SlideShare une entreprise Scribd logo
1  sur  15
Télécharger pour lire hors ligne
Eco-Management and Auditing
Eco-Mgmt. Aud. 6, 61–75 (1999)
ENVIRONMENTAL
SELF-REGULATION AND
SUSTAINABLE ECONOMIC
GROWTH: THE SEAMLESS WEB
FRAMEWORK
William J. Altham1
and Turlough F. Guerin2
*
1
Murdoch University, Australia
2
Environmental Adviser, USA
A ‘seamless web’ framework of
environmental regulation is emerging.
The seamless web provides a
comprehensive and holistic framework for
facilitating the transition to ecologically
sustainable development (ESD). This
seamless web comprises numerous
threads, that is regulators and regulatory
mechanisms, which provide the
framework in which society may attain
effective protection from environmental
degradation. Regulatory bodies include
government and state regulators, NGOs,
industry peers, investors and consumers.
Regulatory mechanisms and incentives
range through lower costs, increased
market share and long term resource
access and sanctions ranging through
incarceration of directors, license
withdrawal, fines, falling profits, loss of
market share and falling investor
confidence. We conclude that
self-regulation is a useful mechanism to
promote environmental protection, and
that industry will increasingly face
pressure to improve its environmental
performance from many stakeholders.
The seamless web framework recognizes
the pivotal role of industry in
environmental regulation, catering for a
range of corporate cultures, and thereby
stimulating innovation of appropriate
technology. Copyright  1999 John
Wiley  Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment.
Accepted 3 February 1999
INTRODUCTION
T
he environment, according to many
opinion polls, is the issue of the ‘future’
(Gunningham, 1994a). Concern for the
environment has led to many innovations, fora
and institutions that study, discuss or attempt to
provide solutions for our environmentally unsus-
tainable social and economic system. The World
Business Council for Sustainable Development,
Brundtland Report, Agenda 21 and the Earth
Summit, Climate Change Convention and Ozone
Conventions are just some examples of institu-
tional responses to environmental problems.
Many of these responses see industry involve-
ment, through self-regulation in a broad sense, as
a critical component of a successful resolution of
these issues (Anonymous, 1996; Deavenport,
*Correspondence to: Dr. Turlough F. Guerin, 1691 E Green Briars
Drive, Suite 3821, Schaumburg, IL 60173, USA.
CCC 0968-9427/99/020061–15 $17.50
Copyright  1999 John Wiley  Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment.
1996; Hemphill, 1996; Nash and Ehrenfeld, 1997;
Jackson, 1998; Mullin, 1998a  b; Noor-Drugan,
1998; Scott, 1998).
There is ongoing debate regarding the most
effective forms of environmental regulation
(Mullin and Sissell, 1996). Environmental regula-
tions are required to correct market failures, while
offering protection to the environment and future
generations. Full costs should be considered by
the market to ensure the correct allocation of
resources. However, environmental regulations
are open to political interference in a climate
where there are high levels of uncertainty as to
future technology, resource availability, industry
growth, innovation and employment.
Self-regulation is increasingly being promoted
as an efficient form of regulation and is being
incorporated into corporate environmental policy
making and implementation (Seif, 1995; Sheldon,
1997). However, this has created heated debate
within society. Industry fears that self-regulation
may become part of standard regulatory practice
(Colby, 1997) under political pressure from envi-
ronmentalists. Industry also fears that a voluntary
industry framework, to allow companies to go
beyond environmental compliance within their
own time-frame, could become another regulatory
weapon by which they will be controlled, that it
would hit small business particularly hard and that
it could become a barrier to trade and increase
commodity prices (Blau, 1995; Samdani, 1995;
Bridgen, 1996; Dwyer, 1996). Certain industries
also see the introduction of further environmen-
tal standards as additional, non-business work
(Webb, 1995). On the other hand, environmental-
ists maintain that self-regulation is a move to ‘pull
the wool’ over the public’s eyes, with the environ-
mental movement having a distrust of initiatives
from industry (Mullin, 1998a  b). Others argue
that the command-and-control framework, which
is the basis for most environmental regulations,
is economically inefficient and have proposed a
variety of market-based alternatives. The most
prominent alternative is industry self-regulation,
which affords industry the opportunity to gain
exemptions from specific command-and-control
requirements by proposing different methods
for achieving underlying environmental goals
(Steinzor, 1998).
Industry needs to take an active role in the
development of all forms of environmental
regulation if it wishes to ensure a balanced debate
with workable solutions. To encourage proactive
industry involvement in setting and implementing
corporate environmental policy will require the
development of institutions and government
and state policies that manage risk and uncer-
tainty for industry (Lepkowski, 1994; Jaffe and
Stavins, 1995). The development of feedback
loops, or improvement cycles, within company
management systems, which leads to continuous
improvement, is important if industry is going
to demonstrate environmental leadership. The
commercial benefits of such a proactive approach
to environmental management are becoming
clear in numerous industries (Greis, 1995; Ferrone,
1998; Jancsurak, 1998). Traditionally, environ-
mental issues and concerns have been viewed as a
constraint to businesses and have resulted in
environmental managers relying heavily on a
reactive, compliance-based approach to justify
change. Businesses are now recognizing that
efficient management in the environmental
arena can benefit the entire company and
open new opportunities for increased profits.
Managers have acknowledged that environmental
issues can be integrated into daily business
trends and activities (Metcalf et al., 1996). Not
only does sound environmental management
decrease liability, but also, in current markets,
a ‘green’ image can attract investors and
customers.
