SlideShare une entreprise Scribd logo
1  sur  101
Télécharger pour lire hors ligne
Revenue Mobilization in Developing Countries
Prepared by Dr Malik Khalid Mehmood PhD
Chief Policy Adviser
March18,2011
Contents Page
AbbreviationsandAcronyms....................................................................................................3
Executive Summary...................................................................................................................4
I. Introduction............................................................................................................................6
II. Aims,Trends, andPossibilities .............................................................................................6
A.ObjectivesandContext .............................................................................................7
B. Similarities, Differences, and Strategies for Reform ................................................8
C.Trends andRecentExperience................................................................................12
D. Assessing the Scope to Raise More Revenue .........................................................16
III. Issues andLessons.............................................................................................................17
A. Core Administration Reforms.................................................................................19
B. The Value-Added Tax (VAT) .................................................................................23
C. Trade Liberalization and Customs Administration .................................................28
D. PersonalIncomeTaxation.......................................................................................31
E. TaxingCorporations................................................................................................33
F.Excises.....................................................................................................................37
G.TaxingSmall Businesses........................................................................................39
H. Real Estate Taxation ...............................................................................................41
IV. InstitutionsandTransparency............................................................................................42
V. Issues forDiscussion...........................................................................................................45
Table
1.VAT Features byIncomeGroup...........................................................................................25
Figures
1. Revenue-RelatedandOtherStructuralBenchmarks,2002-10...........................................11
2. TrendsinTotalandTaxRevenue1980-2009.....................................................................12
2
3.ReceiptsfromNaturalResources,averages2000-07..........................................................13
4. Tax Revenue Developments in Resource-Rich and Other Countries, 1980-2009..............14
5. Tax Revenue Developments byRegion,1980-2009...........................................................15
6. Distributionofthe TaxRatioinDevelopingCountries,1990-95and2003-08 .................15
7. Trends inthe CompositionofRevenues, 1980-2009..........................................................16
8.The Spreadofthe VAT,1980-2009....................................................................................24
9. Benefits from Zero-Rating Relative to Income Shares, Mexico..........................................26
10. Developments in Trade Tax Revenue and Collected Tariff Rates, 1980-2009 ................28
11. DevelopmentsinTaxRevenueandTrade TaxRevenue,1980-2009...............................29
12. DevelopmentsinCorporate TaxRates andRevenues, 1980-2009...................................34
13.DevelopmentsinExciseRevenues,1980-2008................................................................37
Boxes
1. CommonElementsofStrategiesfor Reform.......................................................................10
2. The RegionalPerspective ....................................................................................................15
3. Aid, Resource Wealth, and Revenue Mobilization..............................................................16
4. KeyChallenges forTaxReform ..........................................................................................18
5. The Distributional Impact ofExemptions and Reduced Rates............................................26
Appendices
I. Technical Assistance onTax Matters...................................................................................46
II. II. Tax Reform in Post-Conflict and Successor States.............................................................48
III. III. Data ....................................................................................................................................50
IV. IV. UnderstandingTax Performance and Effort......................................................................56
V. V. Estimating Tax Effort..........................................................................................................59
VI. VI. StrongPerformers—Three Examples................................................................................63
VII. VII. Taxing Natural Resources—Issues and Principles...........................................................66
VIII. VIII. Estimated Revenue Gains from Increasing VAT Efficiency ..........................................68
IX. IX. Zambia: Building and Maintaining a VAT........................................................................70
X. X. Dangers of Tax Holidays ....................................................................................................71
XI. XI. Regional Agreement on Corporate Taxation—Possible Principles...................................72
XII. XII. Experience with Unilateral Removal of Tax Incentive..................................................74
Appendix Tables
2. SummaryStatistics...............................................................................................................53
3. Fixed CountryGrouping......................................................................................................55
4. EstimatedTax Effort............................................................................................................60
5. VAT Efficiencyby Income Group ......................................................................................68
Appendix Figure
14. Revenue Administration and Tax Policy Mission Intensity, FY2008-10 .........................46
References................................................................................................................................75
3
ABBREVIATIONS AND ACRONYMS
C
E
M
A
C
C
I
T
E
A
C
E
C
O
W
A
S
F
A
D
I
T
H
R
L
I
C
L
M
I
C
LTO
PIT
RA
SACU
SIC
SOE
TPC
VAT
UMIC
WAEMU
WCO
WTO
C
o
m
m
un
au
té
É
co
no
m
iq
ue
de
s
Ét
at
s
d'
A
fri
qu
e
C
en
tra
le
C
o
r
p
o
r
a
t
e
I
n
c
o
m
e
T
a
x
E
a
s
t
A
f
r
i
c
a
n
C
o
m
m
u
n
i
t
y
Economic
Community of
West African
States
F
i
s
c
a
l
A
f
f
a
i
r
s
D
e
p
a
r
t
m
e
n
t
I
n
f
o
r
m
a
t
i
o
n
T
e
c
h
n
o
l
o
g
y
H
u
m
a
n
R
e
s
o
u
r
c
e
s
L
o
w
-
I
n
c
o
m
e
C
o
u
n
t
r
y
Lo
wer
Mid
dle-
Inco
me
Cou
ntry
L
a
r
g
e
T
a
x
p
a
y
e
r
O
f
f
i
c
e
P
e
r
s
o
n
a
l
I
n
c
o
m
e
T
a
x
R
e
v
e
n
u
e
A
u
t
h
o
r
i
t
y
S
o
u
t
h
ern
Africa
n
Custo
ms
Union
Soc
ial
Ins
ura
nce
Co
ntri
buti
ons
S
t
a
t
e
-
O
w
n
e
d
E
n
t
e
r
p
r
i
s
e
T
a
x
P
r
o
c
e
d
u
r
e
s
C
o
d
e
V
a
l
u
e
-
A
d
d
e
d
T
a
x
U
p
p
e
r
M
i
d
d
l
e
-
I
n
c
o
me
Cou
ntry
West African
Economic and
Monetary Union
W
or
ld
C
us
to
m
s
O
rg
an
iz
ati
on
W
o
r
l
d
T
r
a
d
e
O
r
g
a
n
i
z
a
t
i
o
n
4
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
TheFundhaslongplayedaleadroleinsupportingdevelopingcountries'effortsto
improvetheirrevenuemobilization. Thispaperdrawsonthatexperiencetoreviewissuesand
good practice,andto assess prospects inthis keyarea.1
Theneedforadditionalrevenueissubstantialinmanydevelopingcountries,butimproving
revenuemobilizationhasimportancebeyondthat. Requirementsforrelievingpovertyand
improving infrastructure are substantial: achieving the Millennium Development Goals, for
instance, may require low-income countries to raise their tax-GDP ratios by around 4 percentage
points (UnitedNations, 2005). But the quality ofmeasures also matters: increasingrevenue by
further taxing readily compliant taxpayers can worsen distortions and perceived inequities;
conversely, reducingreliance ontrade taxes can bring real structural gains that outweigh
short-term revenue difficulties. More fundamentally still, the centrality of taxation in the exercise
ofstate powermeans that moreefficient,fairer,andless corrupttaxsystems can spearhead
improvement in wider governance relations.
Experienceshowsthatprogresscanbemade—givenstrongpoliticalwill.Therehavebeen
disappointments: insome areas ofadvice (such as early espousal ofthe global income tax) and in
country practice (the use made of improved IT systems, for instance). But several countries have
significantly improved their tax performance over relatively short periods, and econometric
analysis (comparing performance in differing countries) suggests that many lower-income
countries could increase their tax ratios by 2-4 percent of GDP. A commonelement of success
stories is sustained political commitment at the highest levels: even administrative reforms can
promptstrongopposition.Reforms must be entrenched,however,to avoidsubsequentslippage.
Significantadditionalrevenuecanberaisedinmanydevelopingcountriesbyestablished
methods,adaptedinemphasisandsequencingtocountries'circumstances. Thereare
importantcommonalitiesinreform strategies recommendedbythe Fundandothers—andinthe
challengesandopportunitiesthatremain:
 Building administrations that effectively limit incentives and opportunities for rent-
seeking and inappropriate behavior, and are capable of implementingthe voluntary
compliance neededto extend the tax base, includingby risk management (allocating
resourceswherethe risks to revenue are greatest) andtaxpayer segmentation(tailoring
interventionand services to the distinct challenges posed by different groups, starting
with a large taxpayer office)—here much remains to be done,but positive results have
beenseen;
 Adopting and making readily available clear laws and regulations embodying strong
taxpayer protection—the main problem is often implementation;
1The paper doesnot address thetaxationof natural resources: Appendix VIIprovides anoverviewof issues and
advice,whicharetreatedat lengthinarecent Fund book(Daniel, Keen, and McPherson, 2010).
5
 Eliminating exemptions that forego revenue to little useful end—these are often still
substantial and can amount to several points of GDP;
 Implementing a broad-based VAT with a fairly high threshold (the turnover level at
which registration for the tax becomes compulsory)—in lower-income countries where
VAT performance is weakest, base-broadening and improved compliance might raise
somethingin the order ofan additional 2 percent of GDP;
 Establishing a broad-based corporate income tax, at rates competitive by international
standards—morehasbeendoneonthelatterthanontheformer,leavingsignsof
significant scope for base-broadening in many lower-income countries;
 Extendingthe PIT base, and ensuringa coherent treatment ofalternative forms ofcapital
income—still a major challenge;
 Levying excises on a few key items that are adequate to revenue needs and wider social
concerns—these too have furtherpotentialinsome countries;
 Implementing simple but coherent regimes for taxing smaller businesses—now receiving
increasedattention;
 Strengtheningreal estate taxes—minimal in manycountries, but with potential to
transform local government finance in the longer-term; and
 Developing capacity for tax expenditure and wider policy analysis—impressive advances
in some countries, but much still to do in others.
Protectionofthepoorest,includingthroughbasicpublicspending,isanoverarching
concern. The fairnessofa taxsystem cannotmeaningfully be assessed inisolationofthe
spendingit finances: a regressive tax may be the onlyway to finance strongly progressive
spending. This makes it important not only to examine the distributional impact of tax reforms
themselves but also to identify specific spendingmeasures to address any concerns they raise.
Better persuading taxpayers ofthe value ofthe public spendingfinancedby the taxes they pay,
including by improvingthe management and quality ofthat spending, can further bolster trust in
andcompliancewiththetaxsystem.
Thereareemergingconcernsandissuesrequiringgreaterattention. Challengesin
international taxation and from regional integration are intensifying, and call for closer
cooperation on tax matters—including with advanced economies—in both policy and
administration, as well as further support for capacity building. Continued trade liberalization
willput pressure onrevenueinmanylower-incomecountries.Scopeto meetthese andother
revenue needs by simply raising standard VAT rates is becoming limited, so the potential lies
largely in better improving compliance and scaling back preferential treatments. Not least, and
important too for the wider legitimacy of tax systems, greater efforts can be made—requiring
political will as much as technical capacity—in taxing elites and high-income/wealth individuals.
6
I. INTRODUCTION
1. Strengtheningrevenuemobilizationindevelopingcountrieshaslongbeenacentral
concernoftheFund,anditsadvicehasbeenhighlyinfluential. Initsprogram,surveillance
and—the main perspective here—technical assistance (TA) work, the Fund has for manyyears
supported developingcountries' efforts tobuildmore effective andfairertax systems. Though
far from the only provider, the Fund has come to occupya leading role in advising ontax matters
in these countries (Appendix I). Its advice has been keenly felt by Fund members, closely
watched by academics and CSOs, and sometimes controversial.
2. Interestinenhancingrevenuemobilizationindevelopingcountriesisincreasing.Most
developing countries are emerging from the crisis with their fiscal prospects broadly intact (IMF,
2010a), but with many still facinga fundamental needto raise more revenue from their owntax
bases. Achieving the Millennium Development Goals, for instance, has been suggested to require
increasing domestic revenues in low-income countries (LICs) by around 4 percent of GDP
(United Nations, 2005). Infrastructure needs are also extensive (IMF, 2010a), and there are
climate challenges to address. Advanced economies are increasingly focused on improving their
support of these revenue mobilization efforts. In this context the G-20 leaders called in
November 2010 for the Fund, with others, to report onkey issues instrengthening revenue
mobilization.2
3. Thispaperreviewsexperienceinstrengtheningtaxsystemsindevelopingcountries—
focusingparticularlyonlower-incomecountries.3 Itdrawslessons,forbothpolicyand
administration, from analytical and TA work,4 discusses core elements of Fund advice, and
assesses prospects for strengtheningrevenue mobilization in the face ofemerging challenges.5
II. AIMS, TRENDS, AND POSSIBILITIES
4. Thissectionaddressesoverarchingissues:theobjectivesofrevenuemobilization,
similarities and differences in the challenges faced by developing countries (and the implications
2Othersigns ofstrongdonorinterestincludethecreationoftwotrustfunds tosupport theFund's taxTA,the
emphasis ontheissue bytheEuropeanCommission (2010), thecreationbytheDevelopment Assistance Committee
of a Task Force onTax and Development, and of the DfID/NORAD-sponsored International Centre for Tax and
Development.
3Meaning, broadly speaking, low- and lower middle-income countries (in the World Bank classification, per capita
incomebelow$995andbetween$996-3,945);forperspective,indicatorsforuppermiddle-income($3,946-12,195)
andadvancedcountriesarealsosometimesreportedbelow.
4Several recent surveys bear on these issues: African Development Bank and OECD (2010), Bird (2008), ECORYS
(2010; preparedfor theDutchMinistryofFinance), Gordon(2010), Keenand Simone (2004), and Chambas (2005),
and Keenand Mansour (2010a, b)onsub-SaharanAfrica.
5This paperwill informtheFund's contributiontotheworkrequestedbytheG-20.
7
forreformstrategies),recenttrends,andthescopetoraisemore.
A.ObjectivesandContext
5. Raisingrevenueisthecoreobjectiveofanytaxsystem,butrevenueisnotthesole
concern. Thespendingneedsofdevelopingcountriesaresubstantial,andbothgreaterand,
ultimately, more sustained than can be metfrom foreign assistance.6 In low-incomecountries
(LICs) the revenue imperative is stark: over 20 still have tax ratios (tax revenue relative to GDP)
under15percent.7 Butthereareotherconsiderations:
 The effects which theory suggests the level and compositionof taxes can have on
efficiencyandlong-rungrowth—viainvestment,humancapitalacquisition,and
innovation—have proved hard to identify robustly. For OECD countries, Arnold (2008)
concludes that property taxes are least damaging for growth, followed by consumption
taxes, the personal income tax (PIT), and the corporate income tax (CIT): this is as theory
suggests, with taxation of capital income having a potentially strong impact on
investment.Butthere has beenmuchless workfordevelopingcountries,andwhat there
is tends to find no significant effect from either the overall level of taxation or the
direct-indirect tax mix (Adams and Bevan, 2005; and Martinez-Vasquez, Vulovic, and
Liu, 2009). Lee and Gordon (2005) find lower CIT rates are associated with faster
growth, including in non-OECD countries, though other tax variables are insignificant.
Evidence that trade liberalization fosters growth (Wacziarg and Welch, 2008) suggests a
potential impact from reduced reliance ontrade tax revenue. Other effects likely operate
through the considerable volatility of tax revenue in many developing countries (there
beingsome evidencethat this depresses public investment:Ebeke andEhrhart, 2010),
stressing the value ofdiversifying revenue sources;
 Distributionaleffects areimportantinthemselves(povertyreliefisamajormotivation
for raising revenue in the first place) and for their impact on compliance (likely damaged
if taxpayers perceive others, including all-too-often some elite, as paying too little). Two
points are critical in assessing these effects. First, what ultimately matters is not the
impact of any tax instrument in isolation, but the combined impact of all such
measures—and ofthe spendingthey finance. A regressive tax may be the onlyway to
finance strongly progressive public expenditure; conversely, where the ability to target
spending is relatively weak, progressivity on the tax side is a greater concern. Second,
those whobearthe realburdenofanytax maynotbe those responsible forremittingitto
the government. To the extent that capital is internationally mobile, for instance, a small
country cannotaffect the after-tax return required by foreign investors: trying to do so
will simply reduce the income of immobile factors (local labor, most likely). Judging
6Support toadapt toandhelpthemitigationofclimatechange maybeanexception,totheextent thatitisseenas
compensationforpastemissions inadvancedeconomies.
7This commonbutarbitrarybenchmarkappearstodatebacktoKaldor(1963).
8
where the real incidence of taxation falls is difficult in advanced economies, and no
easier inthe different context oflower-incomeeconomies; and
 Taxation is a definingfeature ofstate power, makingits improvement a key aspect of
state-building.Thisconsideration,whichstresses theviewoftaxreformasaninvestment
central to wider institutional development, has been prominent in recent policy
initiatives.8 What remains unclear is what its increased recognition means for tax advice
andpolicy.
B.Similarities,Differences,andStrategiesforReform
6. Developingcountriesfacemanycommontaxchallenges. Mostarequalitativelythe
same as in advancedeconomies—but muchlarger.9 Theyinclude:
 Dealingwithsectors that are 'hard-to-tax'everywhere (small businesses,includingsmall
farmers, professionals, and—in some cases—state-ownedenterprises), but especially
whereadministrativecapacityandcompliancehabitsareweak.'Informality' isextensive
in developingcountries—perhaps 40 percent ofGDP on average, up to 60 percentin
many.10 Butthisisarguablynotinitselftheproblem:11 microtradersmaybe'informal,'
for instance, but are also likely to have income and sales well below any reasonable tax
threshold; and much of the most egregious evasion is by qualified professionals. The
issueisbestframedasoneof non-compliance. Estimatesofnon-compliancearescarce,
butValue-AddedTax(VAT)'gaps'12 havebeenputat50-60percentinIndonesiaand
Mozambique, for instance, compared to 13 percent in the United Kingdom;
 Weakrevenueadministrations, lowtaxpayermorale,andpoorgovernance—closely
linked—though not unique to lower-incomecountries, are especially entrenchedthere.
Corruption indicators are strongly associated with low revenue (Attila, Chambas, and
Combes, 2008)—indeed corruption functions like a tax itself, and likely a particularly
regressive one—as are other governance indicators (weak rule of law, political
instability). Causation can run both ways, and governance problems are notunique to
revenue administrations and nor can they be fully addressed in isolation from, for
8See for instance OECD (2008) and Everest-Philips (2008).
9Gordonand Li(2009), Heady(2002), and Keenand Simone (2004) discussthe distinct tax-relevant features of
developingcountries.
10SeeSchneider,Buehn,andMontenegro(2010).
11Thetermisusedlooselyhere,andindeed—one reasontopreferthefocusonnon-compliancesuggestedhere—is
rarelywell-defined (Kanbur, 2009); Keen(2011)elaborates.
12VAT revenue with full compliance less actual VAT revenue, relative to the former; the figures are from Silvani et
al.(2008)andCastroetal.(2009).
9
example, judicial reform. Nevertheless, the centrality of tax collection as an exercise of
state power gives governance issues in tax collection a particular importance;
 Heavyrelianceonreceiptsfrom multinationalenterprises,whoseadroitnessintax
planning poses increasing challenges, and, in many cases, difficulties in dealing with
state-ownedenterprises thathavebeenknowntoabuseorsimplyignorethetaxsystem;
 Shallowuseoffinancialinstitutions,avaluablesourceoftax-relevantinformation;
 Pressuresonrevenuefrom tradeliberalization,including regionalintegration, andfrom
intensifyinginternational taxcompetition;and
 Dealingwith internationalservices,increasinglyimportantbut—sincetheycannotbe
intercepted at the border—hard to tax, especially where administrations fail to progress
beyond heavy reliance on physical controls.
7. Buttherearealsosignificantdifferencesamongdevelopingcountries.Probablythe
most important is in natural resource wealth. Geography also matters. Small islands are better
able to impose taxes at the border than are landlocked countries; this may explain both why they
have been less inclined to adopt a VAT13 and why, when adopted, it tends to perform well.14
Post-conflict countries, with shattered administrations and tax bases, face particular difficulties,
as do successor states eager to establish investor-friendly reputations (AppendixII provides case
studies). History also has a role: constitutional restrictions dating to the 1935 Government of India Act
still powerfully constrain VAT design in both India and Pakistan, for instance, and
there is evidence that differing legal traditions, reflecting colonial pasts, are associated with
differentrevenueperformance.
8. Fundadvicereflectsboththesesimilaritiesandthedifferences.Acommoncriticismis
thatFundtax adviceis'onesizefitsall.'15 Sometaxpracticesareindeedclosetouniversally
appropriate: establishingfirm control of the largest taxpayers, for instance. Beyond that there are
certainly commonalities in broad strategies for reform (Box 1), reflecting the generality of
underlying economic and organizational principles. But the timing, relative importance, and
precise design of appropriate tax reform measures varies substantially. Advice has repeatedly
stressed, for instance, the need for substantial administrative reform in advance of VAT
adoption. Sometimes addressing severe non-compliance is an overwhelming priority, leading to
a focus on strengtheningenforcement actions before movingto medium-term reforms. And
countries' idiosyncrasies affect the substance ofadvice. Substantial re-exportingin The Gambia,
for instance, gave pause before recommending a VAT (given the difficulties of exporter
13Keenand Lockwood (2010).
14Chapter 4of Ebrill et al. (2001), and Aizenman and Jinjarak (2008).
15As forinstance inStewart and Jogarajan(2004) and Marshall (2009).
10
refunding, discussed below); and constitutional constraints have affected the design and
implementation of effective VATs. Political and social views on the proper degree of
progressivity vary widely, the traditional role of the external advisor then being to describe and
assessalternatives.
Box1.CommonElementsofStrategiesforReform
Fund advice to developing countries has commonlystressed:
 Establishing effective revenue administrations16 making proper use of withholding
and third-party information, and capable of building on these to implement voluntary
compliance and self-assessment—taxpayers calculatingand remittingtax themselves,
subjectto auditandpenalties—bothas aprerequisite forexpandingthe tax base and
tohelpaddresscorruption.
 Assuring strong control of the largest taxpayers, in a dedicated office (and with
specialized units for the most critical sectors), as a key step towards introducing risk
assessmentandfullertaxpayer segmentation.
 Implementing policies and procedures that limit opportunities for rent seeking and
help identify and punish inappropriate behavior in the revenue administration.
 Designing and applying forceful and efficient strategies to deal with non-compliance.
 Ensuring that laws and regulations are reasonably simple, readily available, coherent
across taxes, and provide good taxpayer protection (including effective appeals
procedures).
 Replacinginefficientproduction or sales taxes, after adequate preparation ofboth the
administration and taxpayers, by a simple VAT—including to catalyze administrative
reforms.
 Levying a VAT on a broad base, with a high threshold (the level of turnover at which
registering for the tax becomes compulsory) and avoiding multiple rates, to realize its
potential as a reasonably efficientsource ofgovernmentfinance.
 Coordinating any prospective loss of trade tax revenue with measures to replace it
fromdomesticsources.
 Avoiding exemptions—under all taxes—that jeopardize revenue and good
governance, are hard to reverse, and generate no clearly offsetting social benefit.
 Removing minor taxes and fees that are inordinately costly to comply with and
administer.
 Building CITs that are simple (in their depreciation and carry forward provisions, for
instance) and sufficiently broad-based to allow statutory rates competitive by
international standards, with effective tax rates that are reasonably low and uniform
acrossinvestments.
16Thetermencompasses bothdomestictaxandcustoms administration.
11
Box1.CommonElementsofStrategiesforReform(continued)
 Strengthening capacity to deal with profit-shifting by multinationals, while
recognizing the extreme difficulty of doing so.
 Extending the coverage of the PIT (particularly through inclusion of smaller
businesses and professionals) and establishing coherent taxation ofcapital income,
withan effective rate structure consistentwiththe authorities' distributional
preferences.
 Exploiting the potential for regional cooperation, in both policy and administration—
particularly on business taxation and excises—to limit mutually damaging
competition.
 Balancing royalties, auctioning and profit-related charges in taxing natural resources.
9. Fund-supportedprogramsaremakingincreasinguseofstructuralrevenuemeasures
aspartofgovernment-ownedstrategiestoincreaseeconomicgrowthandreducepoverty
(Figure 1). These are often informed by TA advice, and might involve, for instance, the
introduction of an LTO or removal of exemptions. There is evidence that IMF-supported
programs can improve tax performance by inducing reforms requiring strong political
commitment(Brunetal.,2010).
Figure 1. Revenue-Related and Other Structural Benchmarks, 2002-10
250
200
150
100
50
0
200
2-03
Structural
Benchmarks1
Total Fiscal
Revenue
2
0
0
7
-
0
8
2009-10
Sourc
e:
MON
A
datab
ase.
1Structural benchmarks can be legal, institutional or
policy measures that are
relevant for a program's macroeconomic objectives.
e.g., Introduction of Tax
Identification Number, Increase of VAT Threshold, Establishment
of a Large Taxpayer
Unit,
Reduction/elimination of
tax exemption.
12
C.TrendsandRecentExperience17
10. Revenuesinlower-incomecountries(especiallyLICs)showedresiliencethroughthe
crisis. Figure 218 showsdevelopments since1980inthree measures ofgovernmentrevenue:
total, excludinggrants from abroad, and—the focus in the bulk ofthis paper—tax revenue
(including social security contributions). The narratives naturally differ, but the buoyancy of
revenues in LICs in particular is apparent.
Figure 2. Trends in Total and Tax Revenue, 1980-2009
(In percent of GDP)
Government Revenue
45.0
40.0
35.0
30.0
25.0
20.0
15.0
10.0
5.0
0.0
1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008
Government Revenue, Excluding Grants
45.0
40.0
35.0
30.0
25.0
20.0
15.0
10.0
5.0
0.0
1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008
17The analysis in this paper draws ona mix of GFS, WEO and other data, from 1980on—an eclecticism that
reflects limitations of available revenue data for developing countries. Appendix III provides detail.
18Figuresshowmedians(ratherthanmeans)tolimittheimpactofoutliersanddatagaps.'Dynamic'incomegroups
areconstructedbyranking countries byincome per capitaat eachdate,and dividing themintofour equal-sized
groups: this avoids biases fromclassifying countries by income at any single date (using final income per capita, for
instance, could exclude strong revenue performers that migrate tothe LMIC group, giving an unduly pessimistic
viewof LICs as a group). Averages and/or categorizing groups bytheir final incomes, however, gives broadly the
same conclusions as follow.
13
Tax Revenue
40.0
35.0
30.0
25.0
20.0
15.0
10.0
5.0
0.0
1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008
Low in come Lo wer mid dle income Up per middlein come High income
Source: IMF staff estimates.
Note: Group medians and dynamic income groups.
11. Revenuesfromnaturalresourcesplayedanimportantroleintherelativelystrong
performanceofrecentyears,butwerenottheonlyfactor. Dataonresource-relatedreceipts
are poor, but they loom very large in the fiscal situations of many countries (Figure 3). Keen and
Mansour (2010) find that, within sub-Saharan Africa, revenue has performed more strongly in
resource-rich countries. Figure 4, however—comparing experiences in resource-rich and other
countries more widely—shows not only the massively greater volatility of receipts in the former
but also that tax ratioshave increasedoverrecentyears innon-resourcecountriestoo.
Figure 3. Receipts from Natural Resources, averages 2000-07
(selected countries, percent of government revenues)
Petroleum Minerals
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
Source: IMF staff calculations.
Jordan
Sierra
Leone
South
Africa
Peru
Namibia
Liberia
Mongolia
Gabon
Colombia
Mauritania
Chile
Guinea
Papua
New
Guinea
Russia
Bolivia
Ecuador
Norway
Indonesia
Cameroon
Chad
Kazakhstan
Vietnam
Mexico
São
Tomé
&…
Trinidad
and
Tobago
Syrian
Arab…
Botswana
Turkmenistan
Venezuela
Sudan
Azerbaijan
Iran
Qatar
United
Arab…
Timor-Leste
Algeria
Yemen
Saudi
Arabia
Congo,
Republic
of
Bahrain
Angola
Liby
a
Equatorial
Guinea
Nigeria
Kuwait
Oman
Iraq
3
5.
0
3
0.
0
2
5.
0
2
0.
0
1
5.
0
1
0.
0
5
.
0
0
.
0
1
4
Figure 4. Tax Revenue Developments in Resource-Rich
and Other
Countries,19
80-2009
(In
percent
of
GDP)
Non
-
Res
ourc
e
Cou
ntri
es
Resource
Rich
Countries
4
0
.
0
3
5
.
0
3
0
.
0
2
5
.
0
2
0
.
0
1
5
.
0
1
0
.
0
5
.
0
0.0
Source:
IMF staff
estimates
.
Note: Group medians and dynamic income groups; 'resource-rich' countries at each date are those
with resource rents over
1
0
p
e
r
c
e
n
t
o
f
G
D
P
.
12. Therehasbeensomeincreaseinlower-incomecountries'taxrevenuessince
the
mid-1990s. Regional experiences differ (Box 2) but, followingstagnation or
even decline,
Figure 2 shows an increase in median performance. Comparing (LICs and
LMICs) in 1990-95
and2003-08,Figure 6shows, morebroadly, amarkedincrease intaxratios.Over
this period,
five or so countries raised their tax ratios to above
15 percent.
13. Thesedevelopmentsintaxperformancereflectincreasedrevenuefromthe
VAT,
strongperformanceoftheCITanddecliningtradetaxrevenues (Figure7)—trends
apparent
sincethe
early
1980s.
15
Box2.TheRegionalPerspective
While the focus in this paper is on lower-incomecountries as a group, experiences have
differed across regions. While sample size becomes more of a concern at finer disaggregation,
Figure 5suggests, forinstance,that tax revenue performancehas strengthenedinsub-Saharan
Africasincethe mid-1990'sbut weakenedindevelopingAsia.
Figure 5. Tax Revenue Developments by Region, 1980-2009
Source: IMF staff calculations.
Note: Group medians and (to ensure that the sample for one region is not affected by changes in the income
classification of countries in other regions) fixed income groups.
Figure 6. Distribution of the Tax Ratio in Developing Countries,
1990-95and2003-08
30
20
10
0
0 10 20 30 40 50
Tax revenue in percent of GDP
Tax 1990-95 Tax 2003-08
Source: IMF staff calculations.
Note: Sample composed of low - and lower middle-income countries, using dynamic income groups.
Proportion
of
countries
(percent)
16
Figure 7. Trends in the Composition of Revenues, 1980-2009
(In percent of GDP)
VAT revenues have increased... ...and CIT receipts have been robust.
8 3.5
7
3.0
6
2.5
5
4 2.0
1980-1989 1980-1989
3 1.5
1990-1999 1990-1999
2 1.0
2000-2009
1 0.5 2000-2009
0 0.0
L
o
w
inc
o
m
e
Lo
wer
mid
dle
inco
me
Upp
er
mid
dle
inco
me
H
i
g
h
i
n
c
o
m
e
L
o
w
i
n
c
o
m
e
Lo
wer
midd
le
inco
me
Upp
er
midd
le
inco
me
High
income
The PIT is modest and flat... ... and trade
tax receipts are in decline.
12
6
10
5
8
4
6 1980-1989 3
1980-1989
4 1990-1999 2
1990-1999
2 2000-2009 1
2000-2009
0
0
Low Lower Upper High Low
Lower Upper High
income middle middle income income
middle middle income
income income
income
income
Source: IMF
staff
calculations.
Note: Group medians and
dynamic income groups.
D.AssessingtheScopetoRaise
MoreRevenue
Percent
GDP
Percent
GDP
Percent
GDP
Percent
GDP
14. Econometricworkhaslinkedrevenueperformance—theratioofactual
revenuesto
GDP—witharangeofstructural,developmentalandinstitutionalfeatures
(AppendixIV).
Many (such as the agricultural share, past political instability) are largely
exogenous to tax
decisions, especially in the very short-term. The impact ofresource wealth and aid
on revenue
performance inthis context has attracted particular
attention (Box 3).
Box3.Aid,ResourceWealth,andRevenue
Mobilization
Theempiricalevidenceonwhethersomekindsofaidmightdisplaceown
revenuesis
mixed. Over2001-06,aidinrecipientcountriesaveraged around4.4percentof
GDP; in25
countries it exceeded half of all tax revenue. Such receipts could displace
domestic revenue-
raising by reducingimmediate needs and creatinga disincentive to strengthen
performance for
fear of offsetting reductions in future assistance. In practice, empirical findings vary.
Gupta et al.
(2004), for instance, find that grants displace domestic revenue (almost fully where
corruption is
high) while loans are associated with stronger domestic revenues. Reviewingthe
evidence more
widely, however, Moss, Petterson, and van de Walle (2006) stress the
diversity of country
experiences and empirical results. Better understandingof these links between foreign
assistance
and domestic revenues would help ensure that aid is provided in forms most
supportive of
developingcountries'owntax
reformefforts.
17
Box3.Aid,ResourceWealth,andRevenueMobilization(continued)
Therearestrongsignsthatoilrevenuesdisplaceowntaxation,andsomethatnon-oil
resourcerevenuesdotoo. Bornhorstetal.(2009)findthatanincreaseinhydrocarbonrevenues
of $1 displaces about 20 cents of non-hydrocarbon tax revenue. Results for sub-Saharan Africa19
suggest a similar effect for all forms of resource wealth.
15. Empiricalestimatessuggestthat'effort'—theratioofactualrevenuesto
potential20—isnotlowinalldevelopingcountries,butthatsignificantadditionalrevenue
couldberaisedwhereperformanceisweakest.AppendixVdescribesthemethodologyand reports—as
illustrative of broad implications, not prescriptions—country-specific estimates of
'effort'(basedonPessinoandFenochietto,2010).Onaverage,effortisnolowerinLICs.21
Those with the lowest tax ratios, however, also tend to be those with the lowest effort. Of the 15
LICs and middle-income countries (LMICs) in the sample with tax ratios below 15 percent, for
instance, 13 have estimated effort below their group median; raisingit to that level would
increase their revenue by an average of about 3percent ofGDP. This leaves open,ofcourse,
precisely how this can be done. Though details must be highly country-specific, the analysis in
the next section gives a sense ofwhere the possibilities may lie.
16. Severalcountrieshaveshownthefeasibilityofsubstantiallyincreasingdomestic
revenue mobilization.While some (suchas Egypt, Pakistan)show little movementintaxratios
over extendedperiods,others have made impressive progress. Peru, forinstance,increasedits
tax ratio from 6to 13percentoverthe 1990sandto around17percentnow.Somehave achieved
sustained revenue increases of4-5 percent ofGDP overjust a few years. Appendix VI details
three cases ofsubstantial progress: El Salvador, Tanzania, and Vietnam.
III. ISSUES AND LESSONS
17. Thissectionconsiderscentralissuesofprincipleandlessonsofexperienceinnon-
resourcetaxation.Taxingnaturalresourcesraisesmoredistinctandcomplexchallengesthan
can adequately be addressed here: Appendix VII provides an overview.22
19Notreportedhere;usingthedatasetofKeenandMansour(2010).
20Theterms'performance'and'effort'areoftenusedsynonymously,butthedistinctionmadehere,duetoLotzand
Morss(1967),provesuseful.
21Gupta(2007) reaches asimilar conclusion.
22Afuller treatment is in Daniel, Keen and McPherson (2010).
18
18. Itisexpositionallyconvenienttofocusinturnondistinctaspectsoftaxdesign—Box
4distillskeylessons—butaholisticperspectiveisalsoneeded.Fundamentalissuesof
administrative reform overarch all (and so are dealt with first); more specific administrative
challenges are discussed inrelation to the particular instruments then considered. Andthere are
important design links between those policyinstruments. Perhaps most fundamentally, one
theme underlying much ofthe followingdiscussion is that pressures on revenue from trade
liberalization,regional integration and tax competition mean that, absent greater international
coordination, the search for additional revenue will likely focus on relatively immobile bases—
most obviously labor,consumption,andreal estate.
Box4.KeyChallengesforTaxReform
Prioritiesvarywithcountrycircumstances,butseverallessonsemerge. Relativetokey
elements of the reform strategies setoutinBox1,inmanycases:
 Progress has been made in administrative reforms, but more onbasic organizational
structures than indevelopingandapplyingrisk-management,andgovernanceproblems
remainextensive;
 The VAT still has more obvious revenue potential than most other instruments, but
realizing this requires expanding the base—by both policy change and improving
compliance—ratherthanincreasingstandardrates;
 More systematic attention needs to be given to replacing revenue lost from trade
liberalization;
 Incentives, including in free trade zones, continue to undermine revenue from CIT, which
is any event likely to come under continued pressure from globalization in coming years;
 Profit-shifting by multinationals is an increasing concern; strengthening capacity and
legislative frameworks is important, but, absent fundamental changes in international tax
policies,there are noeasysolutions;
 The PIT will likely remain poorly developed for some time, but movement to explicitly,
and coherent,schedular structures can improve effectiveness andfairness;
 High-income individuals can be taxed more effectively by removing opportunities for
avoidanceandstrengtheningdetectionandenforcement;
 Establishing streamlined tax regimes for small businesses, and extending to them the
methods of taxpayer segmentation, is unlikely to yield significant short-term revenue
gains but is important for the longer-term development and perceived legitimacy ofthe
taxsystem;
 Muchremainsto be doneto make taxexpenditure analysis routine;
 Capacity in tax policy analysis is often very weak, and a significant hindrance to better
designandownership;
19
Box4.KeyChallengesforTaxReform(continued)


