it could alternatively reduce its need for ICs by cutting
its exports to the U.S. or by increasing its purchases from us. This
last choice would probably be the most palatable for China, and
we should wish it to be so.
If our exports were to increase and the supply of ICs were
therefore to be enlarged, their market price would be driven
down. Indeed, if our exports expanded sufficiently, ICs would be
rendered valueless and the entire plan made moot. Presented
with the power to make this happen, important exporting coun-
tries might quickly eliminate the mechanisms they now use to in-
hibit exports from us.
Were we to install an IC plan, we might opt for some transi-
tion years in which we deliberately ran a relatively small deficit,
a step that would enable the world to adjust as we gradually got
where we need to be. Carrying this plan out, our government
could either auction “bonus” ICs every month or simply give
them, say, to less-developed countries needing to increase their
exports. The latter course would deliver a form of foreign aid
likely to be particularly effective and appreciated.
I
will close by reminding you again that I cried wolf once
before. In general, the batting average of doomsayers in
the U.S. is terrible. Our country has consistently made
fools of those who were skeptical about either our eco-
nomic potential or our resiliency. Many pessimistic
seers simply underestimated the dynamism that has allowed us
to overcome problems that once seemed ominous. We still have
a truly remarkable country and economy.
But I believe that in the trade deficit we also have a problem
that is going to test all of our abilities to find a solution. A gen-
tly declining dollar will not provide the answer. True, it would re-
duce our trade deficit to a degree, but not by enough to halt the
outflow of our country’s net worth and the resulting growth in
our investment-income deficit.
Perhaps there are other solutions that make more sense than
mine. However, wishful thinking—and its usual companion,
thumb sucking—is not among them. From what I now see, ac-
tion to halt the rapid outflow of our national wealth is called for,
and ICs seem the least painful and most certain way to get the
job done. Just keep remembering that this is not a small prob-
lem: For example, at the rate at which the rest of the world is now
making net investments in the U.S., it could annually buy and
sock away nearly 4% of our publicly traded stocks.
In evaluating business options at Berkshire, my partner,
Charles Munger, suggests that we pay close attention to his joc-
ular wish: “All I want to know is where I’m going to die, so I’ll
never go there.” Framers of our trade policy should heed this cau-
tion—and steer clear of Squanderville. F
WA R R E N B U F F E T T
Produced exclusively by Fortune Custom Reprints. ©2003 Time Inc. All rights reserved.

Contenu connexe

En vedette

Lesson 4 ppt (p2)
Lesson 4 ppt (p2)Lesson 4 ppt (p2)
Lesson 4 ppt (p2)citifinlit
 
фотоотчёт масленица)
фотоотчёт масленица)фотоотчёт масленица)
фотоотчёт масленица)virtualtaganrog
 
12 апреля день космонавтики
12 апреля   день космонавтики12 апреля   день космонавтики
12 апреля день космонавтикиvirtualtaganrog
 
El cielo y el infierno de un jugador
El cielo y el infierno de un jugadorEl cielo y el infierno de un jugador
El cielo y el infierno de un jugadorLola Arroyo
 
Lesson8 ppt (p2)
Lesson8 ppt (p2)Lesson8 ppt (p2)
Lesson8 ppt (p2)citifinlit
 
Lesson3 ppt (p2)
Lesson3 ppt (p2)Lesson3 ppt (p2)
Lesson3 ppt (p2)citifinlit
 
фотоотчёт сказка коза и 7козлят
фотоотчёт сказка коза и 7козлятфотоотчёт сказка коза и 7козлят
фотоотчёт сказка коза и 7козлятvirtualtaganrog
 
Lesson2 ppt (p2)
Lesson2 ppt (p2)Lesson2 ppt (p2)
Lesson2 ppt (p2)citifinlit
 
Development of the self in society
Development of the self in societyDevelopment of the self in society
Development of the self in societyMosa Kgaswane
 
Росшкола Обучение: 23.10. Документы на сайте и персональные данные
Росшкола Обучение: 23.10. Документы на сайте и персональные данныеРосшкола Обучение: 23.10. Документы на сайте и персональные данные
Росшкола Обучение: 23.10. Документы на сайте и персональные данныеRosshkola
 

En vedette (11)

Lesson 4 ppt (p2)
Lesson 4 ppt (p2)Lesson 4 ppt (p2)
Lesson 4 ppt (p2)
 
фотоотчёт масленица)
фотоотчёт масленица)фотоотчёт масленица)
фотоотчёт масленица)
 
12 апреля день космонавтики
12 апреля   день космонавтики12 апреля   день космонавтики
12 апреля день космонавтики
 
El cielo y el infierno de un jugador
El cielo y el infierno de un jugadorEl cielo y el infierno de un jugador
El cielo y el infierno de un jugador
 
Lesson8 ppt (p2)
Lesson8 ppt (p2)Lesson8 ppt (p2)
Lesson8 ppt (p2)
 
Lesson3 ppt (p2)
Lesson3 ppt (p2)Lesson3 ppt (p2)
Lesson3 ppt (p2)
 