It is argued in the current paper that a seamless
web of environmental regulation has an ability to
provide the greatest protection to the environ-
ment while stimulating the innovation and diffu-
sion of environmental technology, catering for
different corporate cultures and providing a holis-
tic approach to environmental regulation. This
paper describes the development of a seamless
web framework of environmental regulation. The
paper divides the evolution of environmental
regulation into three stages in order of develop-
ment (Figure 1(A) – (C)). These represent the
major groups of stakeholders in the setting of
environmental regulation for each of the stages
(Table 1). The ISO 14000 environmental manage-
ment system (EMS) standards (Begley, 1996) have
been used as an example of self-regulation in this
paper and the specific definitions used are given in
Table 2.
W. J. ALTHAM AND T. F. GUERIN
Copyright  1999 John Wiley  Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment. Eco-Mgmt. Aud. 6, 61–75 (1999)
62
Figure 1. (A) Stage one – traditional environmental regulation. (B) Stage two – traditional environmental regulation influenced
by market mechanisms. (C) Stage three – seamless web model of environmental self-regulation.
(A)
(B)
(C)
SEAMLESS WEB FRAMEWORK
Copyright  1999 John Wiley  Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment. Eco-Mgmt. Aud. 6, 61–75 (1999)
63
MARKET FAILURE AND THE
DEVELOPMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL
REGULATIONS
A market failure occurs when the market does not
produce the allocation of resources that maxi-
mizes the total level of social welfare. In other
words, such failures occur when an important
economic factor is overlooked and therefore left
unpriced. Underpricing can lead to the rapid
overexploitation of a given resource and regulat-
ory institutions should operate on the assumption
that higher prices must be assigned to limited
resources (Brown, 1996).
Hawken (1993) comments that ‘markets are
superb at setting prices, but incapable of recog-
nizing costs’. The costs referred to here are
externalities, and these create a market failure. An
externality occurs when a third party has to bear
the cost of the action of others, and is not fully
compensated (Philpot, 1992). Pollution is the
classic example of an externality. This cost of
pollution is largely borne by the community as a
social cost. Because the community and not the
consumer of the product carries some of these
costs, the price of the product is reduced and
demand is increased.
A range of environmental regulatory mechan-
isms are available to correct such market failures
(Harris, 1996; Hyde, 1997). These vary in the
degree of their government and state authority.
Such mechanisms include traditional (command-
and-control) regulation, market mechanisms and
self-regulation measures. The effectiveness of
these mechanisms varies depending on many
factors. These include the culture of the organiz-
ation under these regulatory mechanisms, the
nature of the market failure, the opportunities for
the industry to alter their production methods and
substitute materials, the resources allocated to the
regulator, the visibility of the industry sector in
the market place and the expectations of the
community and other stakeholders.
THE ROLE OF TRADITIONAL
REGULATION
Traditional environmental regulation involves
what is commonly called ‘command-and-control’.
This includes flat taxes and charges, and direct
environmental regulations. They involve a gov-
ernment or state institution legislating industry
behaviour (Gunningham, 1994b), in effect telling
industry what it can and cannot do, and how
much it will cost them (Figure 1(A)). Industry
responds to the regulations by addressing the
specific concerns with limited view to any
greater environmental impact reduction (Wilson,
1997).
Table 1. Stakeholders in environmental regulation.
Stakeholder Influence
Government Set industry standards under political pressure
State Set industry environmental performance standards under direction of government
Industry organization Influence industry standard settings
Industry Influence industry standard settings
Peers Influence industry standard settings
Participate in trading under market regulation
Environmental regulators Set and enforce industry standards
Market Place where market regulation are traded
Community Influence environmental performance and standards through political pressure
Consumers Influence sales, therefore profit of company
Environmental NGOs Influence industry standard settings through political pressure
Financial institutions Influence industry behaviour through reduced cost if environmental risk is managed
Insurance sector Influence industry behaviour through reduced cost if environmental risk is managed
Investors Influence industry behaviour through supply of capital if environmental risk is managed
Work force Affect worker productivity and staff turn-over
W. J. ALTHAM AND T. F. GUERIN
Copyright  1999 John Wiley  Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment. Eco-Mgmt. Aud. 6, 61–75 (1999)
64
Many problems with traditional environmental
regulation have been identified (Bovy, 1989;
Susani, 1996). These including their inflexiblility
(Wolf, 1988) and tendency to be directed by
political consideration (Brozen et al., 1990). In
addition, limited power and resources available
to the regulator often leads to inadequate
enforcement of regulations.
As far back as the late 1960s economists and
industrialists were questioning the economic ef-
ficiency of traditional environmental regulations
(BIE, 1992; Tyler Miller, 1994). The BIE (1992)
provides a summary of concerns with traditional
regulations, while highlighting the benefits of the
market mechanism:
Many economists argue that direct regu-
lations are static, inflexible and sub-optimal
in terms of environmental and economic ef-
ficiency. Direct regulation, despite its accept-
ability by government, is cost-ineffective in
reducing emissions when compared to both
pollution taxes and permits.
These statements were supported by studies of
the costs of the two types of policy (traditional
versus market) on industry in the US’s Clean Air
Act policy changes, with the shift to market
requirements producing an estimated saving of
$US900 million up to 1985 (BIE, 1992). Tyler-
Miller (1994) claims that the current US bill for
environmental protection of over $US120 billion
per year could be cut by 33–50% if more effective
market-based policies were used.
However, possibly the greatest drawback with
traditional regulation is that, in general, it has
resulted in ‘end-of-pipe’ solutions to environ-
mental problems (Nash and Ehrenfeld, 1997).