1
9.
Greater transparency and consultation on tax matters—not least,
improvingthe
effectiveness and visibility of public spending it finances—can promote
the trust on
which voluntary tax
compliance rests; and
Sustained political commitment from the highest level is essential for deep
reform, which
needs then to be entrenched to prevent
backsliding.
A. Core
Administration
Reforms23
Improving revenue administration is essential for enhanced and fairer
revenue
mobilizationandforwidergovernanceimprovement;thoughsuccessishardto
evaluate. It
maybetoomuchtoassertthat"indevelopingcountries,taxadministration is
taxpolicy"
(Casanegra de Jantscher, 1990): tax policysets the framework within which
the revenue
administration must operate. In practice, the distinction between administration
and policy is
oftenhard(andpointless) to make.Butthere isnodoubtthat weakandoften
corruptrevenue
administration remains a fundamental barrier to effective and fair taxation, and to
building wider
trust between governmentand citizens. Key indicators—tax gaps, audit recovery
rates and the
levelandpattern ofarrears—can saymuchaboutthe performanceoftax
administrations:
developingthe capacity to monitor and analyzing these, indeed,is a central
reform aim.
Evaluating the impact of administrative reforms on revenue itself, however, can
be especially
difficult, since they take time, are complex, and rarely lend themselves to
experiment-type
evaluation.Inthisrespect,assessmentsaretosomedegree
judgmental.
Accomplishments
andtrends
20. Developingcountrieshaveimplementedwiderangingadministration
reforms—
moreearnestlysincetheearly1990s—butwithmixedsuccess. Somehavemade
impressive
advances (Mozambique, Peru, Rwanda, Tanzania, and Vietnam, for instance);
others very little,
reflecting conflict or governance issues (DRC, Haiti, Nicaragua, Sierra
Leone). Sometimes
progress has been followed by stagnation ordecline (Guatemala, Honduras, Zambia),
sometimes
by a resurgence (Bolivia, Ghana, Uganda). There is no single formula for
assuring major
administrative improvement, but experience points to some
key elements.
21. Manymajororganizationalchangeshaveprovedconstructive,thoughthere
have
alsobeen mistakes. Keyimprovements include movingaway fromduplicative
andnarrowly
focused tax-by-tax approaches by implementingfunction-based organizational
structures,
establishing headquarters organizations to guide them, and integratingdomestic
direct and
indirect tax management. Less successful—because less appropriate given their
different tasks—
23Detailedregional assessments are in Crandall and Bodin(2005), Kloeden (forthcoming), and Zake
(forthcoming).
20
havebeenattemptstomergeoperational(asopposedtomanagerial)taxandcustoms
administrationprocesses (Zimbabwe).
22. Revenueauthorities(RAs)havenotalwaysliveduptothehighexpectationsheldby
some,but,withpoliticalwill,canprovideaframeworkforsustainedprogress. Thecreation
ofRAs has beenawidely-notedinnovationoverthe last 10-15years (theyare nowalmost
ubiquitous, for instance, in Anglophone Africa), and the Fund has supported countries that have
chosen this path. RAs differ greatly, the essential beinga semi-autonomous status intendedto
protect against political interference,give independencein operations and HR management, and
enable flexibility in budgeting and operations. The high hopes sometimes expressed have not,
however, been fully realized (Kidd and Crandall, 2006; Kloeden, forthcoming). The (mostly
anecdotal) evidenceis that managerial and staff capacity and practice often have improved
(many examples in Latin America, Eastern and Southern Africa, Ghana, and The Gambia). But
the disruption of instituting an RA often delayed reforming core tax administration functions: the
integration of direct and indirect tax administration is only now getting underway in Anglophone
Africa, for instance. And even substantial increases leave salaries dwarfed by the potential gain
from corruption. As RAs now spread further, including with heightened interest in Francophone
Africa, it is important to recognize that the aim of reform is to improve core administration
functions, not just the vehicle for their delivery.
23. Segmentingthetaxpayerpopulationhasenabledabetterallocationof
administrativeresourcesandfacilitatedrisk-managementapproachestocompliance.
Large, medium, small, and micro taxpayers offer very different revenue possibilities and
compliance concerns. As noted above, the needfor focused attention on large taxpayers is now
nearly universally accepted: given the highly skewed size distribution of firms, controlling the
largestenterprises(usuallyafewhundredorthousand),cansecure60-80percentofdomestic
taxes (more, in island economies). Securing prompt and appropriate tax payment from resource
companies, financial institutions and telecom operators is a prerequisite for effective revenue-
raising. While Africa trailed earlier adopters in Latin America (Argentina, Peru, and Uruguay),
and the absence ofintegrated administration rendered some early efforts ineffective (Egypt,
Kenya, and Uganda), an LTO is now the norm [though gaps remains, as in SACU (except South
Africa)]. LTOs have accomplished much (Baer, 2002) and can likely do more: in resource
taxation, for instance (as is beginning in Ghana, Uganda, and Mongolia), and by developing
specialist units to deal with high wealth individuals. Their very effectiveness, however, can
create difficulty: the ease of collecting from large firms may lead governments to disadvantage
smaller companies (Auriol and Warlters, 2005), and the focus can distort competition and be
perceived as unfair (factors contributing to the disbandmentof Uganda's first LTO). The natural
next step is to deliver similarly high-quality services and compliance enforcement to non-large
taxpayers, with medium taxpayer offices emerging (in Indonesia and Francophone Africa) and
some innovative small taxpayer approaches (Tanzania, and small taxpayer offices in Algeria and
some Francophone African countries).
24. Improvedbusinessprocesses,builtoneffectiveITsystems,arecritical,butfailures
havebeentoocommon. Betterprocessescanreducecompliancecostsandfacilitateself-
21
assessment by simplifying taxpayer registration, filing and payment, audit, collection
enforcement,andappeals. Automationofroutinetasks, and,sincethe mid-2000s, the emergence
of linkages between tax and customs IT applications, have also increased effectiveness. Less
progress has beenmadeinrelationtoexpost controls(audit,enforcement,appeals). IT systems
in developingcountries(whetherhome-grown orpackages) are often inadequate,withmany
disappointing examples and far fewer moderately successful ones (as in Colombia, Peru,
Rwanda, Tanzania). Poorresults can arise from inadequate linkages with a broader reform
strategy (perhaps being designed with only an isolated objective—administering the VAT, for
instance—in mind, or with insufficient attention to restructuring basic processes), or conversely,
from excessive ambition. High failure rates and costs in going alone on computerization could be
mitigated through regional cooperation: the possibilities of this are emerging in East Africa, and
through customs harmonization efforts in Central America.
25. Simplifyingtaxlawsandadoptingtaxprocedurecodes(TPCs)caneaseboth
administrationand compliance.Harmonizingacross taxes andsimplifyingkeyadministrative
provisions facilitates administration and compliance. TPCs are not always effective, whether
because ofan absenceofaccompanyingmeasures(Paraguay) orhesitationto impose the strictest
penalties. Wheretheyare,however,theyhave strengthenedadministrative powersof
investigation and arrears collection, while protecting taxpayer rights.
Challengesahead
26. Compliancecostsremainhighinmanydevelopingcountries.Forthetypicalfirmof
the Doing Business exercise, time spent preparing and paying taxes exceeds 300 hours in
developing countries, compared to under 210 for high-income countries. In the East African
corridor Mombasa-Kigali, customs' handlingcosts per import containerby road are $0.13 per
km, compared to $0.05 per km along the Danang-Tak corridor in Asia (CPCS Transcom, 2010).
27. Revenueadministrationsoftensufferfromunder-resourcing,misallocation,and
weakmid-levelskills.Revenueadministrationsneedassuranceofadequateresourcing,though
rigid and legislatively-mandated financing by a fixed percentage of collections (such as the 3
percentin Ghana) has often failed in its intentionto motivate stronger performance. Such
resources as they have, moreover, needto be carefully deployed, avoidingfads (particularly
technological) and distractions (excessive focus on minor non-tax revenues). Mid-level
managerial and technical skills (though noticeably improved in Latin America) are often weak.
Comprehensive skill studies to identify tax gaps, compliance trends, and needed improvements
are rare, resultingin poor taxpayer services and inadequate orinappropriate interventions
(includingharassment).
28. Coordinationbetweendomestictaxandcustomsadministrationsisgenerallypoor.
Tax and customs administrations—and reforms to each—needto be closely coordinated.
Economic activity straddles both domains, and customs has a critical role in managing VAT on
22
international trade: half or more of gross VAT revenue in developing countries is collected by
customs.24 Coordination,which can enable a more complete view ofeach taxpayer, is often
weak: information on VAT collected on imports and zero-rated exports needs to flow from
customs to tax administration for automatic cross-checking against VAT returns to identify
anomalies and high-risk cases for audit consideration.Transactional customs and tax data
provides opportunities for trend analysis by customs and tax managers to collaboratively and
jointly (particularly within the framework of RA) develop compliance models and response
strategies. All too often these opportunities remain underexploited.
29. Addressingtheseconcerns,andstrengtheningthelegitimacyofthetaxsystem,
requiresimprovingcompliancemanagement—dealingwiththe"hard-to-tax"—inparallel
withconsolidatinggoodtaxadministrationfundamentals. Beyondthefundamentals—
functionally structured organizations, taxpayer focus, self-assessment, simple IT-supported
processes, ethicalandcompetentmanagers andstaff—is the needforclearstrategies to address
the most non-compliant businesses and individuals. Keyelements include: understanding the
nature of the taxpayer/trader population; identifying key compliance risks and how they arise
(from weak laws and regulations, for instance, or administrative incapacity?); clarity on
accountability for, and adequate resourcing of, compliance activities; and specifying
performance indicators and potential corrective actions.
30. Addressingnon-complianceultimatelyrequiresthehardworkofroutine
administration. Shortcuts often prove illusory. Amnesty schemes offeringwaiver oftax, interest
andpenalties,oftenwith'noquestionsasked,'canunderminecompliancebycreating
expectations of more to come and doing a keenly-felt injustice to the compliant (Baer and Le
Borgne, 2008). Limited voluntary disclosure programs, on the other hand, intended to achieve
enduring tax compliance by partial waiver of penalties accompanied by strong enforcement
action, can prove helpful. Other schemes that have proved problematic include requiring tax
certificates for access to contract or bank accounts, which can simply invite forgery; and lottery
schemes rewarding those holding VAT invoices, or allowing deduction against PIT of some
itemsbackedbyinvoice(intendedtoensure that these are issued),whichcanresult intax
administrations being presented with bags of invoices to sift through and verify. Some simple
measures canhelp:requiringlarge payments to go through bankingsystem, forinstance,can
provide useful information. But what is key is a program of routine but targeted and thoughtful
intervention:Russell (2010), for instance, sets out a range of practical measures to address non-
compliance by small businesses. Registration programs (increasing unannounced visits to
market) and follow-upofstopfilingare criticaltofinding'ghosts'—those (apparently) unknown
to the tax administration—while education and welcoming taxpayer services, together with wider
intelligence operations, are crucial for all aspects of compliance.
24Table 4.3 of Ebrill et al. (2001).
23
31. Progresscanbemadeinaddressingcorruption.Itrequiresstrongleadership(political
and managerial), institutional measures—strong and proactive internal audit and staff
investigation functions, visible implementation of a code of ethics (including prosecutions)—and
processes that limit rent-seekingopportunities (minimizingcontact between taxpayers and tax
officials). The Uganda Revenue Authority is an example of how (by, for instance, forceful
measures to purge staff and re-hire, with zero tolerance forcorruption)a once poorly-perceived
institution is now cited as a model.
32. Successfuladministrativereformrequiressustainedpoliticalwillasmuchas
technicalcapacity.Asoundreformstrategy,technicalunderstandingandadequatehuman
resources are essential, of course, but so too is political commitment—from the highest levels
and over substantial periods oftime—to overcomeresistance (not least from the revenue
administration itself), ensure effective application of the laws, assure funding, and drive through
complementary legal and tax policy changes. Where this has been present (in Peru, Ecuador,
Guatemala, and Rwanda, for instance), progress can be substantial; where it is not, it will be
minimal. A holistic approach is also needed: partial approaches often disappoint, as the potential
revenue gain from investments in administrative improvementcan be offset by base-narrowing
exemptions(asperhapsinUganda).
B. The Value-Added Tax (VAT)
33. MostdevelopingcountrieshavenowdevelopedaVAT. Sincetheearly1990s,the
VAT has spread rapidly beyond advanced economies (Figure 8). Though not ubiquitous, it has
becomethe normandcontinuesto spread(The GambiaandSyria,forinstance,plan
introduction, and it is also under consideration in the Gulf Cooperation Council). The Fund has
been active in its promotion,25 and VAT adoption and implementation continue to be a
significant part of its TA.
25The probability of adoption is significantly relatedtoparticipation ina Fund-supported program (Keen and
Lockwood,2010).
24
Figure 8. The Spread of the VAT, 1980-2009
140
120
100
80
60
40
20
0
1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2009
High Income Other Countries
Source: IMF data.
Note: Figure shows the number of countries with a VAT at each date.
34. Fundadvice—largelyfollowed—favorsabroadbase,singlerateandfairlyhigh
threshold.26 These prescriptions (widely shared by others advisingin this area)27 aim to realize
the core potential merits of the VAT: raising significant amounts of revenue in a way that does
less damage to economic activity than alternatives, supports equity objectives, and is relatively
simple to administer and comply with. They do not mean no exemptions:28 some (for financial
serviceschargedforas a margin,governmentagencies,basic health andeducation)are common
to most VATs, often on technical (though increasingly challenged) grounds. Others (for staple
foodstuffs) are driven by political and distributional sensitivities. A relatively high threshold
excludes traders with little revenue potential relative to the administration and compliance costs
involved. IMF (2000) found these prescriptions have been widely followed, except perhaps in
relation to the threshold: a single rate is much more common in LICs, for instance, than in higher
income countries (Table 1),29 though there are signs of pressure: the WAEMU VAT directive, for
example,hasbeenamendedtoallowasecondrate.
26Ebrill et al. (2001).
27Suchas Birdand Gendron(2007). Theory[arecent reviewis byCrawford, Keen, and Smith(2010)], suggeststhat
rate differentiation canplay a useful role ineasing distortions tomarket participationand (especially where better
targetedinstruments areweak) pursuing distributional objectives.Inpractice, however, it ishardtoidentify
desirable forms of differentiation (beyond those handled by excises), while differentiation is costlytoadminister and
comply with,and opens the doortospecial pleading.
28'Exemption'meanssalesarenottaxed,but(unlike'zero-rating')taxoninputsisnotrefunded.Fundadvice
generally resists zero-rating other thanfor exports because of the difficultyof controlling refunds.
29This partly reflects the greater age of VATs inhigher income countries: most new VATs have beensingle rate.
Number
of
countries
25
Table 1. VAT Features by Income Group
Number of
Average VAT C-efficiency
Income Class strictly positive
Rate
VAT rates
Low-Income 16 1.28 38.0
Lower Middle-Income 13 1.94 46.6
Upper Middle-Income 15 1.90 51.6
High-Income 20 2.52 55.6
Source: IMF staff calculations.
Note: Rates as at end -2010; C-efficiency (the ratio of VAT revenue to the product of the standard VAT rate
and consumption), discussed below, as at 2005 (for reasons of sample size).
35. TheVAThasestablisheditselfasarobustsourceofrevenue,withsignsthatithas
provedarelativelyefficientinstrument. It typicallyaccountsforaroundone-quarterofalltax
revenue; and no country has ever removed a VAT without subsequently reintroducing it. Keen
and Lockwood (2010) find that countries with a VAT generally raise more revenue than those
without, all else equal, though the likely gain varies with countries' openness and income levels
(being less, for instance, in smaller countries, presumably because tariffs are then an easy
revenuesource,andperhaps lowerinsub-Saharan Africathan elsewhere).
36. Closeanalysescommonlyreachfairlybenignconclusionsonthedistributional
impactoftheVAT,butmorecanbedonetoidentifyspecificspendingmeasurestoallay
concerns. A proportional tax onall consumption is regressive relative to annual income,but this
effect is mitigated by the common exemption of sensitive food and other items and (less noted)
by the operationofthe threshold: the latter eitherconfersacompetitiveadvantage onsmallerand
presumably less well-off retailers and service providers or enables their customers, likely
amongst the poorer,adefacto exemption(Jenkins,Jenkins,andKuo,2006).The reachofthe tax
is also less in poorer rural regions than in urban centers. Reviewing the evidence, Bird and
Gendron (2007) find the VAT to be generally mildly progressive or mildly regressive. Assessing
the distributional impact of any tax requires, however, comparing it with some alternative. One
possibility is that it replaces other revenue sources: Zolt and Bird (2005) conclude "the evidence
is...that the VAT is likely on the whole to be less regressive than the trade and excise taxes it has
replaced. Furthermore, inat least some developingcountries, the VAT may be about as
progressive as the income tax." Alternatively, if the VAT finances increased expenditure then the
final distributional outcome can be progressive even with a broad-based, single rate VAT: the
benefitof preferential rates/exemptionsgoes mainlyto the betteroff(sincetheyspendmoreon
all items), so that the poorcan benefit from their elimination and use of the additional tax
revenue to financetargetedspendingmeasures (Box5). The effectivenessofthe targeting
instruments available is critical, but even the relatively blunt instruments available to developing
countries can achieve much: Munozand Cho (2004), forinstance, using microdata to look at the
combined tax-spending of a VAT in Ethiopia, find basic health spending to have a particularly
strongeffect.Itremainsthecase,nonetheless,thatprecisemeasurestoaddressanyequity
26
concerns from proposed tax reforms—alleviating poverty is of course in itself a primary reason
to impose these taxes—are oftenleft unspecified.
Box5.TheDistributionalImpactofExemptionsandReducedRates
Reduced rates on (or exemption of) items particularly important to the poor are inherently
limited as distributional devices: even if the poor spend a larger proportion of their income
on some item, the better offmay spend absolutely more (Sah, 1983; and Ebrill et al., 2001).
The practical importance of this recurs in TA and other work: Figure 9 shows how the bulk
of the subsidy implicit in domestic zero-rating in Mexico accrues to the better-off.
The question theniswhetherspendinginstruments candoa betterjobofprotectingthe poor.
The Ethiopiacase studysuggests that evenwhere spendinginstruments are quite weak,rate
differentiation can be an inferior policy, and similar results have been found, for instance, for
the Philippines(Newhouse andZakharova,2007).It remainsthe case,however,that the
equity case for rate differentiation is generally stronger in developing countries than in
advanced economies. Whether rate differentiation is desirable in any specific context
dependsonthegovernment'sequityobjectivesandthepreciseinstrumentsavailabletoitfor
protectingthepoor.
Figure 9. Benefits from Zero-Rating Relative to Income Shares, Mexico
(by income decile)
25
20
15
10
5
0
I II III IV V VI VII VIII IX X
Percent of total subsidy Percent of income
Source: OECD 2007.
37. Anytaxencouragesinformality,butaVATmaybelessharmfulthanalternatives.
A higher rate of VAT tends to increase informality, so the rate should be lower where
informality is a greater concern. But other tax instruments, such as an income tax, also spur
informality, and the VAT offers some advantages: if a trader's customers are registered for VAT,
27
it is advantageous forthem to register too.30 But 'bad' VAT chains can also form: ifa trader's
customer are notregistered,betterforthem notto register either(de Paula andScheinkman,
2006). It has also been argued that the VAT may deal with informality less effectively than
tariffs, because unregistered traders will at least pay tariffs on their imports (Emran and Stiglitz,
2005). This though can be overstated: unregistered operators will incur unrecovered input VAT
on imports just as they incur customs duty31 and, unlike tariffs, the VAT also reaches informal
operators on their purchases from compliant domestic firms.32
38. VATintroductioncancatalyzeimprovementsintaxadministration, byusingthe
VAT threshold for taxpayer segmentation (see Section G), introducing self-assessment and
spurring implementation of functionally-organized tax administrations and IT reform.
39. FlaweddesignandimplementationunderminestheeffectivenessoftheVATin
manydevelopingcountries—withrefundsaparticularproblem. Commondifficulties
include: low (sometimes, as in Nigeria, zero) thresholds (pressurizing tax administrations and
diverting attention from higher value and riskier taxpayers); extensive exemptions and zero-
rating (creating classification disputes and increasing compliance costs); inadequate preparations
and public sensitization (making resistance more likely); and piecemeal implementation (as
previously in Yemen, for instance). Refunding exporters requires balancing the risk of fraud
against that of turning the VAT into a de facto export tax. This challenges all tax administrations,
but significant and sometimes corrupt delays in refunding legitimate claims are commonplace in
developing countries, and a major business complaint. Developing effective refunding
procedures is time-consuming and difficult, but crucial: ITD (2005) and Harrison (2008)
elaborateonhowitcanbedone.
40. ThesedifficultiesarereflectedinrelativelylowrevenueproductivityoftheVATin
developingcountries—pointingtopotentiallysignificantrevenuegainsfrombase-
broadening. Standard rates ofVAT rates are already quite high in manydevelopingcountries (Table 1),33
and further increases may pose a particularly heavy risk of worsening compliance.
But that is notthe onlyoptionfor increasing revenue, as emerges from consideringonecommon
measureoftheeffectivenessofaVAT:its'C-efficiency,'theratioofrevenuetotheproductof
the standard rate and consumption.This would take the value of100 under a single rate VAT on
a broad base,but willbelowerto the extentthat reducedrates apply andcomplianceis
30This is because by registering for VAT a trader canrecover taxon their own inputs while their customer receives
acreditforthetaxtheyarethencharged.
31Import VATis not subject toany threshold.
32Keen (2009) reviews the tariffs vs. VAT controversy; Stiglitz (2010) sets out other criticisms of the VAT.
33Insome cases, however, thereisriskof introducing aVATat solowarate—under5percent, say—that it is
questionable whetherthe effort is worthwhile.
28
imperfect.34 In LICs, for instance, median C-efficiency is only about 36 percent (Table 1 above).
In countries where it is less, raisingit to that level—without changing the standard rate, but by
some combination ofbase-broadeningand improvingcompliance—could raise, onaverage,
nearly 2 percent of GDP (Appendix VIII). Indeed a long-term objective, given sufficient base-
broadening and improved compliance, could even be lower standard VAT rates.
41. TheVAT iswork in progress. Adoptionisanatural focusofattention,andrevenue
commonly performs well in its immediate aftermath. But much—more than often realized—
remains to be done thereafter to develop the audit and other capacities an effective VAT
requires: Appendix IX recounts the experience of Zambia, illustrating the need for continued
nurturing of the VAT.
C.TradeLiberalizationandCustomsAdministration
42. Tradetaxrevenues,stillimportanttomanydevelopingcountries,aresettocontinue
todecline. Relative to bothGDP andtotal revenue,trade taxes have beenintrenddeclinefor
thirty years, tracking a decline in collected tariff rates (revenues relative to imports): Figure 10.
Further liberalization (including through regional agreements and bilateral agreements with the
EU and others), some alreadyprogrammedintoagreements inforce,meanthat the trendwill
continue. While the efficiency and growth implications of this are welcome, the fiscal challenges
can be significant: in sub-Saharan Africa, for instance, trade taxes still account for one-quarter of
alltaxrevenue.
Figure 10. Developments in Trade Tax Revenue and Collected Tariff Rates,
1980-2009
Low-Income Countries
45 5
40 4.5
35 4
30 3.5
25
32.5
20 2
15 1.5
10 1
5 0.5
0 0
1980 1984 1988 1992 1996 2000 2004 2008
34Care is needed, however, since some poorVATpractices—suchas afailure torefund exporters, orexemptionof
intermediate products—lead tohigh C-efficiency; Ebrill et al. (2001): discuss these and other limitations of the
concept.
29
Lower Middle-Income Countries
40 6
35 5
30
25 4
20 3
15 2
10
5 1
0 0
1980 1984 1988 1992 1996 2000 2004 2008
Source: IMF staff calculations.
Note: Group medians and dynamic income groups; left hand scale differs between panels.
43. Replacingtradetaxrevenuesfromdomesticsourceshasprovedproblematicin
some LICs. Most middle-income countries have readily recovered revenue from domestic
sources(Figure 11; andBaunsgaard andKeen,2010).The same has notbeentrue ofLICs
throughout the sample period[though sub-Saharan Africa may inthis respect have performed
better than otherregions(KeenandMansour,2010)].The markeddeclineintrade tax revenues
means that slow progress inoverall tax ratios may mask a constructive rebalancing.
Figure 11. Developments in Tax Revenue and Trade Tax Revenue, 1980-2009
Low-Income Countries
16
14
12
10
8
6
4
2
0
1980-1984 1985-1989 1990-1994 1994-1999 2000-2004 2005-2009
Percent
GDP
30
Lower Middle-Income Countries
25
20
15
10
5
0
1980-1984 1985-1989 1990-1994 1994-1999 2000-2004 2005-2009
Upper Middle-Income Countries
25
20
15
10
5
0
1980-1984 1985-1989 1990-1994 1994-1999 2000-2004 2005-2009
Tax Revenue Trade Revenue
Source: IMF staff calculations.
Note: Group averages and fixed income groups.
44. Revenuechallengesfromtradeliberalizationwillcontinue.TherearesignsinFigure
10thatrevenuereplacementhasbeenmorecompletesincethemid-1990s,buttherearealso
intensified challenges ahead. The standard policy prescription for recovery is to combine tariff
reduction with increased consumption taxes (exactly matching tariff reductions on excisable
products, for instance, with higher excises),35 and the analysis above suggests further roomfor
this without an increase in standard VAT rates—already high in many developing countries
(Table 1)—that may pose a particularly heavy risk of worsening compliance. Countries with a
VAT, however, have not been systematically more successful in replacing lost trade tax revenue
(Baunsgaard and Keen,2010), and the case studies in IMF (2005) suggest that successful
replacementhas beenassociatedwithusingarange ofinstruments, includingthe incometax.
While there is thus nosimple recipe for success, failure to quantify and prepare for the revenue
impact of trade reforms has in some cases amplified the difficulties. In Lebanon and
Mozambique, in contrast, introduction of an effective VAT was carefully coordinated with trade
reform.
35This preserves the efficiency gain from the reform, widens the taxbase (by including domestic productionalong
withimports)and canleave consumer prices lower (Keenand Ligthart,2002). Emran and Stiglitz (2005) stress that
informalitycaninvalidatetheargument (becausenot all domesticconsumptioncanthenbetaxed), thoughtheresult
continues to apply if an appropriate withholding taxis applied toimports (Keen, 2008).
Percent
GDP
Percent
GDP
31
45. Institutionalcapacityincustomsadministrationremainsparticularlyweakinmost
lower-incomecountries. Manymiddle-incomecountrieshavebeenpursuingcomprehensive
reform programs that advance the modernization agenda,36 includingby implementing
modernized customs codes aligned with the Kyoto convention;37 replacing universal pre-release
inspection by risk-based, selective post-release audits; adopting HR reforms centered on the
introduction of career systems and codes of ethics for staff; using non-intrusive verification
techniques; implementingsingle-windowsystems fortrade;andimplementingWCO 'SAFE'
guidelines38 (to address security concerns while pursuing trade facilitation). Progress in many
low-income countries, however, has proved much harder, with limited progress, for instance, in
the Kyoto convention.There have been rewardingmultiyear reform strategies supported by
carefully-planned TA (Mozambique, Nepal), but for the most part customs administration reform
results have been disappointing. Limited resources, lack of long-term commitment and overall
limitations in the institutional capacity of the civil service in most LICs are the key challenges.
46. Manycustomsadministrationsstillstruggletocontrolrent-seeking,andregional
integrationcanraisefurtherchallenges. Progressinimplementingintegrity-enhancing
measures (suchas adequate salaries andworkingconditions,managementcontrolsystems,
computer systems to streamline procedures and minimize face-to-face contacts, and accreditation
of customs brokers and importers) remains patchy. Regional integration also poses distinct
problems. Shifting fiscal control from national to regional borders requires new ways to collect
import VAT and certify export-related refund claims, and potentially new policy frameworks to
deal with intra-regional transactions—issues with which the EU is still struggling, and which can
pose even greaterchallengesfordevelopingcountries.
D.PersonalIncomeTaxation
47. ReceiptsfromthePITarelowandstagnantindevelopingcountries,andcome
almostentirelyfromwagewithholdingonlargeenterprisesandpublicsectoremployees.
Since the early 1980s, the PIT has raised 1-3 percent ofGDP indevelopingcountries, compared
to 9-11 percentindeveloped(Peter,ButtrickandDuncan2010).Upto 95percentcomesfrom
wage withholding by the public sector and large firms, compared to about 80 percent in
developed countries. Less than 5 percent of the population pay PIT (compared to nearly 50
percentin developed),andonlyabout15percentofincomeisreached(comparedto 57percent):
Modietal. (1987).
36Described indetail inKeen (2003).
37See http://www.wcoomd.org/home_pfoverviewboxes_tools_and_instruments_pfrevisedkyotoconv.htm
38http://www.wcoomd.org/home_cboverviewboxes_valelearningoncustomsvaluation_epsafeframework.htm
32
48. TopstatutoryratesofPIThavebeencut,andratestructuressimplified,butwithno
discerniblebehavioralimpact. Thesecutsarelikelytohavebeendriven,tosomedegree,by
reductions in CIT rates: absent matchingcuts in top PIT rates, these can invite avoidance by
incorporation. They affect even fewer taxpayers in developing countries than in advanced.39
Thresholds vary widely; raising them could enable a better focus on high-income individuals,
though the revenueloss can be non-trivial.
49. AnemergingconcernisthemandatingofuniversalfilingforallPITtaxpayers to
inculcate greater appreciation of the tax system and in the expectation that additional income will
be declared. In Kenya, for instance, processing the additional returns has significantly increased
workloads but collection and compliance outcomes have disappointed. The impact on taxpayer
awareness may have actually been harmful as taxpayers see that non-filing and under-declaration
goesundetected.
50. Evasionandavoidancebyhigh-incomeindividuals,rangingfromlegaluseoftax
preferencestoillegaluseoflowtaxjurisdictions,couldbeaddressedmoreforcefully. These
activities take a variety of forms, some purely domestic (concealing income, exploiting
preferential treatments), some international (notdeclaring incomefrom abroad). They are
inevitably hard to quantify: for the latter, one estimate is that about $50 billion of tax revenue is
foregone annually in developing countries (Tax Justice Network, 2005). Whatever the precise
amount, there islittle doubt that the sums are large—and,moreover,that failure ofelites to pay a
fair share of taxes undermines support for the wider tax system. Raising substantially more from
such groups, often influential and intimidating, is hard. At a minimum, appropriate legal
provisions are needed: exemptions for agricultural income,for instance, can pander to the
powerful, and in some countries personal incomefrom abroad is simply exempt. Real estate
taxes can be a powerful tool for reaching the better off. Dedicating units within the tax
administration to high-income/wealth individuals can provide a focus for enforcement efforts,
with high profile prison terms sending a salutary lesson. Strong audit power, including the
possibility to use indirect methods to assess tax liabilities, is an effective tool for increasing the
effectiveness ofaudit operations: these enable revenue agencies to use third party information,
particularly relatedto assets andflow ofinvestments, toestimate the taxpayer's income(Biber,
2010). Collective action on abuse through tax havens, as with the work of the Global Forum on
Transparency and Exchange of Information for Tax Purposes, can benefit developing countries.
51. 'Global'PITshaveprovedespeciallyhardtoimplementinlowerincome
countries—explicitlyschedularsystems,withcoherenttreatmentofcapitalincome,can
offerimprovement. Onpaper,mostdevelopingcountrieshavea'global'incometax—a
39The topPITbracket startsat about 18times percapitaincome inupper middle-income countries,and 83times in
LICs (Peter, Buttrick, and Duncan, 2010). Lee and Gordon(2005) find no growthimpact fromthe topPITrate.
33
progressive charge on the sum of income from all sources40—and building such income taxes
was a focus ofmuch advice through the 1970s.41 The low yield, narrow base, and accumulated
structuralincoherenciesofthesetaxesmean,however,thatthisapproachhasfailed:"....inmost
developingcountries, the global progressive personal incometax long advocated by experts
is…neitherglobalorprogressive,norpersonal,notoftenevenonincome"(ZoltandBird,2005).
In practice, many lower income countries have schedular systems—taxing different types of
income separately. The theoretical merit of the global approach has itself been more widely
challenged in recent years (it may, for instance, simply be unrealistic, given their differing
international mobility, to apply the same top marginal rate to capital as to labor income). Several
advancedcountrieshavemovedtowardsaparticularformofschedulartaxation,the'dual
income tax' (DIT): applying a progressive tax to labor incomebut a lower (and, critically,
uniform) rate to capital income. Whatever view is taken of this as a long-term objective in
personal income taxation, movement towards explicit and more coherent schedular taxation—
with limited discrimination between different types of capital income—can be a practical option
towards greater effectiveness.42 It can limit avoidance opportunities that arise through relabeling
capital income,43 and ease both administration and compliance, especially where capital income
is taxed at a flat rate (tax then being implementable largely by final withholding). Importantly,
the 'Achillesheel' ofthe DIT inadvancedeconomies—the ability ofsmallercompaniesto
reclassify labor as capital income (or vice versa)—is less troubling in developing countries given
the difficulty of subjecting them to any reasonable tax at all.
E. Taxing Corporations
52. CITrevenues—moreimportanttodevelopingthanadvancedeconomies—face
pressuresfromglobalization,buthaveasyetprovedreasonablyrobust. Figure12shows
developments inCIT rates andrevenuebyincomeclass. Statutory rates have tumbled
worldwide, though remaining somewhat higher in lower income countries.44 The revenue
challenges that suchdownwardpressures couldpose are agreaterconcernfordevelopingthan
advanced economies:the CIT raises about 17percentoftotal tax inthe former,comparedto
10 percent (pre-crisis) in the OECD. In practice, CIT revenue in all income groups has
performed strongly in the face of rate reductions (at least until the crisis, in high-income
countries),45
40Or,insomeFrancophonecountries,a'complementary'incometax:aprogressivetaxonthesumofnetincomes
fromsources towhichdistinct schedular taxesapply.
41SeeforinstanceGoode(1993).
42Others have reacheda similar conclusion: Almand Wallace (2002), Zolt and Bird(2005).
43As tax-preferredcapital gains, forinstance.
44This mayinsomecasesreflecttheuseoftheCITtoextract resourcerents,absent bettertargetedinstruments.
45This does not imply any causality inthe relationship.
34
Figure 12. Developments in Corporate Tax Rates and Revenues, 1980-2009
Low-Income Countries
2.50 60
50
2.00
40
1.50
30
1.00
20
0.50
10
0.00 0
1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008
Corporate Tax Revenue (% GDP) Corporate Tax Rate (Right Axis)
Lower Middle-Income Countries
4.00 45
3.50 40
3.00 35
30
2.50
25
2.00
20
1.50
15
1.00 10
0.50 5
0.00 0
1 9 8 0 1 9 8 2 1 9 8 4 1 9 8 6 1 9 8 8 1 9 9 0 1 9 9 2 1 9 9 4 1 9 9 6 1 9 9 8 2 0 0 0 2 0 0 2 2 0 0 4 2 0 0 6 2 0 0 8
Corporate Tax Revenue (%GDP) Corporate Tax Rate (Righ Axis)
Upper Middle-Income Countries
4.00 45
3.50 40
3.00 35
30
2.50
25
2.00
20
1.50
15
1.00 10
0.50 5
0.00 0
1 9 8 0 1 9 8 2 1 9 8 4 1 9 8 6 1 9 8 8 1 9 9 0 1 9 9 2 1 9 9 4 1 9 9 6 1 9 9 8 2 0 0 0 2 0 0 2 2 0 0 4 2 0 0 6 2 0 0 8
Corporate Tax Revenue(%GDP) Corporate Tax Rate (Right Axis)
High-Income Countries
4.00 50
3.50 45
40
3.00
35
2.50 30
2.00 25
1.50 20
15
1.00
10
0.50 5
0.00 0
1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008
Percent
points
In
percent
Percent
Points
In
percent
Percent
Points
In
percent
Percent
Points
In
percent
Corporate Tax Revenue(%GDP) Corporate Tax Rate (Right Axis)
Source: IMF staff calculations.
Note: Group medians, dynamic income group; scales vary.
35
53. Incentives—preferentialtreatmentofparticulartypesofinvestment—havebecome
morepervasiveinsub-SaharanAfrica,thoughthewiderpictureismixed. In1980about
40 percent of LICs in sub-Saharan Africa offered tax holidays, while by 2005 about 80 percent
did; and there was a very marked increase in the proportion providingspecial tax treatment in
free trade zones:fromnilto 50 percent(KeenandMansour,2010).That revenuenevertheless
broadly held up, even aside from resource revenues, presumably reflects an increase in the profit
share whose continuationcannotbe assumed.46 In Latin Americaandthe Caribbean,onthe other
hand, the average length ofholidays fell (Klemm and van Parys, 2009).
54. Reducedtaxratesandincentivescanattractforeigninvestment,butonlywhere
otherbusinessconditionsaregood. Businesssurveysrepeatedlyfindthatwhiletaxation
matters for foreign investors, other considerations—infrastructure, rule of law, labor—matter
more (for instance, McKinsey, 2003), as emerging econometric evidence confirms (van Parys
andJames,2009andDharmapalaandHines,2009).
55. Incentivesposeconcernsofeffectiveness,leakage,governanceandspillovers. Some
types of incentive are more likely to attract investment generatingwider social benefits than are
others: an investment tax credit, for instance, may for this reason be preferable to simply
exempting profits. Incentives can be hard to control: free zones, for instance, are notalways
well-controlled sealed areas,47 and profits can be transfer priced from non-holiday to holiday
companies. Signaling a willingness to provide special tax treatment invites special pleading and
corruption;and the demand for incentives, particularly tax holidays—generally agreed to be the
worst form of incentive (Appendix X)—may in part be a response to, and so entrench, corruption
in the tax administration. The scope to raise more revenue by limiting such incentives is hard to
assess— andevenharderwhere holidaycompaniesare notevenrequiredto filetaxreturns—but
seems likely in manycases to be substantial. Cubeddu et al. (2008) put the revenue cost of CIT
incentives in 15 Caribbean countries at an average of around 5½ percent of GDP. Less dramatic
but sizable, available estimates for Latin America put the cost of preferential treatments under
the income tax at 0.5-6 percent ofGDP (Villela, Lemgruber, and Jorratt, 2010).48 And, as an
indicator to betreatedwithverygreat caution,forthose LICs with'CIT-productivity'49 below
the median fortheirincomegroup,raisingittothat median,whetherbybase-broadeningor
improved compliance, would in 2002 have increased revenue by about 0.7 percent of GDP.
46TheconvergenceofstatutoryCITratesoverthesampleperiodmayalsohavereducedlossesthroughtransfer
pricing.
47They also raise WTO-consistency issues.
48Thefiguresneedtobeinterpretedwithcare:methodologiesdiffer,and, moreover,theneedtohonorexisting
commitmentscanmeanthattherevenuegainstakesometimetomaterialize.
49CIT revenue in percent of GDP divided by the CIT rate. One reason for caution is that (unlike VAT C-efficiency)
thisisnot evaluatingrevenueperformancerelativetoacoherentbenchmarkbase.
36
56. Regionalcooperationcanhelpcombatexcessiveincentives—butunilateralactions
havealsosucceeded. Incompetingtoattractinvestment,countriescanmakethemselves
collectively worse off. Regional agreements to limit incentives (a model is in Appendix XI) can
block downward tax competition. This can be especially helpful where the formation of customs
unionsincreases firms' mobilityandcanpromptpressure foralternative protective measures;
indeed one lesson of the continuing difficulties many trading blocs have in reaching such
agreements isthat theyare best putinplace intandemwithotherintegrationmeasures,before
the intensified pressures come into play. While participants in such agreements remain
vulnerable to competition from third countries, the net gains—including in scaling back
governance problems associated with preferential treatments—could be substantial. The
difficulties in reaching such agreements are more political than technical, as seen in Central
America and the East African Community (EAC), for example. Unilateral actions, however,
have also proved beneficial: Appendix XII.
57. Internationaltaxconsiderationsareincreasinglyimportantfordeveloping
countries,whichcanbepowerfullyaffectedbyactionsofadvancedcountries. Multinational
companies have opportunities for profit-shifting through intra-group transactions, financial
arrangements andcorporate structuring.Even the most advancedtaxadministrationsstruggle
with this, and—although the extent of the revenue impact remains unclear50—the challenges are
greater where capacityisweak.Someargue,moreover,that presentnormsare tiltedagainst
developing countries; the low withholding taxes common in double tax treaties (DTTs), for
instance, can weaken a last line ofprotection for weak administrations. The sheer transactions
costs of negotiatingDTTs can be a severe drain, which could perhaps be eased by developing
multilateral treaties. (Thuronyi, 2001). Convergence ofstatutory tax rates reduces avoidance
incentives, but developing (and retaining) capacity to deal with them will remain a severe
challenge. A realistic balance must be struck between the additional revenue to be gained in this
area—by increased administrative efforts in relation to transfer pricing, for instance—and that
from strengtheningmore prosaic aspects of administration. Advanced country decisions can ease
the difficulties of developing countries (as with the reinvigorated G-20 action on tax havens, for
instance)51 but canalso riskdeepeningthem:rate cuts inadvancedeconomiescan trigger cuts
elsewhere, for example, and exemptingforeign profits, as sometimes proposed inthe U.S. and
underway in the United Kingdom, might intensify global tax competition.52
50Baker(2005), widely-cited, putssuchflows at $700-1,000billionper year,with$320-520 fromdeveloping
countries (with a total of a further $350-500 billion of criminal and corrupt flows); the underlying sources, however,
are not available. While there is indeed substantial evidence that profit-shifting is extensive, Fuest and Reidl (2010)
arguethatthemethodologiesunderlyingavailable estimatesofitsextent andrevenuecostareproblematic.
51Torvik(2009) argues that their impact ongovernance canmake taxhavens especially damaging fordeveloping
countries.
52Underthealternative'residence-based'approach,taxpaidabroadiscreditableagainstthatdueathome,sothat
those foreign taxes impose no additional liability onthe investor; Mullins (2006) elaborates.
37
58. SOEsposesignificantcomplianceproblemsinsomecountries. Thetransitionto
taxing them bythe same rules andmethods as appliedto private enterprises has notalways been
easy, and in some cases remains incomplete—most evidently so inrelation to some natural
resource companies,53 butalso sometimestooinsuchsectorsas energygenerationand
transmission, telecommunications, and transportation. While the taxation of SOEs profits raises
no netrevenue for government broadly interpreted, revenue from the VAT and wage withholding
can suffer, non-compliance undermines good commercial practice and wider taxpayer morale,
and large accumulations oftax arrears can result in administrations diverting scarce resources
away from more productive activities. Solutions rarely lie within the capacity of the tax
administration alone,though efforts can be made to identify and quarantine arrears, followingup
byenforcement.
F. Excises
59. Excises—taxesonafewkeyproducts—areasignificantsourceofrevenue,butin
trend decline (Figure 13)—mainly, it seems, as a result of decliningreal rates. Their importance
also varies substantially across regions, being much less, for instance, in sub-Saharan Africa and
Middle Eastern and Central Asian countries than in Asia54 and South America; and Francophone
Africa derives less from this source than Anglophone.
Figure 13. Developments in Excise Revenues, 1980-2008
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
Low income Lower middleincome Upper middleincome High income
Source: IMF staff calculations
Note: Dynamic income groups. Samples are sometimes small (as low as two LICs for 2005-07).
60. Leviedonafewkeyitems,excisescanservebothrevenueand,insomecases,wider
socialends. Specialtaxes are sometimesleviedonluxury goods suchas jewelryorperfume,but
53The particular challenges indealing withthese are discussedbyMcPherson(2010).
54Tobaccoalone raises around 8percent of central government revenue inChina P.R.and Indonesia: Barber etal.
(2008)andHuetal.(2008).
38
typically bring little revenue and so have only a token impact on equity. Almost all excise
revenue comes from fuels, tobacco, alcohol and other drinks, cars and, increasingly, mobile
phones,55 the rationale for these charges beingnotonlyto tap the revenue potential ofa relatively
inelastic and readily identified base but, to varying degrees, to change behavior:





6
1.
Petroleum products. Fuel taxes are often part of wider frameworks to
stabilizeand
moderate domestic retail prices. Direct subsidies in developing countries
amounted to
around $54 billion in mid-2009, and net revenue foregone relative to a tax
of $0.3 per
liter to around $110 billion (Arze del Granado et al., 2010). More effective
fuel pricing
would serve distributional ends—empirical work repeatedly finds better ways
to help the
poor (del Granado et al., 2010)—and help address environmental concerns
(not only, or
even mainly, climate change, but also local pollution and
congestion);
Cigarettes: Externality and self-control considerations point to higher taxes
than would
otherwise be the case (there being substantial evidence that they can deter new
smokers;
Ross and Chaloupka, 2000), with several studies suggesting scope for
gains inboth
revenue and health from increases in many developing countries: 56 in
the order of
0.3-0.4 percent of GDP in India and Vietnam, for
instance;57
Alcoholic and other drinks: Local custom, social preferences and drinking
patternsmean
that revenue potential can differ widely. Increasing attention is being paid to
the case for
taxing non-alcoholic bottled drinks in low-
income countries;
Motor vehicles. In addition to raising worthwhile revenue—0.1 to 0.15 percent
ofGDP in
Botswana and Lebanon—largely from the better-off, vehicle taxes can
also address
extern
alities;
and
T
e
l
e
c
o
m
s
.
A
u
ctioninglicenses is in principle the best way to tax the potentially
substantial rents in this increasingly important sector. Failing that, excises
can raise
substantial revenue without unduly discouraging use (the positive
externalities from
which appear to be sizeable: Jensen, 2007). Liberia, for instance, raises about 6
percentof
its revenue from this source. The amounts are much less elsewhere, but the
scopefor
increa
se is
clear.
Excisescanbeamongthesimplesttaxestoimplement,buttherearechallenges
—
someofwhichcanbeeasedbyregionalcooperation. Concentratedproduction
andhigh
55In2009, excises ontobaccoand drink accountedfor around 80percent ofnon-fuelexciserevenue in
the Central
African Republic and Senegal, and 90 percent inEgypt and the
Philippines.
56Seefor example: WHO(2010), Sunley(2010), and Petit
(forthcoming).
57International Unionagainst tuberculosis and lung disease,countrystudies are
available at:
http://www.tobaccofreeunion.org
(January4,2011).
39
import shares make administration (nowadays generally located in the LTO) relatively easy. One
long-standing issue is the choice between specific and ad valorem forms of excise (specified as
monetary amountsandas proportionofthe price,respectively): the formerare better-suitedto
addressing externalities (which generally dependon quantities, not prices), and have often been
regarded as simpler to administer, though any advantages of specific taxation in this respect are
becoming less marked as implementation moves away from physical control).58 But other
concerns are coming more to the fore. Telecoms, for instance, raise less familiar implementation
issues, includingthe taxation ofprepaid airtime and auditing operators without the necessary
software and technical expertise. Still more of a concern in many countries are potential
difficulties—or, for some, a source of revenue gain—from smuggling. Illicit and small scale
production can also undercut excise revenue (and in some cases raise public health issues). Fear
ofinducingrevenue losses from these sourcesisonereasonmanycountrieshave hesitatedto
increase rates. Administrative measures, including close control of bondedwarehouses and
transit shipments are important, especially within customs unions; however, some degree of
policy cooperation may be needed—perhaps including, in CEMAC and WAEMU, agreement to
raise regionally-agreedmaximum rates.
62. Thereisscopeinmanycountriestoraisesignificantadditionalrevenuefromexcises
withoutadversedistributionaleffects. Thedecliningshareofexcisesintaxrevenuesuggests
considerable scope for increase (beyond offsetting any tariff reductions on excisables), perhaps
supported by some degree of policy and administrative cooperation. Prescriptions clearly need to
be country-specific (an exception being the universal importance of automatic indexation of
specific taxes), but, for example, sub-Saharan Africa and the Middle East and Central Asia could
increase excise revenue by an average of 0.5 percent ofGDP and 1.3 percent ofGDP
respectively by increasing the share of excises in total revenue to the world average.
G. TaxingSmallBusinesses
63. Smallbusinessesareextremelydifficulttomanage,andhavelimitedrevenue
potential. Thisisahighlyheterogeneousgroup,from'micro'businesses—streettraders,
subsistence farmers—with limited ability to pay (in both fairness and practical terms), through
professionals and businesses with many employees. The highly skewed size distribution of
firms—in all countries, but perhaps especially so in developing—means that such businesses are
numerous, but have little revenue potential. In Egypt, the largest 4,000 companies account for about 90
percentof total turnover; even a massive proportional increase in receipts from the 5
million small enterprises would have relatively little impact on total receipts. It is not uncommon
for developingcountry tax administrations to devote large resources to this segment inthe hope
of flushing out medium or large taxpayers by blanket enforcementoperations; but results have
been poor andcosts ofimplementationhigh.
58Other considerations in making the choice include the stabilityof revenues (tending tofavor specific where the
demand elasticity is low) and maintaining the availability of low-price product variants (favoring ad valorem).
40
64. Thetaxtreatmentofsmallbusinesshasimportance,however,beyondrevenue. They
are often viewed as especially important in generating employment and productivity-enhancing
innovations, although the evidence onthis is mixed.59 What is clear is that they are often
politically influential. Such considerations, combined with their limited revenue potential and the
risk of distracting the tax administration from more critical tasks, might suggest subjecting them
to nomorethansometokentax—as hasbeencommon.Buttherearepowerfulreasonsfor
carefulattentionto the treatmentofsmall businesses, whichcan:




6
5.
Ease competitive distortions and inefficiencies. Taxation—including
attendant
compliance costs and, potentially, exposure to bribery and harassment
—canbe a
powerful disincentive for small firms to regularize their activities. In
some instances,
there is a high effective tax rate on new investments by small enterprises
(FIAS, 2007),
and firms may limit their growth to avoid detection by the revenue authorities.
In extreme
but not uncommon cases, firms become 'ghosts'. Although surveys repeatedly
showthat
taxation is far from the only reason firms remain irregular—labor laws, social
standards
and corruption can be at least as important—the distortions are clear. Non-
compliance by
small taxpayers, coupled with the greater ability of large firms to
benefit from tax
exemptions, can create an inverse U-shaped relationship between firm size and
effective
tax rates that is unlikely to be optimal.60 Even a tax on small businesses which
raises less
than it costs to collect is desirable to the extent it eases these distortions
(Keen,2010);
Enhance taxpayer morale. Compliance of larger businesses can be
underminedif
smaller ones are not seen to pay reasonable amounts. And small businesses
themselves
are more likely to comply if they believe others are—creating the possibility
of shifting
from'bad'complianceequilibriato'good'
ones;
Contributetostate-building.Bringingsmallbusinessesintothetaxnetcanhelp
secure
their participation in the political process and improve government
accountability; and
B
r
i
n
g
n
o
n
-taxbenefitstosmallenterprisesthemselves.Compliancemayboost
record-keeping capacities and financial sophistication, for instance, and
so improve
capital market access. If enterprises fail to appreciate such benefits
themselves, orthe
consequent productivity gains yield wider spillover benefits,
intervention by the tax
authorities beyond that justified by revenue considerations would be
warranted.
Small businesses tax regimes vary widely,61 but a coherent structure can be
built
around a relatively high VAT threshold. All too often, a low VAT threshold
and overly-
59Biggs and Shah(1998) findlarge firms tobe thedominant creatorsof manufacturing jobs insub-
SaharanAfrica.
60Gauthier and Gersovitz (1997) on Cameroon; and Gauthier and Reinikka (2006) on Uganda. This
may also partly
explainthe'missingmiddle'inthedistributionoffirmsizeindeveloping
countries.
61Bodin (2010) and Bodin and Koukpaizan (2008) reviewrecent developments and options in
taxing small
businesses in lower income countries, including withholding and advance collection schemes
discussedbelow.
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d

Contenu connexe

Tendances

Mind the Gap Report Overview
Mind the Gap Report OverviewMind the Gap Report Overview
Mind the Gap Report Overview
pondo4life
 
C201 candy estimating & valuations - rev 5
C201   candy estimating & valuations - rev 5C201   candy estimating & valuations - rev 5
C201 candy estimating & valuations - rev 5
Self-employed
 
C202 construction planning and programming
C202   construction planning and programmingC202   construction planning and programming
C202 construction planning and programming
ALEXANDRASUWANN
 
Us gaap v_ifrs_comparison_document-june08
Us gaap v_ifrs_comparison_document-june08Us gaap v_ifrs_comparison_document-june08
Us gaap v_ifrs_comparison_document-june08
Sahas Patil
 
Energy and carbon management strategy 2015
Energy and carbon management strategy 2015Energy and carbon management strategy 2015
Energy and carbon management strategy 2015
Paul Stephenson
 
Jordan Innovation Policy - A Practical Guide to Wealth Creation
Jordan Innovation Policy - A Practical Guide to Wealth CreationJordan Innovation Policy - A Practical Guide to Wealth Creation
Jordan Innovation Policy - A Practical Guide to Wealth Creation
GrowthWorks
 
Candy - Construction Estimating & Valuations - rev 2.01
Candy - Construction Estimating & Valuations - rev 2.01Candy - Construction Estimating & Valuations - rev 2.01
Candy - Construction Estimating & Valuations - rev 2.01
Jerico Awat
 
National venture capital association yearbook 2013
National venture capital association yearbook 2013National venture capital association yearbook 2013
National venture capital association yearbook 2013
Steve Hu
 

Tendances (19)

Gis database
Gis databaseGis database
Gis database
 
Mind the Gap Report Overview
Mind the Gap Report OverviewMind the Gap Report Overview
Mind the Gap Report Overview
 
C201 candy estimating & valuations - rev 5
C201   candy estimating & valuations - rev 5C201   candy estimating & valuations - rev 5
C201 candy estimating & valuations - rev 5
 
Punjab Economic Report 2007
Punjab Economic Report 2007Punjab Economic Report 2007
Punjab Economic Report 2007
 
C202 construction planning and programming
C202   construction planning and programmingC202   construction planning and programming
C202 construction planning and programming
 
Us gaap v_ifrs_comparison_document-june08
Us gaap v_ifrs_comparison_document-june08Us gaap v_ifrs_comparison_document-june08
Us gaap v_ifrs_comparison_document-june08
 
Strategy Package for Higher Growth & Structural Change Human Capital for a Hi...
Strategy Package for Higher Growth & Structural Change Human Capital for a Hi...Strategy Package for Higher Growth & Structural Change Human Capital for a Hi...
Strategy Package for Higher Growth & Structural Change Human Capital for a Hi...
 
Energy and carbon management strategy 2015
Energy and carbon management strategy 2015Energy and carbon management strategy 2015
Energy and carbon management strategy 2015
 
Jordan Innovation Policy - A Practical Guide to Wealth Creation
Jordan Innovation Policy - A Practical Guide to Wealth CreationJordan Innovation Policy - A Practical Guide to Wealth Creation
Jordan Innovation Policy - A Practical Guide to Wealth Creation
 
Fire fighting fluid manufacturing business plan for Labour Market Impact Asse...
Fire fighting fluid manufacturing business plan for Labour Market Impact Asse...Fire fighting fluid manufacturing business plan for Labour Market Impact Asse...
Fire fighting fluid manufacturing business plan for Labour Market Impact Asse...
 
Candy - Construction Estimating & Valuations - rev 2.01
Candy - Construction Estimating & Valuations - rev 2.01Candy - Construction Estimating & Valuations - rev 2.01
Candy - Construction Estimating & Valuations - rev 2.01
 
HSK 2 Chinese Intensive Reading for Beginner Level H20901 汉语水平考试模拟考题 sample
HSK 2 Chinese Intensive Reading for Beginner Level H20901 汉语水平考试模拟考题 sampleHSK 2 Chinese Intensive Reading for Beginner Level H20901 汉语水平考试模拟考题 sample
HSK 2 Chinese Intensive Reading for Beginner Level H20901 汉语水平考试模拟考题 sample
 
National venture capital association yearbook 2013
National venture capital association yearbook 2013National venture capital association yearbook 2013
National venture capital association yearbook 2013
 
Nvca report 2013
Nvca report 2013Nvca report 2013
Nvca report 2013
 
Gii 2012 france innovation profile
Gii 2012   france innovation profileGii 2012   france innovation profile
Gii 2012 france innovation profile
 
Working paper
Working paperWorking paper
Working paper
 
THE STATE OF DOMESTIC COMMERCE IN PAKISTAN STUDY 1 COMPETITIVENESS
THE STATE OF DOMESTIC COMMERCE IN PAKISTAN STUDY 1 COMPETITIVENESSTHE STATE OF DOMESTIC COMMERCE IN PAKISTAN STUDY 1 COMPETITIVENESS
THE STATE OF DOMESTIC COMMERCE IN PAKISTAN STUDY 1 COMPETITIVENESS
 
Buisness Plan V1
Buisness Plan V1Buisness Plan V1
Buisness Plan V1
 
Google Decode q2 2014 toc
Google Decode q2 2014 tocGoogle Decode q2 2014 toc
Google Decode q2 2014 toc
 

Similaire à Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d

Forecasting, Financing & Fast Tracking Your Business Growth
Forecasting, Financing & Fast Tracking Your Business GrowthForecasting, Financing & Fast Tracking Your Business Growth
Forecasting, Financing & Fast Tracking Your Business Growth
Venugopal Rao Pendyala
 
REVISED VALIDATION DRAFT NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT PLAN (2023-2027) 19.12.22.pdf
REVISED VALIDATION DRAFT NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT PLAN (2023-2027) 19.12.22.pdfREVISED VALIDATION DRAFT NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT PLAN (2023-2027) 19.12.22.pdf
REVISED VALIDATION DRAFT NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT PLAN (2023-2027) 19.12.22.pdf
ChernoBBah2
 
Bcv informe económico 2009 en ingles.
Bcv informe económico 2009 en ingles.Bcv informe económico 2009 en ingles.
Bcv informe económico 2009 en ingles.
Rafael Verde)
 
GNW%20Q308%20QFS
GNW%20Q308%20QFSGNW%20Q308%20QFS
GNW%20Q308%20QFS
finance24
 
GNW%20Q308%20QFS
GNW%20Q308%20QFSGNW%20Q308%20QFS
GNW%20Q308%20QFS
finance24
 
Call guides cpm fy10
Call guides cpm fy10Call guides cpm fy10
Call guides cpm fy10
Fitira
 
ingram micro Proxy Statement 2004
ingram micro  Proxy Statement 2004ingram micro  Proxy Statement 2004
ingram micro Proxy Statement 2004
finance7
 
Summary report
Summary reportSummary report
Summary report
econsultbw
 
GNW 04/03/07Supplement
GNW 04/03/07SupplementGNW 04/03/07Supplement
GNW 04/03/07Supplement
finance24
 
GNW 04/03/07Supplement
GNW 04/03/07SupplementGNW 04/03/07Supplement
GNW 04/03/07Supplement
finance24
 

Similaire à Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d (20)

Metasip final1
Metasip final1Metasip final1
Metasip final1
 
11 805-international-trade-investment-rationale-for-support
11 805-international-trade-investment-rationale-for-support11 805-international-trade-investment-rationale-for-support
11 805-international-trade-investment-rationale-for-support
 
Forecasting, Financing & Fast Tracking Your Business Growth
Forecasting, Financing & Fast Tracking Your Business GrowthForecasting, Financing & Fast Tracking Your Business Growth
Forecasting, Financing & Fast Tracking Your Business Growth
 
Strategy Field Project Report
Strategy Field Project ReportStrategy Field Project Report
Strategy Field Project Report
 
MINERAL TAX CLINIC REVISED EDITION 3
MINERAL TAX CLINIC REVISED EDITION 3MINERAL TAX CLINIC REVISED EDITION 3
MINERAL TAX CLINIC REVISED EDITION 3
 
Page 36 Better Regulation Berr 1
Page 36 Better Regulation Berr 1Page 36 Better Regulation Berr 1
Page 36 Better Regulation Berr 1
 
Doing business in india
Doing business in indiaDoing business in india
Doing business in india
 
REVISED VALIDATION DRAFT NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT PLAN (2023-2027) 19.12.22.pdf
REVISED VALIDATION DRAFT NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT PLAN (2023-2027) 19.12.22.pdfREVISED VALIDATION DRAFT NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT PLAN (2023-2027) 19.12.22.pdf
REVISED VALIDATION DRAFT NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT PLAN (2023-2027) 19.12.22.pdf
 
Bcv informe económico 2009 en ingles.
Bcv informe económico 2009 en ingles.Bcv informe económico 2009 en ingles.
Bcv informe económico 2009 en ingles.
 