SC-014-S/C/NR-2008
SC-014-S/C/NR-2008SC-014-S/C/NR-2008
SC-014-S/C/NR-2008
 
фотоотчёт сказка коза и 7козлят
фотоотчёт сказка коза и 7козлятфотоотчёт сказка коза и 7козлят
фотоотчёт сказка коза и 7козлят
 
Lesson2 ppt (p2)
Lesson2 ppt (p2)Lesson2 ppt (p2)
Lesson2 ppt (p2)
 
Development of the self in society
Development of the self in societyDevelopment of the self in society
Development of the self in society
 
Росшкола Обучение: 23.10. Документы на сайте и персональные данные
Росшкола Обучение: 23.10. Документы на сайте и персональные данныеРосшкола Обучение: 23.10. Документы на сайте и персональные данные
Росшкола Обучение: 23.10. Документы на сайте и персональные данные
 

Similaire à Buffett

US Economic Outlook 2008-11+
US Economic Outlook 2008-11+US Economic Outlook 2008-11+
US Economic Outlook 2008-11+contrarian2day
 
US Economic Outlook 2008-11+ (Updated)
US Economic Outlook 2008-11+  (Updated)US Economic Outlook 2008-11+  (Updated)
US Economic Outlook 2008-11+ (Updated)contrarian2day
 
Economic Outlook 2008
Economic Outlook 2008Economic Outlook 2008
Economic Outlook 2008DMajors
 
Soveriegn Society
Soveriegn SocietySoveriegn Society
Soveriegn SocietySwann Media
 
A visual guide toour national debt
A visual guide toour national debtA visual guide toour national debt
A visual guide toour national debtshawkatelbialy
 
Agcapita - February 27 2012 - Charts that Count
Agcapita - February 27 2012 - Charts that CountAgcapita - February 27 2012 - Charts that Count
Agcapita - February 27 2012 - Charts that CountVeripath Partners
 
The wealth of the world v3
The wealth of the world v3The wealth of the world v3
The wealth of the world v3simo0381
 
A visualization of the us dept
A visualization of the us deptA visualization of the us dept
A visualization of the us deptvivliorasis
 
The little book of bulletproof investing_070721130731.pdf
The little book of bulletproof investing_070721130731.pdfThe little book of bulletproof investing_070721130731.pdf
The little book of bulletproof investing_070721130731.pdfSumni Uchiha
 
Veripath Q3 2021 Investor Letter
Veripath Q3 2021 Investor LetterVeripath Q3 2021 Investor Letter
Veripath Q3 2021 Investor LetterVeripath Partners
 
Lesperance and Associates - Back up Plan
Lesperance and Associates - Back up PlanLesperance and Associates - Back up Plan
Lesperance and Associates - Back up PlanJeffreyGarcia51
 
The wealth of the world v2
The wealth of the world v2The wealth of the world v2
The wealth of the world v2simo0381
 
12-2 Productivity Its Role and Determinants Explaining why livi.docx
12-2 Productivity Its Role and Determinants Explaining why livi.docx12-2 Productivity Its Role and Determinants Explaining why livi.docx
12-2 Productivity Its Role and Determinants Explaining why livi.docxmoggdede
 
Ricardo V Lago -Interbank- Lima-22 04 2009
Ricardo V  Lago -Interbank- Lima-22 04 2009 Ricardo V  Lago -Interbank- Lima-22 04 2009
Ricardo V Lago -Interbank- Lima-22 04 2009 neiracar
 
Printable Writing Paper Vintage Map Print Scrapbo
Printable Writing Paper Vintage Map Print ScrapboPrintable Writing Paper Vintage Map Print Scrapbo
Printable Writing Paper Vintage Map Print ScrapboJulie Morales
 
Quoted_11_February 2015
Quoted_11_February 2015Quoted_11_February 2015
Quoted_11_February 2015Colin Bramble
 
Currency Article Discussion.pdf
Currency Article Discussion.pdfCurrency Article Discussion.pdf
Currency Article Discussion.pdfsdfghj21
 
July 4, 2014 Let Freedom Ring
July 4, 2014  Let Freedom RingJuly 4, 2014  Let Freedom Ring
July 4, 2014 Let Freedom RingRichard Kelley
 
Ricardo V Lago Universityof Miami Business Forum 15 01 2009
Ricardo V Lago Universityof Miami  Business Forum  15 01 2009Ricardo V Lago Universityof Miami  Business Forum  15 01 2009
Ricardo V Lago Universityof Miami Business Forum 15 01 2009neiracar
 

Similaire à Buffett (20)

US Economic Outlook 2008-11+
US Economic Outlook 2008-11+US Economic Outlook 2008-11+
US Economic Outlook 2008-11+
 
US Economic Outlook 2008-11+ (Updated)
US Economic Outlook 2008-11+  (Updated)US Economic Outlook 2008-11+  (Updated)
US Economic Outlook 2008-11+ (Updated)
 
Economic Outlook 2008
Economic Outlook 2008Economic Outlook 2008
Economic Outlook 2008
 
Soveriegn Society
Soveriegn SocietySoveriegn Society
Soveriegn Society
 
A visual guide toour national debt
A visual guide toour national debtA visual guide toour national debt
A visual guide toour national debt
 
Agcapita - February 27 2012 - Charts that Count
Agcapita - February 27 2012 - Charts that CountAgcapita - February 27 2012 - Charts that Count
Agcapita - February 27 2012 - Charts that Count
 