End-of-pipe solutions are short-term, regulatory-
driven solutions, which do not generally address
the cause of the problem (Klassen and Angell,
1998). Examples include where equipment is
added to the end of a process, such as filters and
scrubbers to pollution discharge points.
Although sound and well enforced environ-
mental regulations are an essential foundation for
improving environmental quality, command-and-
control systems alone are not achieving the lower
levels of pollution that will be necessary to
achieve ecologically sustainable development
(Rondinelli and Berry, 1997).
THE ROLE OF MARKET MECHANISMS
Market mechanisms require the establishment of
property rights for pollution emission and natural
resources, and a market in which to trade these
rights, with the price determined by market
forces. In theory, market mechanisms allow natu-
ral resources to be used for their highest market
value end use, by the most economically efficient
operators. Pollution is generated by sectors of
industry with the greatest potential to pay, or
the highest control costs (though not strictly
always the case). This leads to the ‘polluter pays
principle’, in which
Trade occurs because low-cost polluters will
find it financially advantageous to cut pol-
lution levels and sell permits, whereas high
cost polluters find it financially advantageous
to purchase permits rather than decrease
pollution (Owen, 1991).
This trading mechanism allows the maximum
production for any loading of total emissions. In
addition, market mechanisms and tradeable permit
systems, in theory, are dynamic, allow for tech-
nological innovation, allow new entrants into the
industry, expand markets and are self-adjusting
for inflation. All of these factors reduce the
involvement of the state in environmental regu-
lation (Figure 1(B)). An example of market mech-
anisms is that of air emissions trading. Under the
US Acid Rain Program, and California’s Regional
Reclaim Program, the US has demonstrated the
economic and environmental feasibility of these
so-called ‘cap-and-trade’ programs. Now, emis-
sions trading is being considered in other areas
e.g. northeastern US, where trading schemes are
under development to curb ozone precursors. A
variety of states have implemented trading
programs to reduce NOx and volatile organic
compounds. Emissions trading is becoming inter-
national as governments attempt to curb
greenhouse-gas emissions (Hairston et al., 1998).
Such initiatives represent a fundamental change in
environmental management. A key element of
emissions trading is the degree of compliance
flexibility it affords individual operators (Hairston
et al., 1998).
The type of environmental regulation also
affects the organizations’ incentive to adopt new
technology for pollution control (Jaffe and
SEAMLESS WEB FRAMEWORK
Copyright  1999 John Wiley  Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment. Eco-Mgmt. Aud. 6, 61–75 (1999)
65
Stavins, 1995). In work by Milliman and Prince
(1989) they concluded that
Direct controls, which are common regulatory
tools, usually provide the lowest relative firm
incentives to promote technology. On a rela-
tive basis, emission taxes and auctioned per-
mits provide the highest firm incentive for the
adoption of new technology.
The major limitation of market mechanisms is
that they cannot set the physical limits to the
level of harvesting of natural resources or the
assimilative capacity of the environment. This is a
role for science, but clearly our scientific knowl-
edge is incomplete (BIE, 1992). For example, if
timber allocations or fishing quotas are set too
high, the level of harvesting will be unsustainable.
Alternatively, if the level of emission quotas
allocated within a region is higher than the area
can assimilate there will be social costs associated
with the activity.
The potential role market mechanisms may
play in effective management of environmental
issues have recently been discussed (Gustafsson,
1998). Although some assert that environmental
problems could be solved by appropriate pricing
of the environment and liberal application of
market mechanisms for environmental manage-
ment, these types of simplification may overlook
the many complicating factors inherent in
environmental degradation and the limitations
of market mechanisms as a means of coping
with environmental problems. These limitations
include problems in defining and enforcing prop-
erty rights concerning functions and services
provided by nature (Gustafsson, 1998).
THE ROLE OF SELF-REGULATION
AND CODES OF PRACTICES
Self-regulation, including codes of practice and
standards, are developed by industry for many
diverse reasons, including as a means of showing
social responsibility and a desire by industry to
reclaim the agenda-setting of their industry from
other stakeholders. The development of EMS
standards (ISO 14001, BS7750 and EMAS) can be
seen as the latest stage in the development of
modern environmental regulation (Nash and
Ehrenfeld, 1997). Self-regulation can include either
performance, content or process standards. It is
the process standard of ISO 14001 which
is now contemporary and is being adopted
internationally (Hemenway, 1995; Snyder, 1995;
Hemenway, 1996; Label and Tandy, 1998).
Simply defined, a standard is anything, a rule or
principle, that is used as a basis for judgment, an
average or normal requirement, quality, quantity,
level, grade, established by authority, custom or
an individual as acceptable. Standardization, and
its application to business systems, is one of the
most important aspects of effective environmental
management, a prerequisite for management, and
empowering employees to understand where the
company is vis-a-vis work and performance
(Johannson, 1994). The improvement process can-
not be undertaken successfully until standards are
established and understood.
Self-regulatory mechanisms, including the ISO
14000 series, accept the legislative regulations as
a minimum standard that industry must achieve.
The standards then encourage industry to be
proactive, encouraging continuous improvement
through the management process. ISO 14000 is
a series of voluntary EMS standards, developed
by the International Standards Organization
(Struebing, 1996; Burns and Fredericks, 1997;
Iwanski et al., 1997; Hersey, 1998). These stan-
dards provide a framework by which an organ-
ization can focus attention on its internal
management activities. This allows the organiz-
ation to integrate environmental management
with other existing management considerations
(such as production, sales, finance, safety and
quality), with the aim of achieving continuous
improvements in the organization’s environ-
mental performance. The overall aim of ISO 14000
is to support environmental protection and
prevention of pollution in balance with socio-
economic needs. This series of standards cover
the following major areas:
(i) environmental management systems,
(ii) environmental auditing,
(iii) environmental performance evaluation,
(iv) eco-labeling and
(v) life-cycle analysis.