Bcv informe económico 2009 en ingles.
Bcv informe económico 2009 en ingles.Bcv informe económico 2009 en ingles.
Bcv informe económico 2009 en ingles.
 
GNW%20Q308%20QFS
GNW%20Q308%20QFSGNW%20Q308%20QFS
GNW%20Q308%20QFS
 
GNW%20Q308%20QFS
GNW%20Q308%20QFSGNW%20Q308%20QFS
GNW%20Q308%20QFS
 
Currency guide
Currency guideCurrency guide
Currency guide
 
Call guides cpm fy10
Call guides cpm fy10Call guides cpm fy10
Call guides cpm fy10
 
ingram micro Proxy Statement 2004
ingram micro  Proxy Statement 2004ingram micro  Proxy Statement 2004
ingram micro Proxy Statement 2004
 
Summary report
Summary reportSummary report
Summary report
 
GNW 04/03/07Supplement
GNW 04/03/07SupplementGNW 04/03/07Supplement
GNW 04/03/07Supplement
 
GNW 04/03/07Supplement
GNW 04/03/07SupplementGNW 04/03/07Supplement
GNW 04/03/07Supplement
 
The Economics of Sustainability in the Comemrcial Real Estate Sector
The Economics of Sustainability in the Comemrcial Real Estate SectorThe Economics of Sustainability in the Comemrcial Real Estate Sector
The Economics of Sustainability in the Comemrcial Real Estate Sector
 
Fdi circular 2015
Fdi circular 2015Fdi circular 2015
Fdi circular 2015
 

Plus de Malik Khalid Mehmood

Poverty reduction strategy _by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_d
Poverty reduction strategy  _by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_dPoverty reduction strategy  _by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_d
Poverty reduction strategy _by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_d
Malik Khalid Mehmood
 
Pefa presentation by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_d
Pefa presentation   by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_dPefa presentation   by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_d
Pefa presentation by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_d
Malik Khalid Mehmood
 
Family planning a right based methodology, a policy framework -by dr malik kh...
Family planning a right based methodology, a policy framework -by dr malik kh...Family planning a right based methodology, a policy framework -by dr malik kh...
Family planning a right based methodology, a policy framework -by dr malik kh...
Malik Khalid Mehmood
 
Family planning challenges in pakistan and south asia dr malik khalid mehmoo...
Family planning challenges in pakistan and south asia  dr malik khalid mehmoo...Family planning challenges in pakistan and south asia  dr malik khalid mehmoo...
Family planning challenges in pakistan and south asia dr malik khalid mehmoo...
Malik Khalid Mehmood
 
Evaluation framework and approaches for institutional development and organis...
Evaluation framework and approaches for institutional development and organis...Evaluation framework and approaches for institutional development and organis...
Evaluation framework and approaches for institutional development and organis...
Malik Khalid Mehmood
 
Logramme process flow chart___by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_d
Logramme   process flow chart___by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_dLogramme   process flow chart___by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_d
Logramme process flow chart___by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_d
Malik Khalid Mehmood
 
Logframme _ strategic options__by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_d
Logframme  _ strategic options__by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_dLogframme  _ strategic options__by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_d
Logframme _ strategic options__by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_d
Malik Khalid Mehmood
 
Logramme _training_needs_assessment__by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_d
Logramme  _training_needs_assessment__by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_dLogramme  _training_needs_assessment__by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_d
Logramme _training_needs_assessment__by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_d
Malik Khalid Mehmood
 
Logramme coverage_matrix__by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_d
Logramme  coverage_matrix__by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_dLogramme  coverage_matrix__by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_d
Logramme coverage_matrix__by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_d
Malik Khalid Mehmood
 
Logramme __participation_matrix__by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_d
Logramme  __participation_matrix__by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_dLogramme  __participation_matrix__by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_d
Logramme __participation_matrix__by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_d
Malik Khalid Mehmood
 
Logframe _indicators__by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Logframe  _indicators__by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_dLogframe  _indicators__by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Logframe _indicators__by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Malik Khalid Mehmood
 
Understanding logframme __organisation_assessment___iom____by_dr_malik_khalid...
Understanding logframme __organisation_assessment___iom____by_dr_malik_khalid...Understanding logframme __organisation_assessment___iom____by_dr_malik_khalid...
Understanding logframme __organisation_assessment___iom____by_dr_malik_khalid...
Malik Khalid Mehmood
 
Understanding logframme __organisation_assessment___iom____by_dr_malik_khalid...
Understanding logframme __organisation_assessment___iom____by_dr_malik_khalid...Understanding logframme __organisation_assessment___iom____by_dr_malik_khalid...
Understanding logframme __organisation_assessment___iom____by_dr_malik_khalid...
Malik Khalid Mehmood
 
Understanding logframe ___problem_tree_analysis_____by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmoo...
Understanding logframe ___problem_tree_analysis_____by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmoo...Understanding logframe ___problem_tree_analysis_____by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmoo...
Understanding logframe ___problem_tree_analysis_____by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmoo...
Malik Khalid Mehmood
 
Understanding logical framework_methodology___by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Understanding logical framework_methodology___by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_dUnderstanding logical framework_methodology___by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Understanding logical framework_methodology___by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Malik Khalid Mehmood
 

Plus de Malik Khalid Mehmood (20)

National sanitation _policy
National sanitation _policyNational sanitation _policy
National sanitation _policy
 
Pakistan _CA
Pakistan _CAPakistan _CA
Pakistan _CA
 
Pakistan ca
Pakistan caPakistan ca
Pakistan ca
 
Trade policy review_of_nepal
Trade policy review_of_nepalTrade policy review_of_nepal
Trade policy review_of_nepal
 
Final report 21 10 2013
Final report 21 10 2013Final report 21 10 2013
Final report 21 10 2013
 
Poverty reduction strategy _by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_d
Poverty reduction strategy  _by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_dPoverty reduction strategy  _by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_d
Poverty reduction strategy _by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_d
 
Pefa presentation by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_d
Pefa presentation   by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_dPefa presentation   by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_d
Pefa presentation by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_d
 
Family planning a right based methodology, a policy framework -by dr malik kh...
Family planning a right based methodology, a policy framework -by dr malik kh...Family planning a right based methodology, a policy framework -by dr malik kh...
Family planning a right based methodology, a policy framework -by dr malik kh...
 
Family planning challenges in pakistan and south asia dr malik khalid mehmoo...
Family planning challenges in pakistan and south asia  dr malik khalid mehmoo...Family planning challenges in pakistan and south asia  dr malik khalid mehmoo...
Family planning challenges in pakistan and south asia dr malik khalid mehmoo...
 
Evaluation framework and approaches for institutional development and organis...
Evaluation framework and approaches for institutional development and organis...Evaluation framework and approaches for institutional development and organis...
Evaluation framework and approaches for institutional development and organis...
 
Logramme process flow chart___by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_d
Logramme   process flow chart___by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_dLogramme   process flow chart___by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_d
Logramme process flow chart___by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_d
 
Logframme _ strategic options__by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_d
Logframme  _ strategic options__by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_dLogframme  _ strategic options__by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_d
Logframme _ strategic options__by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_d
 
Logramme _training_needs_assessment__by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_d
Logramme  _training_needs_assessment__by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_dLogramme  _training_needs_assessment__by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_d
Logramme _training_needs_assessment__by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_d
 
Logramme coverage_matrix__by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_d
Logramme  coverage_matrix__by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_dLogramme  coverage_matrix__by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_d
Logramme coverage_matrix__by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_d
 
Logramme __participation_matrix__by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_d
Logramme  __participation_matrix__by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_dLogramme  __participation_matrix__by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_d
Logramme __participation_matrix__by dr malik khalid mehmood ph_d
 
Logframe _indicators__by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Logframe  _indicators__by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_dLogframe  _indicators__by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Logframe _indicators__by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
 
Understanding logframme __organisation_assessment___iom____by_dr_malik_khalid...
Understanding logframme __organisation_assessment___iom____by_dr_malik_khalid...Understanding logframme __organisation_assessment___iom____by_dr_malik_khalid...
Understanding logframme __organisation_assessment___iom____by_dr_malik_khalid...
 
Understanding logframme __organisation_assessment___iom____by_dr_malik_khalid...
Understanding logframme __organisation_assessment___iom____by_dr_malik_khalid...Understanding logframme __organisation_assessment___iom____by_dr_malik_khalid...
Understanding logframme __organisation_assessment___iom____by_dr_malik_khalid...
 
Understanding logframe ___problem_tree_analysis_____by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmoo...
Understanding logframe ___problem_tree_analysis_____by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmoo...Understanding logframe ___problem_tree_analysis_____by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmoo...
Understanding logframe ___problem_tree_analysis_____by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmoo...
 
Understanding logical framework_methodology___by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Understanding logical framework_methodology___by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_dUnderstanding logical framework_methodology___by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
Understanding logical framework_methodology___by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d
 

Revenue mobilization in_developing_countries.__prepared_by_dr_malik_khalid_mehmood_ph_d