The wealth of the world v3
The wealth of the world v3The wealth of the world v3
The wealth of the world v3
 
A visualization of the us dept
A visualization of the us deptA visualization of the us dept
A visualization of the us dept
 
The little book of bulletproof investing_070721130731.pdf
The little book of bulletproof investing_070721130731.pdfThe little book of bulletproof investing_070721130731.pdf
The little book of bulletproof investing_070721130731.pdf
 
Veripath Q3 2021 Investor Letter
Veripath Q3 2021 Investor LetterVeripath Q3 2021 Investor Letter
Veripath Q3 2021 Investor Letter
 
Arial Case
Arial CaseArial Case
Arial Case
 
Lesperance and Associates - Back up Plan
Lesperance and Associates - Back up PlanLesperance and Associates - Back up Plan
Lesperance and Associates - Back up Plan
 
The wealth of the world v2
The wealth of the world v2The wealth of the world v2
The wealth of the world v2
 
12-2 Productivity Its Role and Determinants Explaining why livi.docx
12-2 Productivity Its Role and Determinants Explaining why livi.docx12-2 Productivity Its Role and Determinants Explaining why livi.docx
12-2 Productivity Its Role and Determinants Explaining why livi.docx
 
Ricardo V Lago -Interbank- Lima-22 04 2009
Ricardo V  Lago -Interbank- Lima-22 04 2009 Ricardo V  Lago -Interbank- Lima-22 04 2009
Ricardo V Lago -Interbank- Lima-22 04 2009
 
Printable Writing Paper Vintage Map Print Scrapbo
Printable Writing Paper Vintage Map Print ScrapboPrintable Writing Paper Vintage Map Print Scrapbo
Printable Writing Paper Vintage Map Print Scrapbo
 
Quoted_11_February 2015
Quoted_11_February 2015Quoted_11_February 2015
Quoted_11_February 2015
 
Currency Article Discussion.pdf
Currency Article Discussion.pdfCurrency Article Discussion.pdf
Currency Article Discussion.pdf
 
July 4, 2014 Let Freedom Ring
July 4, 2014  Let Freedom RingJuly 4, 2014  Let Freedom Ring
July 4, 2014 Let Freedom Ring
 
Ricardo V Lago Universityof Miami Business Forum 15 01 2009
Ricardo V Lago Universityof Miami  Business Forum  15 01 2009Ricardo V Lago Universityof Miami  Business Forum  15 01 2009
Ricardo V Lago Universityof Miami Business Forum 15 01 2009
 

Dernier

Jual obat aborsi Tawangmangu ( 085657271886 ) Cytote pil telat bulan penggugu...
Jual obat aborsi Tawangmangu ( 085657271886 ) Cytote pil telat bulan penggugu...Jual obat aborsi Tawangmangu ( 085657271886 ) Cytote pil telat bulan penggugu...
Jual obat aborsi Tawangmangu ( 085657271886 ) Cytote pil telat bulan penggugu...Klinik kandungan
 
Osisko Gold Royalties Ltd - Corporate Presentation, May 2024
Osisko Gold Royalties Ltd - Corporate Presentation, May 2024Osisko Gold Royalties Ltd - Corporate Presentation, May 2024
Osisko Gold Royalties Ltd - Corporate Presentation, May 2024Osisko Gold Royalties Ltd
 
Terna - 1Q 2024 Consolidated Results Presentation
Terna - 1Q 2024 Consolidated Results PresentationTerna - 1Q 2024 Consolidated Results Presentation
Terna - 1Q 2024 Consolidated Results PresentationTerna SpA
 
Western Copper and Gold - May 2024 Presentation
Western Copper and Gold - May 2024 PresentationWestern Copper and Gold - May 2024 Presentation
Western Copper and Gold - May 2024 PresentationPaul West-Sells
 
Osisko Development - Investor Presentation - May 2024
Osisko Development - Investor Presentation - May 2024Osisko Development - Investor Presentation - May 2024
Osisko Development - Investor Presentation - May 2024Philip Rabenok
 
Premium Call Girls In Kapurthala} 9332606886❤️VVIP Sonya Call Girls
Premium Call Girls In Kapurthala} 9332606886❤️VVIP Sonya Call GirlsPremium Call Girls In Kapurthala} 9332606886❤️VVIP Sonya Call Girls
Premium Call Girls In Kapurthala} 9332606886❤️VVIP Sonya Call Girlsmeghakumariji156
 
AMG Quarterly Investor Presentation May 2024
AMG Quarterly Investor Presentation May 2024AMG Quarterly Investor Presentation May 2024
AMG Quarterly Investor Presentation May 2024gstubel
 
countries with the highest gold reserves in 2024
countries with the highest gold reserves in 2024countries with the highest gold reserves in 2024
countries with the highest gold reserves in 2024Kweku Zurek
 
Gorakhpur Call Girls 8250092165 Low Price Escorts Service in Your Area
Gorakhpur Call Girls 8250092165 Low Price Escorts Service in Your AreaGorakhpur Call Girls 8250092165 Low Price Escorts Service in Your Area
Gorakhpur Call Girls 8250092165 Low Price Escorts Service in Your Areameghakumariji156
 