Self-regulation implies (to a large extent) no
legal requirement to comply. Therefore some
other type of incentive for organizations to adopt
W. J. ALTHAM AND T. F. GUERIN
Copyright  1999 John Wiley  Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment. Eco-Mgmt. Aud. 6, 61–75 (1999)
66
such mechanisms is required. The major initial
incentive for organizations to adopt self-
regulation, including ISO 14001, is provided by
the market. That is, organizations adopting them
will, it is commonly claimed by advocates, be more
efficient and competitive, gaining a marketing
advantage in the longer term (Johannson, 1995).
Codes of practices can act as a trail to see
how industry is affected by changes in regulation.
On occasions, sections of these codes have
even become incorporated into law, such as the
dangerous goods code in Australia, which has
become Federal law. There is the problem of
verifying that individual industry organizations,
claiming compliance to a particular code, are in
fact complying with that code. To minimize this
problem and increase the public’s confidence in
the minerals industry, the Minerals Council of
Australia (MCA), for example, requires member
organizations to be externally audited at least
every three years against the MCA Code for
Environmental Management.
INTEGRATING THE COMPONENTS
OF ENVIRONMENTAL REGULATION
INTO A SEAMLESS WEB
With continuous additions to the regulatory
mechanisms, it is often difficult to determine
where any particular regulator or regulation fits.
One way of understanding the situation is
through the concept of a seamless web of regu-
lation (Figure 1(C)). A seamless web of environ-
mental regulation implies an integrated set of
regulations, regulators and incentives. Regulations
involve a mix of traditional regulation, market
mechanisms and self-regulation. Regulators in-
clude federal and state regulators, NGOs, peers,
other companies along the supply chain, service
providers, investors and consumers. Incentives for
improved environmental performance range from
lower costs to increased market share and long
term resource access, with sanctions ranging
across incarceration of directors, license with-
drawal, loss of resource access, fines, falling
profits, loss of market share and falling investor
confidence.
Even within an industry, individual organiz-
ations will respond to environmental regulations
in different ways, depending on management
culture, size of the organization and the environ-
mental sensitivity of the operation. Improving
environmental performance requires regulatory
mechanisms that cater for a range of variables and
stimulate industry to adopt new environmental
technologies. Traditional, direct environmental
regulation will always be required to motivate
laggards who are the slowest to adopt the most
appropriate course of action (Guerin and Guerin,
1994). Proactive companies (innovators and
leaders), on the other hand, will respond to the
opportunities and incentives that self-regulation
offers to improve environmental performance.
Command-and-control environmental regu-
lations and reactive organizations are unlikely
to develop management improvement cycles
because the aim of the organization under this
mechanism is to meet their legal requirement
(Figure 2). Further, market mechanisms generate
only limited incentive for organizations to
develop a continuous improvement cycle, because
the aim of the organization is to meet their legal
requirements (and no more), at least cost. Industry
self-regulation, through an EMS, can create a
greater incentive for management to develop the
improvement cycle, which leads to a process of
continuous improvement in environmental per-
formance (Kirschner, 1995; Crognale, 1997). Con-
tinuous improvement is created because changes
in environmental performance are measured
against present performance and not past per-
formance or an arbitrary legal standard (Figure 3).
Moreover this level of performance is continually
Table 2. Definitions.
Environmental regulation Means that control or modify organizational behaviour towards the environment
Regulators Stakeholders playing a role in creating and enforcing this modified behaviour
State The unelected institutions and bureaucracy that carry out the affairs of state
Government The elected representative of the people
SEAMLESS WEB FRAMEWORK
Copyright  1999 John Wiley  Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment. Eco-Mgmt. Aud. 6, 61–75 (1999)
67
under review by the organization to determine
whether it can be improved.
The concept of a seamless web removes some
of the limitations of a regulatory system that
relies on a single traditional regulatory mechan-
ism, or single agency, to enforce environmental
regulations. These limitations include the problem
of regulatory capture, skills shortages, budgetary
cutbacks and political interference into the oper-
ations of the regulators. Furthermore, it allows
companies more flexibility in reducing costs
associated with dealing with the environmental
impact(s) (Hesse, 1989; Young, 1994).
Within the concept of the seamless web there is
no single best method of environmental regu-
lation. As soon as an organization identifies under
what category of environmental regulation they
will be controlled, they investigate methods to
reduce that regulation’s impact on their operation.
This action will often lead to measures that
will reduce the effectiveness of the original regu-
lation, and in some cases lead to an inefficient
‘ratcheting-up’ effect of environmental regulation.
Citizen Legal Standing
The proper functioning of the seamless web
requires two factors that are becoming more
prevalent in modern environmental policy. The
first is the granting of legal standing to all
stakeholders under the relevant environmental
regulation. This provision allows individuals or
organizations to instigate legal action against
parties who in their opinion are not complying
with legislative environmental regulation. This
provision supplements the resources the state has
to devote to enforcing environmental regulations
while preventing regulatory capture. Industry
sometimes claims that granting private standing
will lead to large numbers of ‘nuisance’ claims.
However this does not appear to be the case.
This citizen legal standing can also be used
to force public authorities to comply with
relevant environmental regulations and to en-
sure environmental regulators act on breaches
of environmental regulations carried out by
organizations.