  • 1. Revenue Mobilization in Developing Countries Prepared by Dr Malik Khalid Mehmood PhD Chief Policy Adviser March18,2011 Contents Page AbbreviationsandAcronyms....................................................................................................3 Executive Summary...................................................................................................................4 I. Introduction............................................................................................................................6 II. Aims,Trends, andPossibilities .............................................................................................6 A.ObjectivesandContext .............................................................................................7 B. Similarities, Differences, and Strategies for Reform ................................................8 C.Trends andRecentExperience................................................................................12 D. Assessing the Scope to Raise More Revenue .........................................................16 III. Issues andLessons.............................................................................................................17 A. Core Administration Reforms.................................................................................19 B. The Value-Added Tax (VAT) .................................................................................23 C. Trade Liberalization and Customs Administration .................................................28 D. PersonalIncomeTaxation.......................................................................................31 E. TaxingCorporations................................................................................................33 F.Excises.....................................................................................................................37 G.TaxingSmall Businesses........................................................................................39 H. Real Estate Taxation ...............................................................................................41 IV. InstitutionsandTransparency............................................................................................42 V. Issues forDiscussion...........................................................................................................45 Table 1.VAT Features byIncomeGroup...........................................................................................25 Figures 1. Revenue-RelatedandOtherStructuralBenchmarks,2002-10...........................................11 2. TrendsinTotalandTaxRevenue1980-2009.....................................................................12
  • 2. 2 3.ReceiptsfromNaturalResources,averages2000-07..........................................................13 4. Tax Revenue Developments in Resource-Rich and Other Countries, 1980-2009..............14 5. Tax Revenue Developments byRegion,1980-2009...........................................................15 6. Distributionofthe TaxRatioinDevelopingCountries,1990-95and2003-08 .................15 7. Trends inthe CompositionofRevenues, 1980-2009..........................................................16 8.The Spreadofthe VAT,1980-2009....................................................................................24 9. Benefits from Zero-Rating Relative to Income Shares, Mexico..........................................26 10. Developments in Trade Tax Revenue and Collected Tariff Rates, 1980-2009 ................28 11. DevelopmentsinTaxRevenueandTrade TaxRevenue,1980-2009...............................29 12. DevelopmentsinCorporate TaxRates andRevenues, 1980-2009...................................34 13.DevelopmentsinExciseRevenues,1980-2008................................................................37 Boxes 1. CommonElementsofStrategiesfor Reform.......................................................................10 2. The RegionalPerspective ....................................................................................................15 3. Aid, Resource Wealth, and Revenue Mobilization..............................................................16 4. KeyChallenges forTaxReform ..........................................................................................18 5. The Distributional Impact ofExemptions and Reduced Rates............................................26 Appendices I. Technical Assistance onTax Matters...................................................................................46 II. II. Tax Reform in Post-Conflict and Successor States.............................................................48 III. III. Data ....................................................................................................................................50 IV. IV. UnderstandingTax Performance and Effort......................................................................56 V. V. Estimating Tax Effort..........................................................................................................59 VI. VI. StrongPerformers—Three Examples................................................................................63 VII. VII. Taxing Natural Resources—Issues and Principles...........................................................66 VIII. VIII. Estimated Revenue Gains from Increasing VAT Efficiency ..........................................68 IX. IX. Zambia: Building and Maintaining a VAT........................................................................70 X. X. Dangers of Tax Holidays ....................................................................................................71 XI. XI. Regional Agreement on Corporate Taxation—Possible Principles...................................72 XII. XII. Experience with Unilateral Removal of Tax Incentive..................................................74 Appendix Tables 2. SummaryStatistics...............................................................................................................53 3. Fixed CountryGrouping......................................................................................................55 4. EstimatedTax Effort............................................................................................................60 5. VAT Efficiencyby Income Group ......................................................................................68 Appendix Figure 14. Revenue Administration and Tax Policy Mission Intensity, FY2008-10 .........................46 References................................................................................................................................75
  • 7. c e d u r e s C o d e V a l u e - A d d e d T a x U p p e r M i d d l e - I n c o me Cou ntry West African Economic and Monetary Union W or ld C us to m s O rg an iz ati on W o r l d T r a d e O r g a n i z a t i o n
  • 8. 4 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY TheFundhaslongplayedaleadroleinsupportingdevelopingcountries'effortsto improvetheirrevenuemobilization. Thispaperdrawsonthatexperiencetoreviewissuesand good practice,andto assess prospects inthis keyarea.1 Theneedforadditionalrevenueissubstantialinmanydevelopingcountries,butimproving revenuemobilizationhasimportancebeyondthat. Requirementsforrelievingpovertyand improving infrastructure are substantial: achieving the Millennium Development Goals, for instance, may require low-income countries to raise their tax-GDP ratios by around 4 percentage points (UnitedNations, 2005). But the quality ofmeasures also matters: increasingrevenue by further taxing readily compliant taxpayers can worsen distortions and perceived inequities; conversely, reducingreliance ontrade taxes can bring real structural gains that outweigh short-term revenue difficulties. More fundamentally still, the centrality of taxation in the exercise ofstate powermeans that moreefficient,fairer,andless corrupttaxsystems can spearhead improvement in wider governance relations. Experienceshowsthatprogresscanbemade—givenstrongpoliticalwill.Therehavebeen disappointments: insome areas ofadvice (such as early espousal ofthe global income tax) and in country practice (the use made of improved IT systems, for instance). But several countries have significantly improved their tax performance over relatively short periods, and econometric analysis (comparing performance in differing countries) suggests that many lower-income countries could increase their tax ratios by 2-4 percent of GDP. A commonelement of success stories is sustained political commitment at the highest levels: even administrative reforms can promptstrongopposition.Reforms must be entrenched,however,to avoidsubsequentslippage. Significantadditionalrevenuecanberaisedinmanydevelopingcountriesbyestablished methods,adaptedinemphasisandsequencingtocountries'circumstances. Thereare importantcommonalitiesinreform strategies recommendedbythe Fundandothers—andinthe challengesandopportunitiesthatremain:  Building administrations that effectively limit incentives and opportunities for rent- seeking and inappropriate behavior, and are capable of implementingthe voluntary compliance neededto extend the tax base, includingby risk management (allocating resourceswherethe risks to revenue are greatest) andtaxpayer segmentation(tailoring interventionand services to the distinct challenges posed by different groups, starting with a large taxpayer office)—here much remains to be done,but positive results have beenseen;  Adopting and making readily available clear laws and regulations embodying strong taxpayer protection—the main problem is often implementation; 1The paper doesnot address thetaxationof natural resources: Appendix VIIprovides anoverviewof issues and advice,whicharetreatedat lengthinarecent Fund book(Daniel, Keen, and McPherson, 2010).
  • 9. 5  Eliminating exemptions that forego revenue to little useful end—these are often still substantial and can amount to several points of GDP;  Implementing a broad-based VAT with a fairly high threshold (the turnover level at which registration for the tax becomes compulsory)—in lower-income countries where VAT performance is weakest, base-broadening and improved compliance might raise somethingin the order ofan additional 2 percent of GDP;  Establishing a broad-based corporate income tax, at rates competitive by international standards—morehasbeendoneonthelatterthanontheformer,leavingsignsof significant scope for base-broadening in many lower-income countries;  Extendingthe PIT base, and ensuringa coherent treatment ofalternative forms ofcapital income—still a major challenge;  Levying excises on a few key items that are adequate to revenue needs and wider social concerns—these too have furtherpotentialinsome countries;  Implementing simple but coherent regimes for taxing smaller businesses—now receiving increasedattention;  Strengtheningreal estate taxes—minimal in manycountries, but with potential to transform local government finance in the longer-term; and  Developing capacity for tax expenditure and wider policy analysis—impressive advances in some countries, but much still to do in others. Protectionofthepoorest,includingthroughbasicpublicspending,isanoverarching concern. The fairnessofa taxsystem cannotmeaningfully be assessed inisolationofthe spendingit finances: a regressive tax may be the onlyway to finance strongly progressive spending. This makes it important not only to examine the distributional impact of tax reforms themselves but also to identify specific spendingmeasures to address any concerns they raise. Better persuading taxpayers ofthe value ofthe public spendingfinancedby the taxes they pay, including by improvingthe management and quality ofthat spending, can further bolster trust in andcompliancewiththetaxsystem. Thereareemergingconcernsandissuesrequiringgreaterattention. Challengesin international taxation and from regional integration are intensifying, and call for closer cooperation on tax matters—including with advanced economies—in both policy and administration, as well as further support for capacity building. Continued trade liberalization willput pressure onrevenueinmanylower-incomecountries.Scopeto meetthese andother revenue needs by simply raising standard VAT rates is becoming limited, so the potential lies largely in better improving compliance and scaling back preferential treatments. Not least, and important too for the wider legitimacy of tax systems, greater efforts can be made—requiring political will as much as technical capacity—in taxing elites and high-income/wealth individuals.
  • 10. 6 I. INTRODUCTION 1. Strengtheningrevenuemobilizationindevelopingcountrieshaslongbeenacentral concernoftheFund,anditsadvicehasbeenhighlyinfluential. Initsprogram,surveillance and—the main perspective here—technical assistance (TA) work, the Fund has for manyyears supported developingcountries' efforts tobuildmore effective andfairertax systems. Though far from the only provider, the Fund has come to occupya leading role in advising ontax matters in these countries (Appendix I). Its advice has been keenly felt by Fund members, closely watched by academics and CSOs, and sometimes controversial. 2. Interestinenhancingrevenuemobilizationindevelopingcountriesisincreasing.Most developing countries are emerging from the crisis with their fiscal prospects broadly intact (IMF, 2010a), but with many still facinga fundamental needto raise more revenue from their owntax bases. Achieving the Millennium Development Goals, for instance, has been suggested to require increasing domestic revenues in low-income countries (LICs) by around 4 percent of GDP (United Nations, 2005). Infrastructure needs are also extensive (IMF, 2010a), and there are climate challenges to address. Advanced economies are increasingly focused on improving their support of these revenue mobilization efforts. In this context the G-20 leaders called in November 2010 for the Fund, with others, to report onkey issues instrengthening revenue mobilization.2 3. Thispaperreviewsexperienceinstrengtheningtaxsystemsindevelopingcountries— focusingparticularlyonlower-incomecountries.3 Itdrawslessons,forbothpolicyand administration, from analytical and TA work,4 discusses core elements of Fund advice, and assesses prospects for strengtheningrevenue mobilization in the face ofemerging challenges.5 II. AIMS, TRENDS, AND POSSIBILITIES 4. Thissectionaddressesoverarchingissues:theobjectivesofrevenuemobilization, similarities and differences in the challenges faced by developing countries (and the implications 2Othersigns ofstrongdonorinterestincludethecreationoftwotrustfunds tosupport theFund's taxTA,the emphasis ontheissue bytheEuropeanCommission (2010), thecreationbytheDevelopment Assistance Committee of a Task Force onTax and Development, and of the DfID/NORAD-sponsored International Centre for Tax and Development. 3Meaning, broadly speaking, low- and lower middle-income countries (in the World Bank classification, per capita incomebelow$995andbetween$996-3,945);forperspective,indicatorsforuppermiddle-income($3,946-12,195) andadvancedcountriesarealsosometimesreportedbelow. 4Several recent surveys bear on these issues: African Development Bank and OECD (2010), Bird (2008), ECORYS (2010; preparedfor theDutchMinistryofFinance), Gordon(2010), Keenand Simone (2004), and Chambas (2005), and Keenand Mansour (2010a, b)onsub-SaharanAfrica. 5This paperwill informtheFund's contributiontotheworkrequestedbytheG-20.
  • 11. 7 forreformstrategies),recenttrends,andthescopetoraisemore. A.ObjectivesandContext 5. Raisingrevenueisthecoreobjectiveofanytaxsystem,butrevenueisnotthesole concern. Thespendingneedsofdevelopingcountriesaresubstantial,andbothgreaterand, ultimately, more sustained than can be metfrom foreign assistance.6 In low-incomecountries (LICs) the revenue imperative is stark: over 20 still have tax ratios (tax revenue relative to GDP) under15percent.7 Butthereareotherconsiderations:  The effects which theory suggests the level and compositionof taxes can have on efficiencyandlong-rungrowth—viainvestment,humancapitalacquisition,and innovation—have proved hard to identify robustly. For OECD countries, Arnold (2008) concludes that property taxes are least damaging for growth, followed by consumption taxes, the personal income tax (PIT), and the corporate income tax (CIT): this is as theory suggests, with taxation of capital income having a potentially strong impact on investment.Butthere has beenmuchless workfordevelopingcountries,andwhat there is tends to find no significant effect from either the overall level of taxation or the direct-indirect tax mix (Adams and Bevan, 2005; and Martinez-Vasquez, Vulovic, and Liu, 2009). Lee and Gordon (2005) find lower CIT rates are associated with faster growth, including in non-OECD countries, though other tax variables are insignificant. Evidence that trade liberalization fosters growth (Wacziarg and Welch, 2008) suggests a potential impact from reduced reliance ontrade tax revenue. Other effects likely operate through the considerable volatility of tax revenue in many developing countries (there beingsome evidencethat this depresses public investment:Ebeke andEhrhart, 2010), stressing the value ofdiversifying revenue sources;  Distributionaleffects areimportantinthemselves(povertyreliefisamajormotivation for raising revenue in the first place) and for their impact on compliance (likely damaged if taxpayers perceive others, including all-too-often some elite, as paying too little). Two points are critical in assessing these effects. First, what ultimately matters is not the impact of any tax instrument in isolation, but the combined impact of all such measures—and ofthe spendingthey finance. A regressive tax may be the onlyway to finance strongly progressive public expenditure; conversely, where the ability to target spending is relatively weak, progressivity on the tax side is a greater concern. Second, those whobearthe realburdenofanytax maynotbe those responsible forremittingitto the government. To the extent that capital is internationally mobile, for instance, a small country cannotaffect the after-tax return required by foreign investors: trying to do so will simply reduce the income of immobile factors (local labor, most likely). Judging 6Support toadapt toandhelpthemitigationofclimatechange maybeanexception,totheextent thatitisseenas compensationforpastemissions inadvancedeconomies. 7This commonbutarbitrarybenchmarkappearstodatebacktoKaldor(1963).
  • 12. 8 where the real incidence of taxation falls is difficult in advanced economies, and no easier inthe different context oflower-incomeeconomies; and  Taxation is a definingfeature ofstate power, makingits improvement a key aspect of state-building.Thisconsideration,whichstresses theviewoftaxreformasaninvestment central to wider institutional development, has been prominent in recent policy initiatives.8 What remains unclear is what its increased recognition means for tax advice andpolicy. B.Similarities,Differences,andStrategiesforReform 6. Developingcountriesfacemanycommontaxchallenges. Mostarequalitativelythe same as in advancedeconomies—but muchlarger.9 Theyinclude:  Dealingwithsectors that are 'hard-to-tax'everywhere (small businesses,includingsmall farmers, professionals, and—in some cases—state-ownedenterprises), but especially whereadministrativecapacityandcompliancehabitsareweak.'Informality' isextensive in developingcountries—perhaps 40 percent ofGDP on average, up to 60 percentin many.10 Butthisisarguablynotinitselftheproblem:11 microtradersmaybe'informal,' for instance, but are also likely to have income and sales well below any reasonable tax threshold; and much of the most egregious evasion is by qualified professionals. The issueisbestframedasoneof non-compliance. Estimatesofnon-compliancearescarce, butValue-AddedTax(VAT)'gaps'12 havebeenputat50-60percentinIndonesiaand Mozambique, for instance, compared to 13 percent in the United Kingdom;  Weakrevenueadministrations, lowtaxpayermorale,andpoorgovernance—closely linked—though not unique to lower-incomecountries, are especially entrenchedthere. Corruption indicators are strongly associated with low revenue (Attila, Chambas, and Combes, 2008)—indeed corruption functions like a tax itself, and likely a particularly regressive one—as are other governance indicators (weak rule of law, political instability). Causation can run both ways, and governance problems are notunique to revenue administrations and nor can they be fully addressed in isolation from, for 8See for instance OECD (2008) and Everest-Philips (2008). 9Gordonand Li(2009), Heady(2002), and Keenand Simone (2004) discussthe distinct tax-relevant features of developingcountries. 10SeeSchneider,Buehn,andMontenegro(2010). 11Thetermisusedlooselyhere,andindeed—one reasontopreferthefocusonnon-compliancesuggestedhere—is rarelywell-defined (Kanbur, 2009); Keen(2011)elaborates. 12VAT revenue with full compliance less actual VAT revenue, relative to the former; the figures are from Silvani et al.(2008)andCastroetal.(2009).
  • 13. 9 example, judicial reform. Nevertheless, the centrality of tax collection as an exercise of state power gives governance issues in tax collection a particular importance;  Heavyrelianceonreceiptsfrom multinationalenterprises,whoseadroitnessintax planning poses increasing challenges, and, in many cases, difficulties in dealing with state-ownedenterprises thathavebeenknowntoabuseorsimplyignorethetaxsystem;  Shallowuseoffinancialinstitutions,avaluablesourceoftax-relevantinformation;  Pressuresonrevenuefrom tradeliberalization,including regionalintegration, andfrom intensifyinginternational taxcompetition;and  Dealingwith internationalservices,increasinglyimportantbut—sincetheycannotbe intercepted at the border—hard to tax, especially where administrations fail to progress beyond heavy reliance on physical controls. 7. Buttherearealsosignificantdifferencesamongdevelopingcountries.Probablythe most important is in natural resource wealth. Geography also matters. Small islands are better able to impose taxes at the border than are landlocked countries; this may explain both why they have been less inclined to adopt a VAT13 and why, when adopted, it tends to perform well.14 Post-conflict countries, with shattered administrations and tax bases, face particular difficulties, as do successor states eager to establish investor-friendly reputations (AppendixII provides case studies). History also has a role: constitutional restrictions dating to the 1935 Government of India Act still powerfully constrain VAT design in both India and Pakistan, for instance, and there is evidence that differing legal traditions, reflecting colonial pasts, are associated with differentrevenueperformance. 8. Fundadvicereflectsboththesesimilaritiesandthedifferences.Acommoncriticismis thatFundtax adviceis'onesizefitsall.'15 Sometaxpracticesareindeedclosetouniversally appropriate: establishingfirm control of the largest taxpayers, for instance. Beyond that there are certainly commonalities in broad strategies for reform (Box 1), reflecting the generality of underlying economic and organizational principles. But the timing, relative importance, and precise design of appropriate tax reform measures varies substantially. Advice has repeatedly stressed, for instance, the need for substantial administrative reform in advance of VAT adoption. Sometimes addressing severe non-compliance is an overwhelming priority, leading to a focus on strengtheningenforcement actions before movingto medium-term reforms. And countries' idiosyncrasies affect the substance ofadvice. Substantial re-exportingin The Gambia, for instance, gave pause before recommending a VAT (given the difficulties of exporter 13Keenand Lockwood (2010). 14Chapter 4of Ebrill et al. (2001), and Aizenman and Jinjarak (2008). 15As forinstance inStewart and Jogarajan(2004) and Marshall (2009).
  • 14. 10 refunding, discussed below); and constitutional constraints have affected the design and implementation of effective VATs. Political and social views on the proper degree of progressivity vary widely, the traditional role of the external advisor then being to describe and assessalternatives. Box1.CommonElementsofStrategiesforReform Fund advice to developing countries has commonlystressed:  Establishing effective revenue administrations16 making proper use of withholding and third-party information, and capable of building on these to implement voluntary compliance and self-assessment—taxpayers calculatingand remittingtax themselves, subjectto auditandpenalties—bothas aprerequisite forexpandingthe tax base and tohelpaddresscorruption.  Assuring strong control of the largest taxpayers, in a dedicated office (and with specialized units for the most critical sectors), as a key step towards introducing risk assessmentandfullertaxpayer segmentation.  Implementing policies and procedures that limit opportunities for rent seeking and help identify and punish inappropriate behavior in the revenue administration.  Designing and applying forceful and efficient strategies to deal with non-compliance.  Ensuring that laws and regulations are reasonably simple, readily available, coherent across taxes, and provide good taxpayer protection (including effective appeals procedures).  Replacinginefficientproduction or sales taxes, after adequate preparation ofboth the administration and taxpayers, by a simple VAT—including to catalyze administrative reforms.  Levying a VAT on a broad base, with a high threshold (the level of turnover at which registering for the tax becomes compulsory) and avoiding multiple rates, to realize its potential as a reasonably efficientsource ofgovernmentfinance.  Coordinating any prospective loss of trade tax revenue with measures to replace it fromdomesticsources.  Avoiding exemptions—under all taxes—that jeopardize revenue and good governance, are hard to reverse, and generate no clearly offsetting social benefit.  Removing minor taxes and fees that are inordinately costly to comply with and administer.  Building CITs that are simple (in their depreciation and carry forward provisions, for instance) and sufficiently broad-based to allow statutory rates competitive by international standards, with effective tax rates that are reasonably low and uniform acrossinvestments. 16Thetermencompasses bothdomestictaxandcustoms administration.
  • 15. 11 Box1.CommonElementsofStrategiesforReform(continued)  Strengthening capacity to deal with profit-shifting by multinationals, while recognizing the extreme difficulty of doing so.  Extending the coverage of the PIT (particularly through inclusion of smaller businesses and professionals) and establishing coherent taxation ofcapital income, withan effective rate structure consistentwiththe authorities' distributional preferences.  Exploiting the potential for regional cooperation, in both policy and administration— particularly on business taxation and excises—to limit mutually damaging competition.  Balancing royalties, auctioning and profit-related charges in taxing natural resources. 9. Fund-supportedprogramsaremakingincreasinguseofstructuralrevenuemeasures aspartofgovernment-ownedstrategiestoincreaseeconomicgrowthandreducepoverty (Figure 1). These are often informed by TA advice, and might involve, for instance, the introduction of an LTO or removal of exemptions. There is evidence that IMF-supported programs can improve tax performance by inducing reforms requiring strong political commitment(Brunetal.,2010). Figure 1. Revenue-Related and Other Structural Benchmarks, 2002-10 250 200 150 100 50 0 200 2-03 Structural Benchmarks1 Total Fiscal Revenue 2 0 0 7 - 0 8 2009-10 Sourc e: MON
  • 16. A datab ase. 1Structural benchmarks can be legal, institutional or policy measures that are relevant for a program's macroeconomic objectives. e.g., Introduction of Tax Identification Number, Increase of VAT Threshold, Establishment of a Large Taxpayer Unit, Reduction/elimination of tax exemption.
  • 17. 12 C.TrendsandRecentExperience17 10. Revenuesinlower-incomecountries(especiallyLICs)showedresiliencethroughthe crisis. Figure 218 showsdevelopments since1980inthree measures ofgovernmentrevenue: total, excludinggrants from abroad, and—the focus in the bulk ofthis paper—tax revenue (including social security contributions). The narratives naturally differ, but the buoyancy of revenues in LICs in particular is apparent. Figure 2. Trends in Total and Tax Revenue, 1980-2009 (In percent of GDP) Government Revenue 45.0 40.0 35.0 30.0 25.0 20.0 15.0 10.0 5.0 0.0 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 Government Revenue, Excluding Grants 45.0 40.0 35.0 30.0 25.0 20.0 15.0 10.0 5.0 0.0 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 17The analysis in this paper draws ona mix of GFS, WEO and other data, from 1980on—an eclecticism that reflects limitations of available revenue data for developing countries. Appendix III provides detail. 18Figuresshowmedians(ratherthanmeans)tolimittheimpactofoutliersanddatagaps.'Dynamic'incomegroups areconstructedbyranking countries byincome per capitaat eachdate,and dividing themintofour equal-sized groups: this avoids biases fromclassifying countries by income at any single date (using final income per capita, for instance, could exclude strong revenue performers that migrate tothe LMIC group, giving an unduly pessimistic viewof LICs as a group). Averages and/or categorizing groups bytheir final incomes, however, gives broadly the same conclusions as follow.
  • 18. 13 Tax Revenue 40.0 35.0 30.0 25.0 20.0 15.0 10.0 5.0 0.0 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 Low in come Lo wer mid dle income Up per middlein come High income Source: IMF staff estimates. Note: Group medians and dynamic income groups. 11. Revenuesfromnaturalresourcesplayedanimportantroleintherelativelystrong performanceofrecentyears,butwerenottheonlyfactor. Dataonresource-relatedreceipts are poor, but they loom very large in the fiscal situations of many countries (Figure 3). Keen and Mansour (2010) find that, within sub-Saharan Africa, revenue has performed more strongly in resource-rich countries. Figure 4, however—comparing experiences in resource-rich and other countries more widely—shows not only the massively greater volatility of receipts in the former but also that tax ratioshave increasedoverrecentyears innon-resourcecountriestoo. Figure 3. Receipts from Natural Resources, averages 2000-07 (selected countries, percent of government revenues) Petroleum Minerals 100 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 Source: IMF staff calculations. Jordan Sierra Leone South Africa Peru Namibia Liberia Mongolia Gabon Colombia Mauritania Chile Guinea Papua New Guinea Russia Bolivia Ecuador Norway Indonesia Cameroon Chad Kazakhstan Vietnam Mexico São Tomé &… Trinidad and Tobago Syrian Arab… Botswana Turkmenistan Venezuela Sudan Azerbaijan Iran Qatar United Arab… Timor-Leste Algeria Yemen Saudi Arabia Congo, Republic of Bahrain Angola Liby a Equatorial Guinea Nigeria Kuwait Oman Iraq
  • 19. 3 5. 0 3 0. 0 2 5. 0 2 0. 0 1 5. 0 1 0. 0 5 . 0 0 . 0 1 4 Figure 4. Tax Revenue Developments in Resource-Rich and Other Countries,19 80-2009 (In percent of GDP) Non - Res ourc e Cou ntri es Resource Rich Countries 4 0 . 0 3 5 . 0 3 0 . 0 2 5 . 0 2 0 . 0 1 5 . 0 1 0 . 0 5 . 0
  • 20. 0.0 Source: IMF staff estimates . Note: Group medians and dynamic income groups; 'resource-rich' countries at each date are those with resource rents over 1 0 p e r c e n t o f G D P . 12. Therehasbeensomeincreaseinlower-incomecountries'taxrevenuessince the mid-1990s. Regional experiences differ (Box 2) but, followingstagnation or even decline, Figure 2 shows an increase in median performance. Comparing (LICs and LMICs) in 1990-95 and2003-08,Figure 6shows, morebroadly, amarkedincrease intaxratios.Over this period, five or so countries raised their tax ratios to above 15 percent. 13. Thesedevelopmentsintaxperformancereflectincreasedrevenuefromthe VAT, strongperformanceoftheCITanddecliningtradetaxrevenues (Figure7)—trends apparent sincethe early 1980s.