The Leonardo 1Q 2024 Results Presentation
The Leonardo 1Q 2024 Results PresentationThe Leonardo 1Q 2024 Results Presentation
The Leonardo 1Q 2024 Results PresentationLeonardo
 
Camil Institutional Presentation_Mai24.pdf
Camil Institutional Presentation_Mai24.pdfCamil Institutional Presentation_Mai24.pdf
Camil Institutional Presentation_Mai24.pdfCAMILRI
 
Teekay Corporation Q1-24 Earnings Results
Teekay Corporation Q1-24 Earnings ResultsTeekay Corporation Q1-24 Earnings Results
Teekay Corporation Q1-24 Earnings ResultsTeekay Corporation
 
Dubai Call Girls/// Hot Afternoon O525547819 Call Girls In Dubai
Dubai Call Girls/// Hot Afternoon O525547819 Call Girls In DubaiDubai Call Girls/// Hot Afternoon O525547819 Call Girls In Dubai
Dubai Call Girls/// Hot Afternoon O525547819 Call Girls In Dubaikojalkojal131
 
Camil Institutional Presentation_Mai24.pdf
Camil Institutional Presentation_Mai24.pdfCamil Institutional Presentation_Mai24.pdf
Camil Institutional Presentation_Mai24.pdfCAMILRI
 
Financial Results for the Fiscal Year Ended March 2024
Financial Results for the Fiscal Year Ended March 2024Financial Results for the Fiscal Year Ended March 2024
Financial Results for the Fiscal Year Ended March 2024KDDI
 
Corporate Presentation Probe Canaccord Conference 2024.pdf
Corporate Presentation Probe Canaccord Conference 2024.pdfCorporate Presentation Probe Canaccord Conference 2024.pdf
Corporate Presentation Probe Canaccord Conference 2024.pdfProbe Gold
 
一比一原版(Acadia毕业证书)加拿大阿卡迪亚大学毕业证学历认证可查认证
一比一原版(Acadia毕业证书)加拿大阿卡迪亚大学毕业证学历认证可查认证一比一原版(Acadia毕业证书)加拿大阿卡迪亚大学毕业证学历认证可查认证
一比一原版(Acadia毕业证书)加拿大阿卡迪亚大学毕业证学历认证可查认证xzxvi5zp
 

Dernier (20)

Jual obat aborsi Tawangmangu ( 085657271886 ) Cytote pil telat bulan penggugu...
Jual obat aborsi Tawangmangu ( 085657271886 ) Cytote pil telat bulan penggugu...Jual obat aborsi Tawangmangu ( 085657271886 ) Cytote pil telat bulan penggugu...
Jual obat aborsi Tawangmangu ( 085657271886 ) Cytote pil telat bulan penggugu...
 
Osisko Gold Royalties Ltd - Corporate Presentation, May 2024
Osisko Gold Royalties Ltd - Corporate Presentation, May 2024Osisko Gold Royalties Ltd - Corporate Presentation, May 2024
Osisko Gold Royalties Ltd - Corporate Presentation, May 2024
 
Terna - 1Q 2024 Consolidated Results Presentation
Terna - 1Q 2024 Consolidated Results PresentationTerna - 1Q 2024 Consolidated Results Presentation
Terna - 1Q 2024 Consolidated Results Presentation
 
Western Copper and Gold - May 2024 Presentation
Western Copper and Gold - May 2024 PresentationWestern Copper and Gold - May 2024 Presentation
Western Copper and Gold - May 2024 Presentation
 
Osisko Development - Investor Presentation - May 2024
Osisko Development - Investor Presentation - May 2024Osisko Development - Investor Presentation - May 2024
Osisko Development - Investor Presentation - May 2024
 
Premium Call Girls In Kapurthala} 9332606886❤️VVIP Sonya Call Girls
Premium Call Girls In Kapurthala} 9332606886❤️VVIP Sonya Call GirlsPremium Call Girls In Kapurthala} 9332606886❤️VVIP Sonya Call Girls
Premium Call Girls In Kapurthala} 9332606886❤️VVIP Sonya Call Girls
 
AMG Quarterly Investor Presentation May 2024
AMG Quarterly Investor Presentation May 2024AMG Quarterly Investor Presentation May 2024
AMG Quarterly Investor Presentation May 2024
 
countries with the highest gold reserves in 2024
countries with the highest gold reserves in 2024countries with the highest gold reserves in 2024
countries with the highest gold reserves in 2024
 
Gorakhpur Call Girls 8250092165 Low Price Escorts Service in Your Area
Gorakhpur Call Girls 8250092165 Low Price Escorts Service in Your AreaGorakhpur Call Girls 8250092165 Low Price Escorts Service in Your Area
Gorakhpur Call Girls 8250092165 Low Price Escorts Service in Your Area
 
The Leonardo 1Q 2024 Results Presentation
The Leonardo 1Q 2024 Results PresentationThe Leonardo 1Q 2024 Results Presentation
The Leonardo 1Q 2024 Results Presentation
 
Camil Institutional Presentation_Mai24.pdf
Camil Institutional Presentation_Mai24.pdfCamil Institutional Presentation_Mai24.pdf
Camil Institutional Presentation_Mai24.pdf
 