Figure 2. The environmental management improvement cycle.
W. J. ALTHAM AND T. F. GUERIN
Copyright  1999 John Wiley  Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment. Eco-Mgmt. Aud. 6, 61–75 (1999)
68
Public Disclosure
For environmental regulations to work efficiently,
all stakeholders need access to the relevant infor-
mation. Therefore, the second factor required is
environmental reporting by organizations in
order to aid informed debate and correct decision
making by stakeholders (Chynoweth, 1994; Nash
and Ehrenfeld, 1997). This information must be
complete, accurate, relevant, easily understand-
able and made available at short regular intervals
such as in external company reports. The Toxic
Release Inventory (TRI) initiative introduced by
the US EPA is an example of this practice at work.
Under this programme, companies reported as
having the highest levels of emissions had the
largest stock price decline and subsequently
reduced emissions more than their industry peers
(Konar and Cohen, 1997).
Best Practice Licencing
To further illustrate the development of this
seamless web model of environmental regulation,
the Western Australian Environmental Protection
Authority’s (WAEPA’s) Best Practice License initiat-
ive (DEP, 1996) is described. Prior to the intro-
duction of this initiative, most industries in
Western Australia operated within a system of
traditional regulation. All organizations received
the same incentive and the same legislative sanc-
tions. With the introduction of the system,
WAEPA offered a range of alternatives for
organizations, catering for differences in corporate
culture and varying the level of monitoring
required. There are four levels of licence available:
a regulated licence, a partially monitored licence, a
monitored licence and a best practice licence (BPL)
(Baker, 1996). The system was introduced from
1 October 1996 for all forms of licence except the
BPL, whose criteria were released in 1998. After
1 October 1996, organizations could choose to
adopt their preferred licence as their licence
renewals occurred, provided the regulators accept
the organization’s application. It is likely that in
this Western Australian situation laggards will
continue to operate as before, that is under the
regulated (command-and-control) licence. How-
ever, organizations that are proactive have the
opportunity to show leadership and obtain a BPL.
If such organizations can demonstrate proactive
environmental management and go beyond com-
pliance, they receive a benefit in accordance with
their efforts. These benefits include lower license
fees (the theoretical maximum can be as high as
$180 000AUS), reduced external monitoring of
their operation and longer periods between
license renewals.
An Example of Stakeholder Influence
A contrast of the influence that stakeholder press-
ure can have on company behaviour, management
and environmental performance is illustrated by
Shell’s Brent Spar Oil Platform activity in the
North Sea, and the Exxon Valdez oil spill in
Prince William Sound, Alaska. The community
and the market sanctioned Shell, although Shell
complied with legislation and with the support of
the relevant government departments, when they
attempted to sink their oil platform, the Brent
Spar (Greenpeace, 1996). In the case of the Exxon
Valdez oil spill, though many regulations were
breached, anecdotal evidence indicates that,
despite the urgings of high profile environmental
campaigners, neither the community nor the mar-
ket sanctioned the Exxon Oil Company to the
same extent as Shell. This example demonstrates
for modern business the need to be aware of the
stakeholder’s view, together with willingness by
stakeholders to act on these views, as it should
affect a company’s environmental strategy if the
company is to operate in their own long term best
interest.
THE ROLE OF ISO 14001 IN THE
SEAMLESS WEB OF ENVIRONMENTAL
REGULATION
Industry Involvement
Industry is expected to play an increasingly
important role in developing clean, sustainable
production systems. This is in response to regu-
latory failures, increasing public expectation of
industry’s environmental performance, and the
uncertainty surrounding the effect of state
environmental regulations on growth and inno-
vation (Heaton and Banks, 1997). The adoption of
ISO 14001 should encourage organizations to
SEAMLESS WEB FRAMEWORK
Copyright  1999 John Wiley  Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment. Eco-Mgmt. Aud. 6, 61–75 (1999)
69
develop an environmental strategy as an import-
ant element of overall management decision mak-
ing, together with a framework by which this
strategy can be put into operation. Through this
framework, self-regulation can lead to significant
improvements in environmental performance
(Gunningham, 1994b).
Models of Corporate Culture and Beyond
Compliance
There are various models for corporate cultures,
company actions and the benefits to firms and the
environmental impacts of these actions. The re-
lationship between actions and benefits varies
between companies depending on their particular
priorities, and it is expected that there would be
differences between and within industries. Any
given firm will establish their EMS with specific
goals in mind. There are two important points for
management to consider: (i) the development of
an EMS is a learning process for the organization
and (ii) the benefits are compounding. Any firm
can start with the simple inexpensive changes
first, then with experience, develop their EMS to a
higher level at a rate and in a manner which is
compatible with the organization. For example,
any company doing the minimum required for
ISO 14001 certification could be classified as
Observe and Comply, while another certified firm,
which is ‘truly’ environmentally proactive with a
large commitment to RD into environmental
technology, can be classified as Proactive. This
point illustrates a problem with ISO 14001 in its
present form. It should be recognized that the
implementation of ISO 14001 on its own is
unlikely to bring about maximum benefits to the
company, if the company or corporate culture
does not accept the need for a continuous
improvement in environmental management
(Anonymous, 1995; Kanegsberg, 1996; Rimich,
1996; Epstein and Roy, 1997).
Any company, at any point in time, will be
somewhere along the continuum of environ-
mental performance. A company may shift to the
left of their present position, to observe and
comply. This would represent deterioration in the
company’s concern for environmental issues. If a
company has no history in EMS and attempts to
move to True ESD, then it is likely it will have
great difficulty in doing so. Such companies can
speed up the process of learning by devoting
more resources to their EMS. Components of an
effective EMS such as worker participation and
changes to corporate culture and mechanisms to
integrate environmental factors with other man-
agement considerations take time and substantial
resources to develop. Fortunately, there is a
process of learning by doing.