  • 21. 15 Box2.TheRegionalPerspective While the focus in this paper is on lower-incomecountries as a group, experiences have differed across regions. While sample size becomes more of a concern at finer disaggregation, Figure 5suggests, forinstance,that tax revenue performancehas strengthenedinsub-Saharan Africasincethe mid-1990'sbut weakenedindevelopingAsia. Figure 5. Tax Revenue Developments by Region, 1980-2009 Source: IMF staff calculations. Note: Group medians and (to ensure that the sample for one region is not affected by changes in the income classification of countries in other regions) fixed income groups. Figure 6. Distribution of the Tax Ratio in Developing Countries, 1990-95and2003-08 30 20 10 0 0 10 20 30 40 50 Tax revenue in percent of GDP Tax 1990-95 Tax 2003-08 Source: IMF staff calculations. Note: Sample composed of low - and lower middle-income countries, using dynamic income groups. Proportion of countries (percent)
  • 22. 16 Figure 7. Trends in the Composition of Revenues, 1980-2009 (In percent of GDP) VAT revenues have increased... ...and CIT receipts have been robust. 8 3.5 7 3.0 6 2.5 5 4 2.0 1980-1989 1980-1989 3 1.5 1990-1999 1990-1999 2 1.0 2000-2009 1 0.5 2000-2009 0 0.0 L o w inc o m e Lo wer mid dle inco me Upp er mid dle inco me H i g h i n c o m e L o w i n c o m e Lo wer midd le inco me Upp er midd le inco me High income The PIT is modest and flat... ... and trade tax receipts are in decline. 12 6 10 5 8 4 6 1980-1989 3 1980-1989 4 1990-1999 2 1990-1999 2 2000-2009 1 2000-2009 0 0 Low Lower Upper High Low Lower Upper High income middle middle income income middle middle income income income income income Source: IMF staff calculations. Note: Group medians and dynamic income groups. D.AssessingtheScopetoRaise MoreRevenue Percent GDP Percent GDP Percent GDP Percent GDP
  • 23. 14. Econometricworkhaslinkedrevenueperformance—theratioofactual revenuesto GDP—witharangeofstructural,developmentalandinstitutionalfeatures (AppendixIV). Many (such as the agricultural share, past political instability) are largely exogenous to tax decisions, especially in the very short-term. The impact ofresource wealth and aid on revenue performance inthis context has attracted particular attention (Box 3). Box3.Aid,ResourceWealth,andRevenue Mobilization Theempiricalevidenceonwhethersomekindsofaidmightdisplaceown revenuesis mixed. Over2001-06,aidinrecipientcountriesaveraged around4.4percentof GDP; in25 countries it exceeded half of all tax revenue. Such receipts could displace domestic revenue- raising by reducingimmediate needs and creatinga disincentive to strengthen performance for fear of offsetting reductions in future assistance. In practice, empirical findings vary. Gupta et al. (2004), for instance, find that grants displace domestic revenue (almost fully where corruption is high) while loans are associated with stronger domestic revenues. Reviewingthe evidence more widely, however, Moss, Petterson, and van de Walle (2006) stress the diversity of country experiences and empirical results. Better understandingof these links between foreign assistance and domestic revenues would help ensure that aid is provided in forms most supportive of developingcountries'owntax reformefforts.
  • 24. 17 Box3.Aid,ResourceWealth,andRevenueMobilization(continued) Therearestrongsignsthatoilrevenuesdisplaceowntaxation,andsomethatnon-oil resourcerevenuesdotoo. Bornhorstetal.(2009)findthatanincreaseinhydrocarbonrevenues of $1 displaces about 20 cents of non-hydrocarbon tax revenue. Results for sub-Saharan Africa19 suggest a similar effect for all forms of resource wealth. 15. Empiricalestimatessuggestthat'effort'—theratioofactualrevenuesto potential20—isnotlowinalldevelopingcountries,butthatsignificantadditionalrevenue couldberaisedwhereperformanceisweakest.AppendixVdescribesthemethodologyand reports—as illustrative of broad implications, not prescriptions—country-specific estimates of 'effort'(basedonPessinoandFenochietto,2010).Onaverage,effortisnolowerinLICs.21 Those with the lowest tax ratios, however, also tend to be those with the lowest effort. Of the 15 LICs and middle-income countries (LMICs) in the sample with tax ratios below 15 percent, for instance, 13 have estimated effort below their group median; raisingit to that level would increase their revenue by an average of about 3percent ofGDP. This leaves open,ofcourse, precisely how this can be done. Though details must be highly country-specific, the analysis in the next section gives a sense ofwhere the possibilities may lie. 16. Severalcountrieshaveshownthefeasibilityofsubstantiallyincreasingdomestic revenue mobilization.While some (suchas Egypt, Pakistan)show little movementintaxratios over extendedperiods,others have made impressive progress. Peru, forinstance,increasedits tax ratio from 6to 13percentoverthe 1990sandto around17percentnow.Somehave achieved sustained revenue increases of4-5 percent ofGDP overjust a few years. Appendix VI details three cases ofsubstantial progress: El Salvador, Tanzania, and Vietnam. III. ISSUES AND LESSONS 17. Thissectionconsiderscentralissuesofprincipleandlessonsofexperienceinnon- resourcetaxation.Taxingnaturalresourcesraisesmoredistinctandcomplexchallengesthan can adequately be addressed here: Appendix VII provides an overview.22 19Notreportedhere;usingthedatasetofKeenandMansour(2010). 20Theterms'performance'and'effort'areoftenusedsynonymously,butthedistinctionmadehere,duetoLotzand Morss(1967),provesuseful. 21Gupta(2007) reaches asimilar conclusion. 22Afuller treatment is in Daniel, Keen and McPherson (2010).
  • 25. 18 18. Itisexpositionallyconvenienttofocusinturnondistinctaspectsoftaxdesign—Box 4distillskeylessons—butaholisticperspectiveisalsoneeded.Fundamentalissuesof administrative reform overarch all (and so are dealt with first); more specific administrative challenges are discussed inrelation to the particular instruments then considered. Andthere are important design links between those policyinstruments. Perhaps most fundamentally, one theme underlying much ofthe followingdiscussion is that pressures on revenue from trade liberalization,regional integration and tax competition mean that, absent greater international coordination, the search for additional revenue will likely focus on relatively immobile bases— most obviously labor,consumption,andreal estate. Box4.KeyChallengesforTaxReform Prioritiesvarywithcountrycircumstances,butseverallessonsemerge. Relativetokey elements of the reform strategies setoutinBox1,inmanycases:  Progress has been made in administrative reforms, but more onbasic organizational structures than indevelopingandapplyingrisk-management,andgovernanceproblems remainextensive;  The VAT still has more obvious revenue potential than most other instruments, but realizing this requires expanding the base—by both policy change and improving compliance—ratherthanincreasingstandardrates;  More systematic attention needs to be given to replacing revenue lost from trade liberalization;  Incentives, including in free trade zones, continue to undermine revenue from CIT, which is any event likely to come under continued pressure from globalization in coming years;  Profit-shifting by multinationals is an increasing concern; strengthening capacity and legislative frameworks is important, but, absent fundamental changes in international tax policies,there are noeasysolutions;  The PIT will likely remain poorly developed for some time, but movement to explicitly, and coherent,schedular structures can improve effectiveness andfairness;  High-income individuals can be taxed more effectively by removing opportunities for avoidanceandstrengtheningdetectionandenforcement;  Establishing streamlined tax regimes for small businesses, and extending to them the methods of taxpayer segmentation, is unlikely to yield significant short-term revenue gains but is important for the longer-term development and perceived legitimacy ofthe taxsystem;  Muchremainsto be doneto make taxexpenditure analysis routine;  Capacity in tax policy analysis is often very weak, and a significant hindrance to better designandownership;
  • 26. 19 Box4.KeyChallengesforTaxReform(continued)   1 9. Greater transparency and consultation on tax matters—not least, improvingthe effectiveness and visibility of public spending it finances—can promote the trust on which voluntary tax compliance rests; and Sustained political commitment from the highest level is essential for deep reform, which needs then to be entrenched to prevent backsliding. A. Core Administration Reforms23 Improving revenue administration is essential for enhanced and fairer revenue mobilizationandforwidergovernanceimprovement;thoughsuccessishardto evaluate. It maybetoomuchtoassertthat"indevelopingcountries,taxadministration is taxpolicy" (Casanegra de Jantscher, 1990): tax policysets the framework within which the revenue administration must operate. In practice, the distinction between administration and policy is oftenhard(andpointless) to make.Butthere isnodoubtthat weakandoften corruptrevenue administration remains a fundamental barrier to effective and fair taxation, and to building wider trust between governmentand citizens. Key indicators—tax gaps, audit recovery rates and the levelandpattern ofarrears—can saymuchaboutthe performanceoftax administrations: developingthe capacity to monitor and analyzing these, indeed,is a central reform aim. Evaluating the impact of administrative reforms on revenue itself, however, can be especially difficult, since they take time, are complex, and rarely lend themselves to experiment-type evaluation.Inthisrespect,assessmentsaretosomedegree judgmental.
  • 27. Accomplishments andtrends 20. Developingcountrieshaveimplementedwiderangingadministration reforms— moreearnestlysincetheearly1990s—butwithmixedsuccess. Somehavemade impressive advances (Mozambique, Peru, Rwanda, Tanzania, and Vietnam, for instance); others very little, reflecting conflict or governance issues (DRC, Haiti, Nicaragua, Sierra Leone). Sometimes progress has been followed by stagnation ordecline (Guatemala, Honduras, Zambia), sometimes by a resurgence (Bolivia, Ghana, Uganda). There is no single formula for assuring major administrative improvement, but experience points to some key elements. 21. Manymajororganizationalchangeshaveprovedconstructive,thoughthere have alsobeen mistakes. Keyimprovements include movingaway fromduplicative andnarrowly focused tax-by-tax approaches by implementingfunction-based organizational structures, establishing headquarters organizations to guide them, and integratingdomestic direct and indirect tax management. Less successful—because less appropriate given their different tasks— 23Detailedregional assessments are in Crandall and Bodin(2005), Kloeden (forthcoming), and Zake (forthcoming).
  • 28. 20 havebeenattemptstomergeoperational(asopposedtomanagerial)taxandcustoms administrationprocesses (Zimbabwe). 22. Revenueauthorities(RAs)havenotalwaysliveduptothehighexpectationsheldby some,but,withpoliticalwill,canprovideaframeworkforsustainedprogress. Thecreation ofRAs has beenawidely-notedinnovationoverthe last 10-15years (theyare nowalmost ubiquitous, for instance, in Anglophone Africa), and the Fund has supported countries that have chosen this path. RAs differ greatly, the essential beinga semi-autonomous status intendedto protect against political interference,give independencein operations and HR management, and enable flexibility in budgeting and operations. The high hopes sometimes expressed have not, however, been fully realized (Kidd and Crandall, 2006; Kloeden, forthcoming). The (mostly anecdotal) evidenceis that managerial and staff capacity and practice often have improved (many examples in Latin America, Eastern and Southern Africa, Ghana, and The Gambia). But the disruption of instituting an RA often delayed reforming core tax administration functions: the integration of direct and indirect tax administration is only now getting underway in Anglophone Africa, for instance. And even substantial increases leave salaries dwarfed by the potential gain from corruption. As RAs now spread further, including with heightened interest in Francophone Africa, it is important to recognize that the aim of reform is to improve core administration functions, not just the vehicle for their delivery. 23. Segmentingthetaxpayerpopulationhasenabledabetterallocationof administrativeresourcesandfacilitatedrisk-managementapproachestocompliance. Large, medium, small, and micro taxpayers offer very different revenue possibilities and compliance concerns. As noted above, the needfor focused attention on large taxpayers is now nearly universally accepted: given the highly skewed size distribution of firms, controlling the largestenterprises(usuallyafewhundredorthousand),cansecure60-80percentofdomestic taxes (more, in island economies). Securing prompt and appropriate tax payment from resource companies, financial institutions and telecom operators is a prerequisite for effective revenue- raising. While Africa trailed earlier adopters in Latin America (Argentina, Peru, and Uruguay), and the absence ofintegrated administration rendered some early efforts ineffective (Egypt, Kenya, and Uganda), an LTO is now the norm [though gaps remains, as in SACU (except South Africa)]. LTOs have accomplished much (Baer, 2002) and can likely do more: in resource taxation, for instance (as is beginning in Ghana, Uganda, and Mongolia), and by developing specialist units to deal with high wealth individuals. Their very effectiveness, however, can create difficulty: the ease of collecting from large firms may lead governments to disadvantage smaller companies (Auriol and Warlters, 2005), and the focus can distort competition and be perceived as unfair (factors contributing to the disbandmentof Uganda's first LTO). The natural next step is to deliver similarly high-quality services and compliance enforcement to non-large taxpayers, with medium taxpayer offices emerging (in Indonesia and Francophone Africa) and some innovative small taxpayer approaches (Tanzania, and small taxpayer offices in Algeria and some Francophone African countries). 24. Improvedbusinessprocesses,builtoneffectiveITsystems,arecritical,butfailures havebeentoocommon. Betterprocessescanreducecompliancecostsandfacilitateself-
  • 29. 21 assessment by simplifying taxpayer registration, filing and payment, audit, collection enforcement,andappeals. Automationofroutinetasks, and,sincethe mid-2000s, the emergence of linkages between tax and customs IT applications, have also increased effectiveness. Less progress has beenmadeinrelationtoexpost controls(audit,enforcement,appeals). IT systems in developingcountries(whetherhome-grown orpackages) are often inadequate,withmany disappointing examples and far fewer moderately successful ones (as in Colombia, Peru, Rwanda, Tanzania). Poorresults can arise from inadequate linkages with a broader reform strategy (perhaps being designed with only an isolated objective—administering the VAT, for instance—in mind, or with insufficient attention to restructuring basic processes), or conversely, from excessive ambition. High failure rates and costs in going alone on computerization could be mitigated through regional cooperation: the possibilities of this are emerging in East Africa, and through customs harmonization efforts in Central America. 25. Simplifyingtaxlawsandadoptingtaxprocedurecodes(TPCs)caneaseboth administrationand compliance.Harmonizingacross taxes andsimplifyingkeyadministrative provisions facilitates administration and compliance. TPCs are not always effective, whether because ofan absenceofaccompanyingmeasures(Paraguay) orhesitationto impose the strictest penalties. Wheretheyare,however,theyhave strengthenedadministrative powersof investigation and arrears collection, while protecting taxpayer rights. Challengesahead 26. Compliancecostsremainhighinmanydevelopingcountries.Forthetypicalfirmof the Doing Business exercise, time spent preparing and paying taxes exceeds 300 hours in developing countries, compared to under 210 for high-income countries. In the East African corridor Mombasa-Kigali, customs' handlingcosts per import containerby road are $0.13 per km, compared to $0.05 per km along the Danang-Tak corridor in Asia (CPCS Transcom, 2010). 27. Revenueadministrationsoftensufferfromunder-resourcing,misallocation,and weakmid-levelskills.Revenueadministrationsneedassuranceofadequateresourcing,though rigid and legislatively-mandated financing by a fixed percentage of collections (such as the 3 percentin Ghana) has often failed in its intentionto motivate stronger performance. Such resources as they have, moreover, needto be carefully deployed, avoidingfads (particularly technological) and distractions (excessive focus on minor non-tax revenues). Mid-level managerial and technical skills (though noticeably improved in Latin America) are often weak. Comprehensive skill studies to identify tax gaps, compliance trends, and needed improvements are rare, resultingin poor taxpayer services and inadequate orinappropriate interventions (includingharassment). 28. Coordinationbetweendomestictaxandcustomsadministrationsisgenerallypoor. Tax and customs administrations—and reforms to each—needto be closely coordinated. Economic activity straddles both domains, and customs has a critical role in managing VAT on
  • 30. 22 international trade: half or more of gross VAT revenue in developing countries is collected by customs.24 Coordination,which can enable a more complete view ofeach taxpayer, is often weak: information on VAT collected on imports and zero-rated exports needs to flow from customs to tax administration for automatic cross-checking against VAT returns to identify anomalies and high-risk cases for audit consideration.Transactional customs and tax data provides opportunities for trend analysis by customs and tax managers to collaboratively and jointly (particularly within the framework of RA) develop compliance models and response strategies. All too often these opportunities remain underexploited. 29. Addressingtheseconcerns,andstrengtheningthelegitimacyofthetaxsystem, requiresimprovingcompliancemanagement—dealingwiththe"hard-to-tax"—inparallel withconsolidatinggoodtaxadministrationfundamentals. Beyondthefundamentals— functionally structured organizations, taxpayer focus, self-assessment, simple IT-supported processes, ethicalandcompetentmanagers andstaff—is the needforclearstrategies to address the most non-compliant businesses and individuals. Keyelements include: understanding the nature of the taxpayer/trader population; identifying key compliance risks and how they arise (from weak laws and regulations, for instance, or administrative incapacity?); clarity on accountability for, and adequate resourcing of, compliance activities; and specifying performance indicators and potential corrective actions. 30. Addressingnon-complianceultimatelyrequiresthehardworkofroutine administration. Shortcuts often prove illusory. Amnesty schemes offeringwaiver oftax, interest andpenalties,oftenwith'noquestionsasked,'canunderminecompliancebycreating expectations of more to come and doing a keenly-felt injustice to the compliant (Baer and Le Borgne, 2008). Limited voluntary disclosure programs, on the other hand, intended to achieve enduring tax compliance by partial waiver of penalties accompanied by strong enforcement action, can prove helpful. Other schemes that have proved problematic include requiring tax certificates for access to contract or bank accounts, which can simply invite forgery; and lottery schemes rewarding those holding VAT invoices, or allowing deduction against PIT of some itemsbackedbyinvoice(intendedtoensure that these are issued),whichcanresult intax administrations being presented with bags of invoices to sift through and verify. Some simple measures canhelp:requiringlarge payments to go through bankingsystem, forinstance,can provide useful information. But what is key is a program of routine but targeted and thoughtful intervention:Russell (2010), for instance, sets out a range of practical measures to address non- compliance by small businesses. Registration programs (increasing unannounced visits to market) and follow-upofstopfilingare criticaltofinding'ghosts'—those (apparently) unknown to the tax administration—while education and welcoming taxpayer services, together with wider intelligence operations, are crucial for all aspects of compliance. 24Table 4.3 of Ebrill et al. (2001).
  • 31. 23 31. Progresscanbemadeinaddressingcorruption.Itrequiresstrongleadership(political and managerial), institutional measures—strong and proactive internal audit and staff investigation functions, visible implementation of a code of ethics (including prosecutions)—and processes that limit rent-seekingopportunities (minimizingcontact between taxpayers and tax officials). The Uganda Revenue Authority is an example of how (by, for instance, forceful measures to purge staff and re-hire, with zero tolerance forcorruption)a once poorly-perceived institution is now cited as a model. 32. Successfuladministrativereformrequiressustainedpoliticalwillasmuchas technicalcapacity.Asoundreformstrategy,technicalunderstandingandadequatehuman resources are essential, of course, but so too is political commitment—from the highest levels and over substantial periods oftime—to overcomeresistance (not least from the revenue administration itself), ensure effective application of the laws, assure funding, and drive through complementary legal and tax policy changes. Where this has been present (in Peru, Ecuador, Guatemala, and Rwanda, for instance), progress can be substantial; where it is not, it will be minimal. A holistic approach is also needed: partial approaches often disappoint, as the potential revenue gain from investments in administrative improvementcan be offset by base-narrowing exemptions(asperhapsinUganda). B. The Value-Added Tax (VAT) 33. MostdevelopingcountrieshavenowdevelopedaVAT. Sincetheearly1990s,the VAT has spread rapidly beyond advanced economies (Figure 8). Though not ubiquitous, it has becomethe normandcontinuesto spread(The GambiaandSyria,forinstance,plan introduction, and it is also under consideration in the Gulf Cooperation Council). The Fund has been active in its promotion,25 and VAT adoption and implementation continue to be a significant part of its TA. 25The probability of adoption is significantly relatedtoparticipation ina Fund-supported program (Keen and Lockwood,2010).
  • 32. 24 Figure 8. The Spread of the VAT, 1980-2009 140 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2009 High Income Other Countries Source: IMF data. Note: Figure shows the number of countries with a VAT at each date. 34. Fundadvice—largelyfollowed—favorsabroadbase,singlerateandfairlyhigh threshold.26 These prescriptions (widely shared by others advisingin this area)27 aim to realize the core potential merits of the VAT: raising significant amounts of revenue in a way that does less damage to economic activity than alternatives, supports equity objectives, and is relatively simple to administer and comply with. They do not mean no exemptions:28 some (for financial serviceschargedforas a margin,governmentagencies,basic health andeducation)are common to most VATs, often on technical (though increasingly challenged) grounds. Others (for staple foodstuffs) are driven by political and distributional sensitivities. A relatively high threshold excludes traders with little revenue potential relative to the administration and compliance costs involved. IMF (2000) found these prescriptions have been widely followed, except perhaps in relation to the threshold: a single rate is much more common in LICs, for instance, than in higher income countries (Table 1),29 though there are signs of pressure: the WAEMU VAT directive, for example,hasbeenamendedtoallowasecondrate. 26Ebrill et al. (2001). 27Suchas Birdand Gendron(2007). Theory[arecent reviewis byCrawford, Keen, and Smith(2010)], suggeststhat rate differentiation canplay a useful role ineasing distortions tomarket participationand (especially where better targetedinstruments areweak) pursuing distributional objectives.Inpractice, however, it ishardtoidentify desirable forms of differentiation (beyond those handled by excises), while differentiation is costlytoadminister and comply with,and opens the doortospecial pleading. 28'Exemption'meanssalesarenottaxed,but(unlike'zero-rating')taxoninputsisnotrefunded.Fundadvice generally resists zero-rating other thanfor exports because of the difficultyof controlling refunds. 29This partly reflects the greater age of VATs inhigher income countries: most new VATs have beensingle rate. Number of countries
  • 33. 25 Table 1. VAT Features by Income Group Number of Average VAT C-efficiency Income Class strictly positive Rate VAT rates Low-Income 16 1.28 38.0 Lower Middle-Income 13 1.94 46.6 Upper Middle-Income 15 1.90 51.6 High-Income 20 2.52 55.6 Source: IMF staff calculations. Note: Rates as at end -2010; C-efficiency (the ratio of VAT revenue to the product of the standard VAT rate and consumption), discussed below, as at 2005 (for reasons of sample size). 35. TheVAThasestablisheditselfasarobustsourceofrevenue,withsignsthatithas provedarelativelyefficientinstrument. It typicallyaccountsforaroundone-quarterofalltax revenue; and no country has ever removed a VAT without subsequently reintroducing it. Keen and Lockwood (2010) find that countries with a VAT generally raise more revenue than those without, all else equal, though the likely gain varies with countries' openness and income levels (being less, for instance, in smaller countries, presumably because tariffs are then an easy revenuesource,andperhaps lowerinsub-Saharan Africathan elsewhere). 36. Closeanalysescommonlyreachfairlybenignconclusionsonthedistributional impactoftheVAT,butmorecanbedonetoidentifyspecificspendingmeasurestoallay concerns. A proportional tax onall consumption is regressive relative to annual income,but this effect is mitigated by the common exemption of sensitive food and other items and (less noted) by the operationofthe threshold: the latter eitherconfersacompetitiveadvantage onsmallerand presumably less well-off retailers and service providers or enables their customers, likely amongst the poorer,adefacto exemption(Jenkins,Jenkins,andKuo,2006).The reachofthe tax is also less in poorer rural regions than in urban centers. Reviewing the evidence, Bird and Gendron (2007) find the VAT to be generally mildly progressive or mildly regressive. Assessing the distributional impact of any tax requires, however, comparing it with some alternative. One possibility is that it replaces other revenue sources: Zolt and Bird (2005) conclude "the evidence is...that the VAT is likely on the whole to be less regressive than the trade and excise taxes it has replaced. Furthermore, inat least some developingcountries, the VAT may be about as progressive as the income tax." Alternatively, if the VAT finances increased expenditure then the final distributional outcome can be progressive even with a broad-based, single rate VAT: the benefitof preferential rates/exemptionsgoes mainlyto the betteroff(sincetheyspendmoreon all items), so that the poorcan benefit from their elimination and use of the additional tax revenue to financetargetedspendingmeasures (Box5). The effectivenessofthe targeting instruments available is critical, but even the relatively blunt instruments available to developing countries can achieve much: Munozand Cho (2004), forinstance, using microdata to look at the combined tax-spending of a VAT in Ethiopia, find basic health spending to have a particularly strongeffect.Itremainsthecase,nonetheless,thatprecisemeasurestoaddressanyequity
  • 34. 26 concerns from proposed tax reforms—alleviating poverty is of course in itself a primary reason to impose these taxes—are oftenleft unspecified. Box5.TheDistributionalImpactofExemptionsandReducedRates Reduced rates on (or exemption of) items particularly important to the poor are inherently limited as distributional devices: even if the poor spend a larger proportion of their income on some item, the better offmay spend absolutely more (Sah, 1983; and Ebrill et al., 2001). The practical importance of this recurs in TA and other work: Figure 9 shows how the bulk of the subsidy implicit in domestic zero-rating in Mexico accrues to the better-off. The question theniswhetherspendinginstruments candoa betterjobofprotectingthe poor. The Ethiopiacase studysuggests that evenwhere spendinginstruments are quite weak,rate differentiation can be an inferior policy, and similar results have been found, for instance, for the Philippines(Newhouse andZakharova,2007).It remainsthe case,however,that the equity case for rate differentiation is generally stronger in developing countries than in advanced economies. Whether rate differentiation is desirable in any specific context dependsonthegovernment'sequityobjectivesandthepreciseinstrumentsavailabletoitfor protectingthepoor. Figure 9. Benefits from Zero-Rating Relative to Income Shares, Mexico (by income decile) 25 20 15 10 5 0 I II III IV V VI VII VIII IX X Percent of total subsidy Percent of income Source: OECD 2007. 37. Anytaxencouragesinformality,butaVATmaybelessharmfulthanalternatives. A higher rate of VAT tends to increase informality, so the rate should be lower where informality is a greater concern. But other tax instruments, such as an income tax, also spur informality, and the VAT offers some advantages: if a trader's customers are registered for VAT,
  • 35. 27 it is advantageous forthem to register too.30 But 'bad' VAT chains can also form: ifa trader's customer are notregistered,betterforthem notto register either(de Paula andScheinkman, 2006). It has also been argued that the VAT may deal with informality less effectively than tariffs, because unregistered traders will at least pay tariffs on their imports (Emran and Stiglitz, 2005). This though can be overstated: unregistered operators will incur unrecovered input VAT on imports just as they incur customs duty31 and, unlike tariffs, the VAT also reaches informal operators on their purchases from compliant domestic firms.32 38. VATintroductioncancatalyzeimprovementsintaxadministration, byusingthe VAT threshold for taxpayer segmentation (see Section G), introducing self-assessment and spurring implementation of functionally-organized tax administrations and IT reform. 39. FlaweddesignandimplementationunderminestheeffectivenessoftheVATin manydevelopingcountries—withrefundsaparticularproblem. Commondifficulties include: low (sometimes, as in Nigeria, zero) thresholds (pressurizing tax administrations and diverting attention from higher value and riskier taxpayers); extensive exemptions and zero- rating (creating classification disputes and increasing compliance costs); inadequate preparations and public sensitization (making resistance more likely); and piecemeal implementation (as previously in Yemen, for instance). Refunding exporters requires balancing the risk of fraud against that of turning the VAT into a de facto export tax. This challenges all tax administrations, but significant and sometimes corrupt delays in refunding legitimate claims are commonplace in developing countries, and a major business complaint. Developing effective refunding procedures is time-consuming and difficult, but crucial: ITD (2005) and Harrison (2008) elaborateonhowitcanbedone. 40. ThesedifficultiesarereflectedinrelativelylowrevenueproductivityoftheVATin developingcountries—pointingtopotentiallysignificantrevenuegainsfrombase- broadening. Standard rates ofVAT rates are already quite high in manydevelopingcountries (Table 1),33 and further increases may pose a particularly heavy risk of worsening compliance. But that is notthe onlyoptionfor increasing revenue, as emerges from consideringonecommon measureoftheeffectivenessofaVAT:its'C-efficiency,'theratioofrevenuetotheproductof the standard rate and consumption.This would take the value of100 under a single rate VAT on a broad base,but willbelowerto the extentthat reducedrates apply andcomplianceis 30This is because by registering for VAT a trader canrecover taxon their own inputs while their customer receives acreditforthetaxtheyarethencharged. 31Import VATis not subject toany threshold. 32Keen (2009) reviews the tariffs vs. VAT controversy; Stiglitz (2010) sets out other criticisms of the VAT. 33Insome cases, however, thereisriskof introducing aVATat solowarate—under5percent, say—that it is questionable whetherthe effort is worthwhile.