Teekay Corporation Q1-24 Earnings Results
Teekay Corporation Q1-24 Earnings ResultsTeekay Corporation Q1-24 Earnings Results
Teekay Corporation Q1-24 Earnings Results
 
SME IPO Opportunity and Trends of May 2024
SME IPO Opportunity and Trends of May 2024SME IPO Opportunity and Trends of May 2024
SME IPO Opportunity and Trends of May 2024
 
Dubai Call Girls/// Hot Afternoon O525547819 Call Girls In Dubai
Dubai Call Girls/// Hot Afternoon O525547819 Call Girls In DubaiDubai Call Girls/// Hot Afternoon O525547819 Call Girls In Dubai
Dubai Call Girls/// Hot Afternoon O525547819 Call Girls In Dubai
 
Osisko Gold Royalties Ltd - Q1 2024 Results
Osisko Gold Royalties Ltd - Q1 2024 ResultsOsisko Gold Royalties Ltd - Q1 2024 Results
Osisko Gold Royalties Ltd - Q1 2024 Results
 
Camil Institutional Presentation_Mai24.pdf
Camil Institutional Presentation_Mai24.pdfCamil Institutional Presentation_Mai24.pdf
Camil Institutional Presentation_Mai24.pdf
 
Financial Results for the Fiscal Year Ended March 2024
Financial Results for the Fiscal Year Ended March 2024Financial Results for the Fiscal Year Ended March 2024
Financial Results for the Fiscal Year Ended March 2024
 
Corporate Presentation Probe Canaccord Conference 2024.pdf
Corporate Presentation Probe Canaccord Conference 2024.pdfCorporate Presentation Probe Canaccord Conference 2024.pdf
Corporate Presentation Probe Canaccord Conference 2024.pdf
 
一比一原版(Acadia毕业证书)加拿大阿卡迪亚大学毕业证学历认证可查认证
一比一原版(Acadia毕业证书)加拿大阿卡迪亚大学毕业证学历认证可查认证一比一原版(Acadia毕业证书)加拿大阿卡迪亚大学毕业证学历认证可查认证
一比一原版(Acadia毕业证书)加拿大阿卡迪亚大学毕业证学历认证可查认证
 
ITAU EQUITY_STRATEGY_WARM_UP_20240505 DHG.pdf
ITAU EQUITY_STRATEGY_WARM_UP_20240505 DHG.pdfITAU EQUITY_STRATEGY_WARM_UP_20240505 DHG.pdf
ITAU EQUITY_STRATEGY_WARM_UP_20240505 DHG.pdf
 