Figure 3. Improvement of environmental performance in a company.
W. J. ALTHAM AND T. F. GUERIN
Copyright  1999 John Wiley  Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment. Eco-Mgmt. Aud. 6, 61–75 (1999)
70
The Prospects of a Market Solution to a
Market Failure
The public’s expectation of how industry should
act regarding the environment has changed in
recent years. The natural environment cannot
now be treated as a free commodity or a dumping
ground. More importantly, sections of society are
prepared to act on these expectations, either by
changing spending patterns (Grabosky, 1995) or
through direct actions (such as illustrated in Shell’s
Brent Spar case). The US Superfund legislation is
another example where political and social press-
ure is being used to make industry more account-
able for their actions and correct past market
failures. Surveys of the public in the US concluded
that more than 75% of participants classified
themselves as environmentalists (Nicklas, 1993;
McInerney and White, 1995). Similar results were
shown from a survey conducted by the Australian
Bureau of Statistics (1996) where 75% of
Australians were concerned about environmental
issues.
Companies are having to assess and manage
the environmental risks of their operation(s), and
demonstrate this to service providers, investors
and other stakeholders, to ensure the long-term
support of the stakeholders, and indeed the sur-
vival of the company. These changes create the
potential for market pressure to be brought
against a market failure. However, if we were to
leave it up to the market to trigger the change,
the results would be much slower and more
erratic than socially desirable or acceptable. Hence
there is a requirement for public policies to
complement the incentive for industry to adopt
new technologies. This could be achieved through
legislative reform and recommendations in rela-
tion to the US environmental laws and regulatory
framework have been presented by Heaton and
Banks (1997).
This shift in organizational culture towards the
environment, for whatever reason, is paralleled in
other areas of organizational management. Areas
such as unfair dismissal, health and safety issues,
childcare, maternity leave and redundancy pay-
outs are examples where corporate attitudes have
changed in recent times.
There are likely to be many sceptics to the
argument being mounted that the market and
industry can protect the environment, claiming
that self-regulatory standards are another way by
which industry can ‘pull the wool’ over the
public’s eyes. This is being too cynical. Few
advocate the removal of other types of environ-
mental regulation. Both environmentally pro-
active companies and ISO maintain there will
always be a need for the ‘carrot’ and the ‘stick’.
Both approaches are important threads of the
seamless web of regulation. To this effect,
Gunningham (1994a) states
The bigger the stick at the disposal of the
regulators, the more it is able to achieve
results by speaking softly.
This is supported by Stoughton (1994), who
argues that
Voluntary programs have the potential to
affect significant changes in environmental
behaviors, and can be effective policies for
environmental protection. They often depend,
however, on a strong enforcement role for the
agency under its regulatory mandates, and
thus must be a supplement, rather than a
replacement for regulation.
These statements support the argument put
forward in this paper that the time has come when
the ‘carrot’ can play a greater part, by rewarding
companies for being proactive in the field of
environmental management. For this process to
be successful, however, legislative environmental
regulations are required, and the size of the ‘stick’
maintained or increased. To obtain the maximum
environmental benefit of environmental manage-
ment systems (including those based on ISO
14001), these regulations should be integrated
into the seamless web, providing another thread,
and complementing, not replacing, existing regu-
latory measures. The use of economic incentives
is normally preferable to the power of the law to
alter human behaviour. We assert that both need
to be available.
CONCLUSION
There can be a win – win outcome in the ESD
debate – when industry produces and the en-
vironment is protected. Furthermore, the current
ESD debate is not between environment and
SEAMLESS WEB FRAMEWORK
Copyright  1999 John Wiley  Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment. Eco-Mgmt. Aud. 6, 61–75 (1999)
71
development, but rather between sustainable and
unsustainable technology. Economies are achiev-
ing growth with reduced environmental impacts,
through the appropriate use of innovations in
environmental technology.
There is a clear indication that a combination of
a specific type of environmental regulation, cor-
porate culture and public policy will stimulate
innovation in environmental technology. How-
ever, the use of environmental regulation alone is
an indirect and inefficient method of stimulating
innovation in environmental technology. Insti-
tutions and policies that manage risk and uncer-
tainty should assist industry to adopt cleaner
production methods.
The ‘evolution’ of environmental regulation
identified a problem with traditional environ-
mental regulations in that they encouraged ineffi-
cient, ‘end-of-pipe’ solutions. Market mechanisms
generate incentives for the economically most
efficient solution, but they retain many of the
problems of traditional legislative environmental
regulation, including the absence of sufficient
incentives for organizations to go beyond com-
pliance. This evolution has led to the development
of self-regulations that include ISO 14001. ISO
14001 is a process or management standard that is
forming an important thread in the seamless web
model of environmental regulation. ISO 14001
supplies the framework for industry to go beyond
compliance and it encourages continous improve-
ment in environmental performance, based on a
feedback loop that measures improvement from
present performance, not an arbitrary benchmark.
The environmental result desired by organiz-
ations under traditional regulation is to meet the
required legislative standards. The result desired
by organizations under a market mechanism is to
meet the required legislative standard at the least
cost. These are contrary to the desire of organiz-
ations with a continuous improvement cycle in
their management system, and therefore, a desire
and behaviour to improve environmental per-
formance, and to move beyond compliance.