  • 36. 28 imperfect.34 In LICs, for instance, median C-efficiency is only about 36 percent (Table 1 above). In countries where it is less, raisingit to that level—without changing the standard rate, but by some combination ofbase-broadeningand improvingcompliance—could raise, onaverage, nearly 2 percent of GDP (Appendix VIII). Indeed a long-term objective, given sufficient base- broadening and improved compliance, could even be lower standard VAT rates. 41. TheVAT iswork in progress. Adoptionisanatural focusofattention,andrevenue commonly performs well in its immediate aftermath. But much—more than often realized— remains to be done thereafter to develop the audit and other capacities an effective VAT requires: Appendix IX recounts the experience of Zambia, illustrating the need for continued nurturing of the VAT. C.TradeLiberalizationandCustomsAdministration 42. Tradetaxrevenues,stillimportanttomanydevelopingcountries,aresettocontinue todecline. Relative to bothGDP andtotal revenue,trade taxes have beenintrenddeclinefor thirty years, tracking a decline in collected tariff rates (revenues relative to imports): Figure 10. Further liberalization (including through regional agreements and bilateral agreements with the EU and others), some alreadyprogrammedintoagreements inforce,meanthat the trendwill continue. While the efficiency and growth implications of this are welcome, the fiscal challenges can be significant: in sub-Saharan Africa, for instance, trade taxes still account for one-quarter of alltaxrevenue. Figure 10. Developments in Trade Tax Revenue and Collected Tariff Rates, 1980-2009 Low-Income Countries 45 5 40 4.5 35 4 30 3.5 25 32.5 20 2 15 1.5 10 1 5 0.5 0 0 1980 1984 1988 1992 1996 2000 2004 2008 34Care is needed, however, since some poorVATpractices—suchas afailure torefund exporters, orexemptionof intermediate products—lead tohigh C-efficiency; Ebrill et al. (2001): discuss these and other limitations of the concept.
  • 37. 29 Lower Middle-Income Countries 40 6 35 5 30 25 4 20 3 15 2 10 5 1 0 0 1980 1984 1988 1992 1996 2000 2004 2008 Source: IMF staff calculations. Note: Group medians and dynamic income groups; left hand scale differs between panels. 43. Replacingtradetaxrevenuesfromdomesticsourceshasprovedproblematicin some LICs. Most middle-income countries have readily recovered revenue from domestic sources(Figure 11; andBaunsgaard andKeen,2010).The same has notbeentrue ofLICs throughout the sample period[though sub-Saharan Africa may inthis respect have performed better than otherregions(KeenandMansour,2010)].The markeddeclineintrade tax revenues means that slow progress inoverall tax ratios may mask a constructive rebalancing. Figure 11. Developments in Tax Revenue and Trade Tax Revenue, 1980-2009 Low-Income Countries 16 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 1980-1984 1985-1989 1990-1994 1994-1999 2000-2004 2005-2009 Percent GDP
  • 38. 30 Lower Middle-Income Countries 25 20 15 10 5 0 1980-1984 1985-1989 1990-1994 1994-1999 2000-2004 2005-2009 Upper Middle-Income Countries 25 20 15 10 5 0 1980-1984 1985-1989 1990-1994 1994-1999 2000-2004 2005-2009 Tax Revenue Trade Revenue Source: IMF staff calculations. Note: Group averages and fixed income groups. 44. Revenuechallengesfromtradeliberalizationwillcontinue.TherearesignsinFigure 10thatrevenuereplacementhasbeenmorecompletesincethemid-1990s,buttherearealso intensified challenges ahead. The standard policy prescription for recovery is to combine tariff reduction with increased consumption taxes (exactly matching tariff reductions on excisable products, for instance, with higher excises),35 and the analysis above suggests further roomfor this without an increase in standard VAT rates—already high in many developing countries (Table 1)—that may pose a particularly heavy risk of worsening compliance. Countries with a VAT, however, have not been systematically more successful in replacing lost trade tax revenue (Baunsgaard and Keen,2010), and the case studies in IMF (2005) suggest that successful replacementhas beenassociatedwithusingarange ofinstruments, includingthe incometax. While there is thus nosimple recipe for success, failure to quantify and prepare for the revenue impact of trade reforms has in some cases amplified the difficulties. In Lebanon and Mozambique, in contrast, introduction of an effective VAT was carefully coordinated with trade reform. 35This preserves the efficiency gain from the reform, widens the taxbase (by including domestic productionalong withimports)and canleave consumer prices lower (Keenand Ligthart,2002). Emran and Stiglitz (2005) stress that informalitycaninvalidatetheargument (becausenot all domesticconsumptioncanthenbetaxed), thoughtheresult continues to apply if an appropriate withholding taxis applied toimports (Keen, 2008). Percent GDP Percent GDP
  • 39. 31 45. Institutionalcapacityincustomsadministrationremainsparticularlyweakinmost lower-incomecountries. Manymiddle-incomecountrieshavebeenpursuingcomprehensive reform programs that advance the modernization agenda,36 includingby implementing modernized customs codes aligned with the Kyoto convention;37 replacing universal pre-release inspection by risk-based, selective post-release audits; adopting HR reforms centered on the introduction of career systems and codes of ethics for staff; using non-intrusive verification techniques; implementingsingle-windowsystems fortrade;andimplementingWCO 'SAFE' guidelines38 (to address security concerns while pursuing trade facilitation). Progress in many low-income countries, however, has proved much harder, with limited progress, for instance, in the Kyoto convention.There have been rewardingmultiyear reform strategies supported by carefully-planned TA (Mozambique, Nepal), but for the most part customs administration reform results have been disappointing. Limited resources, lack of long-term commitment and overall limitations in the institutional capacity of the civil service in most LICs are the key challenges. 46. Manycustomsadministrationsstillstruggletocontrolrent-seeking,andregional integrationcanraisefurtherchallenges. Progressinimplementingintegrity-enhancing measures (suchas adequate salaries andworkingconditions,managementcontrolsystems, computer systems to streamline procedures and minimize face-to-face contacts, and accreditation of customs brokers and importers) remains patchy. Regional integration also poses distinct problems. Shifting fiscal control from national to regional borders requires new ways to collect import VAT and certify export-related refund claims, and potentially new policy frameworks to deal with intra-regional transactions—issues with which the EU is still struggling, and which can pose even greaterchallengesfordevelopingcountries. D.PersonalIncomeTaxation 47. ReceiptsfromthePITarelowandstagnantindevelopingcountries,andcome almostentirelyfromwagewithholdingonlargeenterprisesandpublicsectoremployees. Since the early 1980s, the PIT has raised 1-3 percent ofGDP indevelopingcountries, compared to 9-11 percentindeveloped(Peter,ButtrickandDuncan2010).Upto 95percentcomesfrom wage withholding by the public sector and large firms, compared to about 80 percent in developed countries. Less than 5 percent of the population pay PIT (compared to nearly 50 percentin developed),andonlyabout15percentofincomeisreached(comparedto 57percent): Modietal. (1987). 36Described indetail inKeen (2003). 37See http://www.wcoomd.org/home_pfoverviewboxes_tools_and_instruments_pfrevisedkyotoconv.htm 38http://www.wcoomd.org/home_cboverviewboxes_valelearningoncustomsvaluation_epsafeframework.htm
  • 40. 32 48. TopstatutoryratesofPIThavebeencut,andratestructuressimplified,butwithno discerniblebehavioralimpact. Thesecutsarelikelytohavebeendriven,tosomedegree,by reductions in CIT rates: absent matchingcuts in top PIT rates, these can invite avoidance by incorporation. They affect even fewer taxpayers in developing countries than in advanced.39 Thresholds vary widely; raising them could enable a better focus on high-income individuals, though the revenueloss can be non-trivial. 49. AnemergingconcernisthemandatingofuniversalfilingforallPITtaxpayers to inculcate greater appreciation of the tax system and in the expectation that additional income will be declared. In Kenya, for instance, processing the additional returns has significantly increased workloads but collection and compliance outcomes have disappointed. The impact on taxpayer awareness may have actually been harmful as taxpayers see that non-filing and under-declaration goesundetected. 50. Evasionandavoidancebyhigh-incomeindividuals,rangingfromlegaluseoftax preferencestoillegaluseoflowtaxjurisdictions,couldbeaddressedmoreforcefully. These activities take a variety of forms, some purely domestic (concealing income, exploiting preferential treatments), some international (notdeclaring incomefrom abroad). They are inevitably hard to quantify: for the latter, one estimate is that about $50 billion of tax revenue is foregone annually in developing countries (Tax Justice Network, 2005). Whatever the precise amount, there islittle doubt that the sums are large—and,moreover,that failure ofelites to pay a fair share of taxes undermines support for the wider tax system. Raising substantially more from such groups, often influential and intimidating, is hard. At a minimum, appropriate legal provisions are needed: exemptions for agricultural income,for instance, can pander to the powerful, and in some countries personal incomefrom abroad is simply exempt. Real estate taxes can be a powerful tool for reaching the better off. Dedicating units within the tax administration to high-income/wealth individuals can provide a focus for enforcement efforts, with high profile prison terms sending a salutary lesson. Strong audit power, including the possibility to use indirect methods to assess tax liabilities, is an effective tool for increasing the effectiveness ofaudit operations: these enable revenue agencies to use third party information, particularly relatedto assets andflow ofinvestments, toestimate the taxpayer's income(Biber, 2010). Collective action on abuse through tax havens, as with the work of the Global Forum on Transparency and Exchange of Information for Tax Purposes, can benefit developing countries. 51. 'Global'PITshaveprovedespeciallyhardtoimplementinlowerincome countries—explicitlyschedularsystems,withcoherenttreatmentofcapitalincome,can offerimprovement. Onpaper,mostdevelopingcountrieshavea'global'incometax—a 39The topPITbracket startsat about 18times percapitaincome inupper middle-income countries,and 83times in LICs (Peter, Buttrick, and Duncan, 2010). Lee and Gordon(2005) find no growthimpact fromthe topPITrate.
  • 41. 33 progressive charge on the sum of income from all sources40—and building such income taxes was a focus ofmuch advice through the 1970s.41 The low yield, narrow base, and accumulated structuralincoherenciesofthesetaxesmean,however,thatthisapproachhasfailed:"....inmost developingcountries, the global progressive personal incometax long advocated by experts is…neitherglobalorprogressive,norpersonal,notoftenevenonincome"(ZoltandBird,2005). In practice, many lower income countries have schedular systems—taxing different types of income separately. The theoretical merit of the global approach has itself been more widely challenged in recent years (it may, for instance, simply be unrealistic, given their differing international mobility, to apply the same top marginal rate to capital as to labor income). Several advancedcountrieshavemovedtowardsaparticularformofschedulartaxation,the'dual income tax' (DIT): applying a progressive tax to labor incomebut a lower (and, critically, uniform) rate to capital income. Whatever view is taken of this as a long-term objective in personal income taxation, movement towards explicit and more coherent schedular taxation— with limited discrimination between different types of capital income—can be a practical option towards greater effectiveness.42 It can limit avoidance opportunities that arise through relabeling capital income,43 and ease both administration and compliance, especially where capital income is taxed at a flat rate (tax then being implementable largely by final withholding). Importantly, the 'Achillesheel' ofthe DIT inadvancedeconomies—the ability ofsmallercompaniesto reclassify labor as capital income (or vice versa)—is less troubling in developing countries given the difficulty of subjecting them to any reasonable tax at all. E. Taxing Corporations 52. CITrevenues—moreimportanttodevelopingthanadvancedeconomies—face pressuresfromglobalization,buthaveasyetprovedreasonablyrobust. Figure12shows developments inCIT rates andrevenuebyincomeclass. Statutory rates have tumbled worldwide, though remaining somewhat higher in lower income countries.44 The revenue challenges that suchdownwardpressures couldpose are agreaterconcernfordevelopingthan advanced economies:the CIT raises about 17percentoftotal tax inthe former,comparedto 10 percent (pre-crisis) in the OECD. In practice, CIT revenue in all income groups has performed strongly in the face of rate reductions (at least until the crisis, in high-income countries),45 40Or,insomeFrancophonecountries,a'complementary'incometax:aprogressivetaxonthesumofnetincomes fromsources towhichdistinct schedular taxesapply. 41SeeforinstanceGoode(1993). 42Others have reacheda similar conclusion: Almand Wallace (2002), Zolt and Bird(2005). 43As tax-preferredcapital gains, forinstance. 44This mayinsomecasesreflecttheuseoftheCITtoextract resourcerents,absent bettertargetedinstruments. 45This does not imply any causality inthe relationship.
  • 42. 34 Figure 12. Developments in Corporate Tax Rates and Revenues, 1980-2009 Low-Income Countries 2.50 60 50 2.00 40 1.50 30 1.00 20 0.50 10 0.00 0 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 Corporate Tax Revenue (% GDP) Corporate Tax Rate (Right Axis) Lower Middle-Income Countries 4.00 45 3.50 40 3.00 35 30 2.50 25 2.00 20 1.50 15 1.00 10 0.50 5 0.00 0 1 9 8 0 1 9 8 2 1 9 8 4 1 9 8 6 1 9 8 8 1 9 9 0 1 9 9 2 1 9 9 4 1 9 9 6 1 9 9 8 2 0 0 0 2 0 0 2 2 0 0 4 2 0 0 6 2 0 0 8 Corporate Tax Revenue (%GDP) Corporate Tax Rate (Righ Axis) Upper Middle-Income Countries 4.00 45 3.50 40 3.00 35 30 2.50 25 2.00 20 1.50 15 1.00 10 0.50 5 0.00 0 1 9 8 0 1 9 8 2 1 9 8 4 1 9 8 6 1 9 8 8 1 9 9 0 1 9 9 2 1 9 9 4 1 9 9 6 1 9 9 8 2 0 0 0 2 0 0 2 2 0 0 4 2 0 0 6 2 0 0 8 Corporate Tax Revenue(%GDP) Corporate Tax Rate (Right Axis) High-Income Countries 4.00 50 3.50 45 40 3.00 35 2.50 30 2.00 25 1.50 20 15 1.00 10 0.50 5 0.00 0 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 Percent points In percent Percent Points In percent Percent Points In percent Percent Points In percent
  • 43. Corporate Tax Revenue(%GDP) Corporate Tax Rate (Right Axis) Source: IMF staff calculations. Note: Group medians, dynamic income group; scales vary.
  • 44. 35 53. Incentives—preferentialtreatmentofparticulartypesofinvestment—havebecome morepervasiveinsub-SaharanAfrica,thoughthewiderpictureismixed. In1980about 40 percent of LICs in sub-Saharan Africa offered tax holidays, while by 2005 about 80 percent did; and there was a very marked increase in the proportion providingspecial tax treatment in free trade zones:fromnilto 50 percent(KeenandMansour,2010).That revenuenevertheless broadly held up, even aside from resource revenues, presumably reflects an increase in the profit share whose continuationcannotbe assumed.46 In Latin Americaandthe Caribbean,onthe other hand, the average length ofholidays fell (Klemm and van Parys, 2009). 54. Reducedtaxratesandincentivescanattractforeigninvestment,butonlywhere otherbusinessconditionsaregood. Businesssurveysrepeatedlyfindthatwhiletaxation matters for foreign investors, other considerations—infrastructure, rule of law, labor—matter more (for instance, McKinsey, 2003), as emerging econometric evidence confirms (van Parys andJames,2009andDharmapalaandHines,2009). 55. Incentivesposeconcernsofeffectiveness,leakage,governanceandspillovers. Some types of incentive are more likely to attract investment generatingwider social benefits than are others: an investment tax credit, for instance, may for this reason be preferable to simply exempting profits. Incentives can be hard to control: free zones, for instance, are notalways well-controlled sealed areas,47 and profits can be transfer priced from non-holiday to holiday companies. Signaling a willingness to provide special tax treatment invites special pleading and corruption;and the demand for incentives, particularly tax holidays—generally agreed to be the worst form of incentive (Appendix X)—may in part be a response to, and so entrench, corruption in the tax administration. The scope to raise more revenue by limiting such incentives is hard to assess— andevenharderwhere holidaycompaniesare notevenrequiredto filetaxreturns—but seems likely in manycases to be substantial. Cubeddu et al. (2008) put the revenue cost of CIT incentives in 15 Caribbean countries at an average of around 5½ percent of GDP. Less dramatic but sizable, available estimates for Latin America put the cost of preferential treatments under the income tax at 0.5-6 percent ofGDP (Villela, Lemgruber, and Jorratt, 2010).48 And, as an indicator to betreatedwithverygreat caution,forthose LICs with'CIT-productivity'49 below the median fortheirincomegroup,raisingittothat median,whetherbybase-broadeningor improved compliance, would in 2002 have increased revenue by about 0.7 percent of GDP. 46TheconvergenceofstatutoryCITratesoverthesampleperiodmayalsohavereducedlossesthroughtransfer pricing. 47They also raise WTO-consistency issues. 48Thefiguresneedtobeinterpretedwithcare:methodologiesdiffer,and, moreover,theneedtohonorexisting commitmentscanmeanthattherevenuegainstakesometimetomaterialize. 49CIT revenue in percent of GDP divided by the CIT rate. One reason for caution is that (unlike VAT C-efficiency) thisisnot evaluatingrevenueperformancerelativetoacoherentbenchmarkbase.
  • 45. 36 56. Regionalcooperationcanhelpcombatexcessiveincentives—butunilateralactions havealsosucceeded. Incompetingtoattractinvestment,countriescanmakethemselves collectively worse off. Regional agreements to limit incentives (a model is in Appendix XI) can block downward tax competition. This can be especially helpful where the formation of customs unionsincreases firms' mobilityandcanpromptpressure foralternative protective measures; indeed one lesson of the continuing difficulties many trading blocs have in reaching such agreements isthat theyare best putinplace intandemwithotherintegrationmeasures,before the intensified pressures come into play. While participants in such agreements remain vulnerable to competition from third countries, the net gains—including in scaling back governance problems associated with preferential treatments—could be substantial. The difficulties in reaching such agreements are more political than technical, as seen in Central America and the East African Community (EAC), for example. Unilateral actions, however, have also proved beneficial: Appendix XII. 57. Internationaltaxconsiderationsareincreasinglyimportantfordeveloping countries,whichcanbepowerfullyaffectedbyactionsofadvancedcountries. Multinational companies have opportunities for profit-shifting through intra-group transactions, financial arrangements andcorporate structuring.Even the most advancedtaxadministrationsstruggle with this, and—although the extent of the revenue impact remains unclear50—the challenges are greater where capacityisweak.Someargue,moreover,that presentnormsare tiltedagainst developing countries; the low withholding taxes common in double tax treaties (DTTs), for instance, can weaken a last line ofprotection for weak administrations. The sheer transactions costs of negotiatingDTTs can be a severe drain, which could perhaps be eased by developing multilateral treaties. (Thuronyi, 2001). Convergence ofstatutory tax rates reduces avoidance incentives, but developing (and retaining) capacity to deal with them will remain a severe challenge. A realistic balance must be struck between the additional revenue to be gained in this area—by increased administrative efforts in relation to transfer pricing, for instance—and that from strengtheningmore prosaic aspects of administration. Advanced country decisions can ease the difficulties of developing countries (as with the reinvigorated G-20 action on tax havens, for instance)51 but canalso riskdeepeningthem:rate cuts inadvancedeconomiescan trigger cuts elsewhere, for example, and exemptingforeign profits, as sometimes proposed inthe U.S. and underway in the United Kingdom, might intensify global tax competition.52 50Baker(2005), widely-cited, putssuchflows at $700-1,000billionper year,with$320-520 fromdeveloping countries (with a total of a further $350-500 billion of criminal and corrupt flows); the underlying sources, however, are not available. While there is indeed substantial evidence that profit-shifting is extensive, Fuest and Reidl (2010) arguethatthemethodologiesunderlyingavailable estimatesofitsextent andrevenuecostareproblematic. 51Torvik(2009) argues that their impact ongovernance canmake taxhavens especially damaging fordeveloping countries. 52Underthealternative'residence-based'approach,taxpaidabroadiscreditableagainstthatdueathome,sothat those foreign taxes impose no additional liability onthe investor; Mullins (2006) elaborates.
  • 46. 37 58. SOEsposesignificantcomplianceproblemsinsomecountries. Thetransitionto taxing them bythe same rules andmethods as appliedto private enterprises has notalways been easy, and in some cases remains incomplete—most evidently so inrelation to some natural resource companies,53 butalso sometimestooinsuchsectorsas energygenerationand transmission, telecommunications, and transportation. While the taxation of SOEs profits raises no netrevenue for government broadly interpreted, revenue from the VAT and wage withholding can suffer, non-compliance undermines good commercial practice and wider taxpayer morale, and large accumulations oftax arrears can result in administrations diverting scarce resources away from more productive activities. Solutions rarely lie within the capacity of the tax administration alone,though efforts can be made to identify and quarantine arrears, followingup byenforcement. F. Excises 59. Excises—taxesonafewkeyproducts—areasignificantsourceofrevenue,butin trend decline (Figure 13)—mainly, it seems, as a result of decliningreal rates. Their importance also varies substantially across regions, being much less, for instance, in sub-Saharan Africa and Middle Eastern and Central Asian countries than in Asia54 and South America; and Francophone Africa derives less from this source than Anglophone. Figure 13. Developments in Excise Revenues, 1980-2008 4.0 3.5 3.0 2.5 2.0 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 Low income Lower middleincome Upper middleincome High income Source: IMF staff calculations Note: Dynamic income groups. Samples are sometimes small (as low as two LICs for 2005-07). 60. Leviedonafewkeyitems,excisescanservebothrevenueand,insomecases,wider socialends. Specialtaxes are sometimesleviedonluxury goods suchas jewelryorperfume,but 53The particular challenges indealing withthese are discussedbyMcPherson(2010). 54Tobaccoalone raises around 8percent of central government revenue inChina P.R.and Indonesia: Barber etal. (2008)andHuetal.(2008).
  • 47. 38 typically bring little revenue and so have only a token impact on equity. Almost all excise revenue comes from fuels, tobacco, alcohol and other drinks, cars and, increasingly, mobile phones,55 the rationale for these charges beingnotonlyto tap the revenue potential ofa relatively inelastic and readily identified base but, to varying degrees, to change behavior:      6 1. Petroleum products. Fuel taxes are often part of wider frameworks to stabilizeand moderate domestic retail prices. Direct subsidies in developing countries amounted to around $54 billion in mid-2009, and net revenue foregone relative to a tax of $0.3 per liter to around $110 billion (Arze del Granado et al., 2010). More effective fuel pricing would serve distributional ends—empirical work repeatedly finds better ways to help the poor (del Granado et al., 2010)—and help address environmental concerns (not only, or even mainly, climate change, but also local pollution and congestion); Cigarettes: Externality and self-control considerations point to higher taxes than would otherwise be the case (there being substantial evidence that they can deter new smokers; Ross and Chaloupka, 2000), with several studies suggesting scope for gains inboth revenue and health from increases in many developing countries: 56 in the order of 0.3-0.4 percent of GDP in India and Vietnam, for instance;57 Alcoholic and other drinks: Local custom, social preferences and drinking patternsmean that revenue potential can differ widely. Increasing attention is being paid to the case for taxing non-alcoholic bottled drinks in low- income countries; Motor vehicles. In addition to raising worthwhile revenue—0.1 to 0.15 percent ofGDP in Botswana and Lebanon—largely from the better-off, vehicle taxes can also address extern alities; and
  • 48. T e l e c o m s . A u ctioninglicenses is in principle the best way to tax the potentially substantial rents in this increasingly important sector. Failing that, excises can raise substantial revenue without unduly discouraging use (the positive externalities from which appear to be sizeable: Jensen, 2007). Liberia, for instance, raises about 6 percentof its revenue from this source. The amounts are much less elsewhere, but the scopefor increa se is clear. Excisescanbeamongthesimplesttaxestoimplement,buttherearechallenges — someofwhichcanbeeasedbyregionalcooperation. Concentratedproduction andhigh 55In2009, excises ontobaccoand drink accountedfor around 80percent ofnon-fuelexciserevenue in the Central African Republic and Senegal, and 90 percent inEgypt and the Philippines. 56Seefor example: WHO(2010), Sunley(2010), and Petit (forthcoming). 57International Unionagainst tuberculosis and lung disease,countrystudies are available at: http://www.tobaccofreeunion.org (January4,2011).
  • 49. 39 import shares make administration (nowadays generally located in the LTO) relatively easy. One long-standing issue is the choice between specific and ad valorem forms of excise (specified as monetary amountsandas proportionofthe price,respectively): the formerare better-suitedto addressing externalities (which generally dependon quantities, not prices), and have often been regarded as simpler to administer, though any advantages of specific taxation in this respect are becoming less marked as implementation moves away from physical control).58 But other concerns are coming more to the fore. Telecoms, for instance, raise less familiar implementation issues, includingthe taxation ofprepaid airtime and auditing operators without the necessary software and technical expertise. Still more of a concern in many countries are potential difficulties—or, for some, a source of revenue gain—from smuggling. Illicit and small scale production can also undercut excise revenue (and in some cases raise public health issues). Fear ofinducingrevenue losses from these sourcesisonereasonmanycountrieshave hesitatedto increase rates. Administrative measures, including close control of bondedwarehouses and transit shipments are important, especially within customs unions; however, some degree of policy cooperation may be needed—perhaps including, in CEMAC and WAEMU, agreement to raise regionally-agreedmaximum rates. 62. Thereisscopeinmanycountriestoraisesignificantadditionalrevenuefromexcises withoutadversedistributionaleffects. Thedecliningshareofexcisesintaxrevenuesuggests considerable scope for increase (beyond offsetting any tariff reductions on excisables), perhaps supported by some degree of policy and administrative cooperation. Prescriptions clearly need to be country-specific (an exception being the universal importance of automatic indexation of specific taxes), but, for example, sub-Saharan Africa and the Middle East and Central Asia could increase excise revenue by an average of 0.5 percent ofGDP and 1.3 percent ofGDP respectively by increasing the share of excises in total revenue to the world average. G. TaxingSmallBusinesses 63. Smallbusinessesareextremelydifficulttomanage,andhavelimitedrevenue potential. Thisisahighlyheterogeneousgroup,from'micro'businesses—streettraders, subsistence farmers—with limited ability to pay (in both fairness and practical terms), through professionals and businesses with many employees. The highly skewed size distribution of firms—in all countries, but perhaps especially so in developing—means that such businesses are numerous, but have little revenue potential. In Egypt, the largest 4,000 companies account for about 90 percentof total turnover; even a massive proportional increase in receipts from the 5 million small enterprises would have relatively little impact on total receipts. It is not uncommon for developingcountry tax administrations to devote large resources to this segment inthe hope of flushing out medium or large taxpayers by blanket enforcementoperations; but results have been poor andcosts ofimplementationhigh. 58Other considerations in making the choice include the stabilityof revenues (tending tofavor specific where the demand elasticity is low) and maintaining the availability of low-price product variants (favoring ad valorem).
  • 50. 40 64. Thetaxtreatmentofsmallbusinesshasimportance,however,beyondrevenue. They are often viewed as especially important in generating employment and productivity-enhancing innovations, although the evidence onthis is mixed.59 What is clear is that they are often politically influential. Such considerations, combined with their limited revenue potential and the risk of distracting the tax administration from more critical tasks, might suggest subjecting them to nomorethansometokentax—as hasbeencommon.Buttherearepowerfulreasonsfor carefulattentionto the treatmentofsmall businesses, whichcan:     6 5. Ease competitive distortions and inefficiencies. Taxation—including attendant compliance costs and, potentially, exposure to bribery and harassment —canbe a powerful disincentive for small firms to regularize their activities. In some instances, there is a high effective tax rate on new investments by small enterprises (FIAS, 2007), and firms may limit their growth to avoid detection by the revenue authorities. In extreme but not uncommon cases, firms become 'ghosts'. Although surveys repeatedly showthat taxation is far from the only reason firms remain irregular—labor laws, social standards and corruption can be at least as important—the distortions are clear. Non- compliance by small taxpayers, coupled with the greater ability of large firms to benefit from tax exemptions, can create an inverse U-shaped relationship between firm size and effective tax rates that is unlikely to be optimal.60 Even a tax on small businesses which raises less than it costs to collect is desirable to the extent it eases these distortions (Keen,2010); Enhance taxpayer morale. Compliance of larger businesses can be underminedif smaller ones are not seen to pay reasonable amounts. And small businesses themselves are more likely to comply if they believe others are—creating the possibility of shifting from'bad'complianceequilibriato'good' ones; Contributetostate-building.Bringingsmallbusinessesintothetaxnetcanhelp secure their participation in the political process and improve government accountability; and
  • 51. B r i n g n o n -taxbenefitstosmallenterprisesthemselves.Compliancemayboost record-keeping capacities and financial sophistication, for instance, and so improve capital market access. If enterprises fail to appreciate such benefits themselves, orthe consequent productivity gains yield wider spillover benefits, intervention by the tax authorities beyond that justified by revenue considerations would be warranted. Small businesses tax regimes vary widely,61 but a coherent structure can be built around a relatively high VAT threshold. All too often, a low VAT threshold and overly- 59Biggs and Shah(1998) findlarge firms tobe thedominant creatorsof manufacturing jobs insub- SaharanAfrica. 60Gauthier and Gersovitz (1997) on Cameroon; and Gauthier and Reinikka (2006) on Uganda. This may also partly explainthe'missingmiddle'inthedistributionoffirmsizeindeveloping countries. 61Bodin (2010) and Bodin and Koukpaizan (2008) reviewrecent developments and options in taxing small businesses in lower income countries, including withholding and advance collection schemes discussedbelow.