Buffett

  • 1. America’s Growing Trade Deficit Is Selling the Nation Out From Under Us. Here’s a Way to Fix the Problem—And We Need to Do It Now. by Warren E. Buffett I’M ABOUT TO DELIVER A WARNING regarding the U.S. trade deficit and also suggest a remedy for the problem. But first I need to mention two reasons you might want to be skeptical about what I say. To begin, my forecasting record with respect to macroeconomics is far from inspiring. For example, over the past two decades I was excessively fearful of inflation. More to the point at hand, I started way back in 1987 to publicly worry about our mounting trade deficits—and, as you know, we’ve not only survived but also thrived. So on the trade front, score at least one “wolf” for me. Nevertheless, I am crying wolf again and NOVEMBER 10, 2003 FORTUNE
  • 2. this time backing it with Berkshire Hath- away’s money. Through the spring of 2002, I had lived nearly 72 years without purchasing a foreign currency. Since then Berkshire has made significant invest- ments in—and today holds—several cur- rencies. I won’t give you particulars; in fact, it is largely irrelevant which curren- cies they are. What does matter is the un- derlying point: To hold other currencies is to believe that the dollar will decline. Both as an American and as an in- vestor, I actually hope these commit- ments prove to be a mistake. Any prof- its Berkshire might make from currency trading would pale against the losses the company and our shareholders, in other aspects of their lives, would incur from a plunging dollar. But as head of Berkshire Hathaway, I am in charge of investing its money in ways that make sense. And my reason for finally putting my money where my mouth has been so long is that our trade deficit has greatly worsened, to the point that our country’s “net worth,” so to speak, is now being transferred abroad at an alarming rate. A perpetuation of this trans- fer will lead to major trou- ble. To understand why, take a wildly fanciful trip with me to two isolated, side-by-side islands of equal size, Squan- derville and Thriftville. Land is the only capital asset on these islands, and their communities are primitive, needing only food and producing only food. Work- ing eight hours a day, in fact, each in- habitant can produce enough food to sustain himself or herself. And for a long time that’s how things go along. On each island everybody works the prescribed eight hours a day, which means that each society is self-sufficient. Eventually, though, the industrious citizens of Thriftville decide to do some serious saving and investing, and they start to work 16 hours a day. In this mode they continue to live off the food they produce in eight hours of work but be- gin exporting an equal amount to their one and only trading outlet, Squan- derville. The citizens of Squanderville are ec- static about this turn of events, since they can now live their lives free from toil but eat as well as ever. Oh, yes, there’s a quid pro quo—but to the Squanders, it seems harmless: All that the Thrifts want in exchange for their WA R R E N B U F F E T T –$100 billion $0 –$200 –$300 –$400 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2003 FORTUNE estimate –$500 billion $0 –$1 trillion –$1.5 –$2 –$2.5 6/03 FORTUNE estimate U.S. TRADE SURPLUS/DEFICIT U.S. NET INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT U.S. holdings of foreign assets minus foreign holdings of U.S. assets* Facing up to the effects of our trade imbalance FORTUNEGRAPHIC/SOURCE:BUREAUOFECONOMICANALYSIS,U.S.DEPARTMENTOFCOMMERCE *Data for 1976 and later years are not strictly comparable with pre-1976 data. Truth and consequences Huge and growing U.S. trade deficits … … are inevitably putting an ever larger slice of America in foreign hands
  • 3. food is Squanderbonds (which are denominated, naturally, in Squanderbucks). Over time Thriftville accumulates an enor- mous amount of these bonds, which at their core represent claim checks on the future output of Squanderville. A few pundits in Squanderville smell trouble coming. They foresee that for the Squanders both to eat and to pay off—or simply service—the debt they’re piling up will eventually require them to work more than eight hours a day. But the residents of Squanderville are in no mood to listen to such doomsaying. Meanwhile, the citizens of Thriftville begin to get nervous. Just how good, they ask, are the IOUs of a shiftless island? So the Thrifts change strategy: Though they continue to hold some bonds, they sell most of them to Squanderville residents for Squanderbucks and use the proceeds to buy Squanderville land. And eventually the Thrifts own all of Squanderville. At that point, the Squanders are forced to deal with an ugly equation: They must now not only return to working eight hours a day in order to eat—they have nothing left to trade—but must also work additional hours to service their debt and pay Thriftville rent on the land so imprudently sold. In effect, Squan- derville has been colonized by purchase rather than conquest. It can be argued, of course, that the present value of the fu- ture production that Squanderville must forever ship to Thrift- ville only equates to the production Thriftville initially gave up and that therefore both have received a fair deal. But since one generation of Squanders gets the free ride and future generations pay in perpetuity for it, there are—in economist talk—some pretty dramatic “intergenerational inequities.” Let’s think of it in terms of a family: Imagine that I, Warren Buffett, can get the suppliers of all that I consume in my life- time to take Buffett family IOUs that are payable, in goods and services and with interest added, by my descendants. This sce- nario may be viewed as effecting an even trade between the Buf- fett family unit and its creditors. But the generations of Buffetts following me are not likely to applaud the deal (and, heaven for- bid, may even attempt to welsh on it). Think again about those islands: Sooner or later the Squan- derville government, facing ever greater payments to service debt, would decide to embrace highly inflationary policies—that is, is- sue more Squanderbucks to dilute the value of each. After all, the government would reason, those irritating Squanderbonds are simply claims on specific numbers of Squanderbucks, not on bucks of specific value. In short, making Squanderbucks less valu- able would ease the island’s fiscal pain. That prospect is why I, were I a resident of Thriftville, would opt for direct ownership of Squanderville land rather than bonds of the island’s government. Most governments find it much harder morally to seize foreign-owned property than they do to dilute the purchasing power of claim checks foreigners hold. Theft by stealth is preferred to theft by force. S o what does all this island hopping have to do with the U.S.? Simply put, after World War II and up un- til the early 1970s we operated in the industrious Thriftville style, regularly selling more abroad than we purchased. We concurrently invested our surplus abroad, with the result that our net investment—that is, our hold- ings of foreign assets less foreign holdings of U.S. assets—in- creased (under methodology, since revised, that the govern- ment was then using) from $37 billion in 1950 to $68 billion in 1970. In those days, to sum up, our country’s “net worth,” viewed in totality, consisted of all the wealth within