Under traditional and market regulations, organi-
zations have very little incentive to review their
environmental impacts, unless for legal reasons,
and therefore a ‘set-and-forget’ mentality may
ensue.
The incentive for adopting ISO 14001 is at
present provided by the market, although this is
starting to change as environmental regulators
begin to recognize benefits in having organiz-
ations develop environmental management
systems. The framework presented here, of a
seamless web, requires the maintenance of tra-
ditional environmental regulation; however, it
allows the ‘carrot’ to play a greater part in the
development and adoption of environmental
technology.
Modern environmental policy needs to be
developed so that industry and society gains the
maximum benefit from all the threads and inter-
actions of the seamless web, leading to better
environmental protection with the least impact
on production and competitiveness for any
organizations that accept this challenge.
A key attribute of the seamless web model is
that it provides a framework that does not rely on
any one mechanism or stakeholder, so, where one
mechanism or stakeholder may fail, another will
fill the gap, allowing for on-going environmental
protection. Furthermore, advocating a single regu-
latory mechanism is prone to failure because those
being regulated implement management changes
that reduce the effect of the relevant regulation on
their behaviour. In addition, complex authori-
tative environmental regulations require large
amounts of public resources to be fully imple-
mented and these resources are not always pro-
vided. The seamless web model provides the
flexibility to cater for different corporate cultures,
a major requirement of modern environmental
policy. It also reduces the demand on public funds
to enforce legislative environmental regulations.
Policy makers need to actively reduce risk and
uncertainty while giving incentives for industry
to be proactive, for these are the organizations
which will help solve many of our environmental
problems. The stick will still need to be main-
tained as an important mechanism to activate
laggards.
It is recognized that there is a large amount of
enlightened self-interest in the process of self-
regulation for industry. Therefore the process of
self-regulation will require external monitoring if
it is to attain credibility amongst stakeholders.
Self-regulation allows companies to be flexible
about how and when they address their environ-
mental problems, reducing associated costs and
improving efficiency. However, industry must
realize that this process will not necessarily reduce
W. J. ALTHAM AND T. F. GUERIN
Copyright  1999 John Wiley  Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment. Eco-Mgmt. Aud. 6, 61–75 (1999)
72
the level of scrutiny industry faces, but rather the
direction from which this scrutiny comes from
will shift from the government and state to other
sectors of society. Further, the required level of
environmental protection may not in all cases be
able to be achieved at no cost to industry, and in
these cases traditional regulation and market
mechanisms will be required.
The stakeholders involved in environmental
regulation do not operate in isolation. To protect
the environment, in balance with economic devel-
opment, the core aim of ESD, will require that all
stakeholders play their part in an integrated
seamless web of environmental regulation.
REFERENCES
Anonymous. (1995) What can ISO 14000 do for your
company?, Environmental Manager, 7, (5), 5–8.
Anonymous. (1996) Winning green strategies, Environ-
mental Manager, 7, (7), 11–13.
Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS). (1996) Environmen-
tal Issues: People’s Views and Practices, ABS, Australian
Government Publishing Services, Canberra.
Baker, A. (1996) Proposed Changes to Environmental
Protection Act Licensing and Fee Structure, Department of
Environmental Protection, Perth.
Begley, R. (1996) ISO 14000: a step toward industry
self-regulation, Environmental Science and Technology, 30,
(7), 298A–302A.
Blau, J.R. (1995) New ISO standard aims at leveling the
playing field for green manufacturers, Machine Design,
67, (17), 48–50.
Bovy, M.W.L. (1989) Acid rain policy in The Netherlands –
Application of mediation techniques, Ambio, 18, (8), 416.
Bridgen, P.J. (1996) ISO 14000: the worldwide reaction
of industry and governments, Environmental Quality
Management, 6, (1), 45–49.
Brown, H. (1996) Pragmatic ethics and the new consult-
ant, Total Quality Environmental Management, 5, (4),
1–6.
Brozen, Y., Groenveld, K., Maks, A. and Muysken, J. (1990)
Economic Policy and the Market – Austrian and Mainstream
Economics, Elsevier, New York.
Bureau of Industry Economics (BIE). (1992) Environmental
Regulation: the Economics of Tradable Permits – a Survey
of Theory and Practice, BIE, Australian Government
Publishing Service, Canberra.
Burns, R. and Fredericks, I. (eds). (1997) Using ISO 14001 for
Environmental Management Systems to Develop a Risk Based
Integrated Management System Throughout NOVA Corpora-
tion, Air and Waste Management Association, Pittsburgh,
PA, p 6.
Chynoweth, E. (1994) Focus on stewardship, reporting, and
small firms, Chemical Week, 155, (1), 103–104.
Colby, P.W. (1997) ISO 14000: a return to command
and control?, Environmental Quality Management, 7, (2),
61–64.
Crognale, G. (1997) Financial incentives, Environmental
Protection, 8, (5), 36–38.
Deavenport, E. (1996) Doing the right thing, Executive
Excellence, 13, (5), 12–13.
Department of Environmental Protection (DEP). (1996)
Achieving Best Practice Environmental Management, DEP,
Perth.
Dwyer, M. (1996) ISO 14001: setting a new standard in red
tape, Australian Financial Review, July 10, 18.
Epstein, M.J. and Roy, M.-J. (1997) Using ISO for improved
organizational learning and environmental management,
Environmental Quality Management, 7, (1), 21–30.
Ferrone, R. (1998) Technology 1998 analysis  forecast: the
environment, IEEE Spectrum, 35, (1), 95–99.