our borders plus a modest portion of the wealth in the rest of the world. Additionally, because the U.S. was in a net ownership position with respect to the rest of the world, we realized net investment income that, piled on top of our trade surplus, became a second source of investable funds. Our fiscal situation was thus similar to that of an individual who was both saving some of his salary and reinvesting the dividends from his existing nest egg. In the late 1970s the trade situation reversed, producing deficits that initially ran about 1% of GDP. That was hardly serious, par- ticularly because net investment income remained positive. In- deed, with the power of compound interest working for us, our net ownership balance hit its high in 1980 at $360 billion. Since then, however, it’s been all downhill, with the pace of de- cline rapidly accelerating in the past five years. Our annual trade deficit now exceeds 4% of GDP. Equally ominous, the rest of the world owns a staggering $2.5 trillion more of the U.S. than we own of other countries. Some of this $2.5 trillion is invested in claim checks—U.S. bonds, both governmental and private— and some in such assets as property and equity securities. In effect, our country has been behaving like an extraordinarily rich family that possesses an immense farm. In order to consume 4% more than we produce—that’s the trade deficit—we have, day by day, been both selling pieces of the farm and increasing the mortgage on what we still own. To put the $2.5 trillion of net foreign ownership in perspec- tive, contrast it with the $12 trillion value of publicly owned U.S. stocks or the equal amount of U.S. residential real estate or what I would estimate as a grand total of $50 trillion in na- tional wealth. Those comparisons show that what’s already been transferred abroad is meaningful—in the area, for exam- ple, of 5% of our national wealth. More important, however, is that foreign ownership of our as- sets will grow at about $500 billion per year at the present trade-deficit level, which means that the deficit will be adding about one percentage point annually to foreigners’ net owner- ship of our national wealth. As that ownership grows, so will the annual net investment income flowing out of this country. That will leave us paying ever-increasing dividends and interest to the world rather than being a net receiver of them, as in the past. We have entered the world of negative compounding— goodbye pleasure, hello pain. We were taught in Economics 101 that countries could not for long sustain large, ever-growing trade deficits. At a point, so it was claimed, the spree of the consumption-happy nation would be braked by currency-rate adjustments and by the unwillingness of creditor countries to accept an endless flow of IOUs from the big spenders. And that’s the way it has indeed worked for the rest of the world, as we can see by the abrupt shutoffs of credit that many profligate nations have suffered in recent decades. The U.S., however, enjoys special status. In effect, we can be- have today as we wish because our past financial behavior was so exemplary—and because we are so rich. Neither our capacity nor our intention to pay is questioned, and we continue to have a moun- tain of desirable assets to trade for consumables. In other words, Through the spring of 2002, I had lived nearly 72 years without purchasing a foreign currency. That has changed. WA R R E N B U F F E T T
  • 4. our national credit card allows us to charge truly breathtaking amounts. But that card’s credit line is not limitless. The time to halt this trading of assets for consumables is now, and I have a plan to suggest for getting it done. My remedy may sound gimmicky, and in truth it is a tariff called by another name. But this is a tariff that retains most free-market virtues, neither protecting specific industries nor punishing specific coun- tries nor encouraging trade wars. This plan would increase our exports and might well lead to increased overall world trade. And it would balance our books without there being a significant de- cline in the value of the dollar, which I believe is otherwise al- most certain to occur. W e would achieve this balance by issuing what I will call Import Certificates (ICs) to all U.S. exporters in an amount equal to the dollar value of their exports. Each exporter would, in turn, sell the ICs to parties—either ex- porters abroad or importers here—wanting to get goods into the U.S. To import $1 million of goods, for example, an importer would need ICs that were the byproduct of $1 million of ex- ports. The inevitable result: trade balance. Because our exports total about $80 billion a month, ICs would be issued in huge, equivalent quantities—that is, 80 bil- lion certificates a month—and would surely trade in an ex- ceptionally liquid market. Competition would then determine who among those parties wanting to sell to us would buy the certificates and how much they would pay. (I visualize that the certificates would be issued with a short life, possibly of six months, so that speculators would be discouraged from accu- mulating them.) For illustrative purposes, let’s postulate that each IC would sell for 10 cents—that is, 10 cents per dollar of exports behind them. Other things being equal, this amount would mean a U.S. pro- ducer could realize 10% more by selling his goods in the export market than by selling them domestically, with the extra 10% coming from his sales of ICs. In my opinion, many exporters would view this as a reduc- tion in cost, one that would let them cut the prices of their prod- ucts in international markets. Commodity-type products would particularly encourage this kind of be- havior. If aluminum, for example, was sell- ing for 66 cents per pound domestically and ICs were worth 10%, domestic alu- minum producers could sell for about 60 cents per pound (plus transportation costs) in foreign markets and still earn normal margins. In this scenario, the out- put of the U.S. would become significantly more competitive and exports would ex- pand. Along the way, the number of jobs would grow. Foreigners selling to us, of course, would face tougher economics. But that’s a prob- lem they’re up against no matter what trade “solution” is adopted—and make no mis- take, a solution must come. (As Herb Stein said, “If something cannot go on forever, it will stop.”) In one way the IC approach would give countries selling to us great flex- ibility, since the plan does not penalize any specific industry or product. In the end, the free market would determine what would be sold in the U.S. and who would sell it. The ICs would determine only the aggre- gate dollar volume of what was sold. To see what would happen to imports, let’s look at a car now entering the U.S. at a cost to the importer of $20,000. Under the new plan and the assumption that ICs sell for 10%, the importer’s cost would rise to $22,000. If demand for the car was ex- ceptionally strong, the importer might manage to pass all of this on to the Amer- ican consumer. In the usual case, however, competitive forces would take hold, re- quiring the foreign manufacturer to absorb some, if not all, of the $2,000 IC cost. An ominous fact: The rest of the world owns a staggering $2.5 trillion more of the U.S. than we own of other countries. WA R R E N B U F F E T T HOW OFTEN HAVE YOU SEEN A COMMENT LIKE THIS IN ARTICLES ABOUT the U.S. dollar? “Analysts say that what really worries them is that foreigners will start moving out of the dollar.” Next time you see something like that, dismiss it. The fact is that foreigners— as a whole—cannot ditch their dollars. Indeed, because our trade deficit is constantly putting new dollars into the hands of foreigners, they have to just as constantly increase their U.S. investments. It’s true, of course, that the rest of the world can choose which U.S. assets to hold. They can decide, for example, to sell U.S. bonds to buy U.S. stocks. Or they can make a move into real estate, as the Japanese did in the 1980s. Moreover, any of those moves, particularly if they are carried out by anxious sellers or buyers, can influence the price of the dollar. But imagine that the Japanese both want to get out of their U.S. real estate and entirely away from dollar assets. They can’t accomplish that by selling their real estate to Americans, because they will get paid in dollars. And if they sell their real estate to non-Americans—say, the French, for euros—the property will remain in the hands of foreigners. With either kind of sale, the dollar assets held by the rest of the world will not (except for any concurrent shift in the price of the dollar) have changed. The bottom line is that other nations simply can’t disinvest in the U.S. unless they, as a universe, buy more goods and services from us than we buy from them. That state of affairs would be called an American trade surplus, and we don’t have one. You can dream up some radical plots for changing the situation. For example, the rest of the world could send the U.S. massive foreign aid that would serve to offset our trade deficit. But under any realistic view of things, our huge trade deficit guarantees that the rest of the world must not only hold the American assets it owns but consistently add to them. And that’s why, of course, our national net worth is gradually shifting away from our shores. Why Foreigners Can’t Ditch Their Dollars
  • 5. T here is no free lunch in the IC plan: It would have certain serious negative consequences for U.S. cit- izens. Prices of most imported products would in- crease, and so would the prices of certain competi- tive products manufactured domestically. The cost of the ICs, either in whole or in part, would therefore typically act as a tax on consumers. That is a serious drawback. But there would be drawbacks also to the dollar continuing to lose value or to our increasing tariffs on specific products or instituting quotas on them—courses of action that in my opinion offer a smaller chance of success. Above all, the pain of higher prices on goods imported today dims be- side the pain we will eventually suffer if we drift along and trade away ever larger portions of our country’s net worth. I believe that ICs would produce, rather promptly, a U.S. trade equilibrium well above present export levels but below present import levels. The certificates would moderately aid all our in- dustries in world competition, even as the free market determined which of them ultimately met the test of “comparative advantage.” This plan would not be copied by nations that are net exporters, because their ICs would be valueless. Would major exporting coun- tries retaliate in other ways? Would this start another Smoot-Haw- ley tariff war? Hardly. At the time of Smoot-Hawley we ran an un- reasonable trade surplus that we wished to maintain. We now run a damaging deficit that the whole world knows we must correct. For decades the world has struggled with a shifting maze of punitive tariffs, export subsidies, quotas, dollar-locked curren- cies, and the like. Many of these import-inhibiting and export- encouraging devices have long been employed by major export- ing countries trying to amass ever larger surpluses—yet significant trade wars have not erupted. Surely one will not be precipitated by a proposal that simply aims at balancing the books of the world’s largest trade debtor. Major exporting countries have behaved quite rationally in the past and they will continue to do so—though, as always, it may be in their interest to attempt to convince us that they will behave otherwise. T he likely outcome of an IC plan is that the exporting nations—after some initial posturing—will turn their ingenuity to encouraging imports from us. Take the position of China, which today sells us about $140 bil- lion of goods and services annually while purchas- ing only $25 billion. Were ICs to exist, one course for China would be simply to fill the gap by buying 115 billion certificates annu- ally. But it could alternatively reduce its need for ICs by cutting its exports to the U.S. or by increasing its purchases from us. This last choice would probably be the most palatable for China, and we should wish it to be so. If our exports were to increase and the supply of ICs were therefore to be enlarged, their market price would be driven down. Indeed, if our exports expanded sufficiently, ICs would be rendered valueless and the entire plan made moot. Presented with the power to make this happen, important exporting coun- tries might quickly eliminate the mechanisms they now use to in- hibit exports from us. Were we to install an IC plan, we might opt for some transi- tion years in which we deliberately ran a relatively small deficit, a step that would enable the world to adjust as we gradually got where we need to be. Carrying this plan out, our government could either auction “bonus” ICs every month or simply give them, say, to less-developed countries needing to increase their exports. The latter course would deliver a form of foreign aid likely to be particularly effective and appreciated. I will close by reminding you again that I cried wolf once before. In general, the batting average of doomsayers in the U.S. is terrible. Our country has consistently made fools of those who were skeptical about either our eco- nomic potential or our resiliency. Many pessimistic seers simply underestimated the dynamism that has allowed us to overcome problems that once seemed ominous. We still have a truly remarkable country and economy. But I believe that in the trade deficit we also have a problem that is going to test all of our abilities to find a solution. A gen- tly declining dollar will not provide the answer. True, it would re- duce our trade deficit to a degree, but not by enough to halt the outflow of our country’s net worth and the resulting growth in our investment-income deficit. Perhaps there are other solutions that make more sense than mine. However, wishful thinking—and its usual companion, thumb sucking—is not among them. From what I now see, ac- tion to halt the rapid outflow of our national wealth is called for, and ICs seem the least painful and most certain way to get the job done. Just keep remembering that this is not a small prob- lem: For example, at the rate at which the rest of the world is now making net investments in the U.S., it could annually buy and sock away nearly 4% of our publicly traded stocks. In evaluating business options at Berkshire, my partner, Charles Munger, suggests that we pay close attention to his joc- ular wish: “All I want to know is where I’m going to die, so I’ll never go there.” Framers of our trade policy should heed this cau- tion—and steer clear of Squanderville. F WA R R E N B U F F E T T Produced exclusively by Fortune Custom Reprints. ©2003 Time Inc. All rights reserved.