Grabosky, P. (1995) in: Eckersley, R. (ed.), Governing at
a Distance: Self-Regulating Green Markets. Markets, the
State and the Environment, Macmillan, Melbourne,
pp 197–228.
Greenpeace. (1996) Brent Spar Protect in North Sea, 21
November, http://www.greenpeace.org/comms/brent/
brent.html.
Greis, N.P. (1995) Technology adoption, product design,
and process change: a case study in the machine tool
industry, IEEE Transactions on Engineering Management,
42, (3).
Guerin, L.J. and Guerin, T.F. (1994) Constraints to the
adoption of agricultural and environmental innovations
and technologies: a review, Australian Journal of Exper-
imental Agriculture, 34, 549–571.
Gunningham, N. (1994a) Proactive environmental manage-
ment:business and regulatory strategies, Australian
Journal of Environmental Management, 1, (2), 121–133,
(September).
Gunningham, N. (1994b) Going beyond compliance: man-
agement of environmental risk. Environmental outlook:
law and policy, Boer, B., Fowler, R. and Gunningham, N.,
Federation Press, Leichhardt, N.S.W., 254–279.
Gustafsson, B. (1998) Scope and limits of the market
mechanism in environmental management, Ecological
Economics, 24, 2–3.
Hairston, D., Shelley, S. and Crabb, C. (1998) Emissions-
trading programs hit their stride, Chemical Engineering,
105, (6), 32–37.
Harris, P. (1996) Textile makers tap DOE labs for enviro-
technologies, Environmental Management Today, 7, (4),
22–24.
Hawken, P. (1993) The Ecology of Commerce, Weidenfeld and
Nicolson, London.
Heaton, G.R. and Banks, R.D. (1997) Towards a new
generation of environmental technology – the need for
legislative reform, Journal of Industrial Ecology, 1, (2),
23–32.
Hemenway, C.G. (1995) From Oslo with love: ISO 14001
moves towards adoption, Environment Today, 6, (7),
17–19.
Hemenway, C.G. (1996) International e-standards head
toward adoption, Environmental Management Today, 7,
(3), 30.
SEAMLESS WEB FRAMEWORK
Copyright  1999 John Wiley  Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment. Eco-Mgmt. Aud. 6, 61–75 (1999)
73
Hemphill, T.A. (1996) The new era of business regulation,
Business Horizons, 39, (4), 26–30.
Hersey, K. (1998) A close look at ISO 14000, Professional
Safety, 43, (7), 26–29.
Hesse, M.O. (1989) A new era in energy regulation, Public
Utility Fortnightly, 123, (6), 18.
Hyde, P. (1997) Environmental management, Safety and
Health Practitioner, 15, (6), 52–55.
Iwanski, M.L., Loney, J.M. and Howell, V.L. (eds). (1997)
Experiences of a Restructured Corporation in Establishing
a Corporate EMS and Audit Program in a Changing
Marketplace, Air and Waste Management Association,
Pittsburgh, PA.
Jackson, D. (1998) Product stewardship takes center stage,
Chemical Week, 160, (25), 116.
Jaffe, A.B. and Stavins, R.N. (1995) Dynamic incentives of
environmental regulations: the effects of alternative
policy instruments on technology diffusion, Journal of
Environmental Economics and Management, 29, (3 (Part 2)),
543–563.
Jancsurak, J. (1998) In pursuit of a greener-bottom line,
Appliance Manufacturer, 46, (1), E23–E25.
Johannson, L. (1994) Voluntary standards at the dawn of
ISO 14000: fit or folly for TQEM?, Total Quality Environ-
mental Management, 4, (2), 101–112.
Johannson, L. (1995) Tuning to Station WIIFY on ISO
14000: what’s in it for you? Total Quality Environmental
Management, 5, (2), 107–117.
Kanegsberg, B. (1996) Quality means business, Chemical
Marketing Reporter, 249, (15), 3–4.
Kirschner, E. (1995) Environmental management systems
get worldwide benchmark, Chemical  Engineering News,
73, (14), 13.
Klassen, R.D. and Angell, L.C. (1998) An international
comparison of environmental management in operations:
the impact of manufacturing flexibility in the US and
Germany. Journal of Operations Management, 16, (2,3),
177–194.
Konar, S. and Cohen, M. (1997) Information as regulation:
the effect of community right to know laws on toxic
emissions, Journal of Environmental Economics and
Management, 32, (1), 109–204.
Label, W.A. and Tandy, P.R. (1998) ISO 14000 envrionmen-
tal management systems: new opportunities and respon-
sibilities for internal auditors, Internal Auditing, 13, (4),
3–8.
Lepkowski, W. (1994) Export outlook modest for green
technologies, Chemical and Engineering News, 72, (14), 23.
McInerney, F. and White, S. (1995) The Total Quality
Corporation; how 10 Major Companies Turned Quality and
Environmental Challenges to Competitive Advantage in the
1990s, New York, Truman Talley.
Metcalf, K.R., Williams, P.L., Minter, J.R. and Hobson, C.M.
(1996) Environmental performance indicators for en-
hancing environmental management, Total Quality
Environmental Management, 5, (4).
Milliman, S. and Prince, R. (1989) Firm incentives to pro-
mote technological change in pollution control, Journal of
Environmental Economics and Management, 17, 247–265.
Mullin, R. (1998a) Critics look for greater commitment,
Chemical Week, 160, (25), 39–42.
Mullin, R. (1998b) Setting tough internal goals, Chemical
Week, 160, (25), 98–101.
Mullin, R. and Sissell, K. (1996) Merging business and
environment, Chemical Week, 158, (38), 52–53.
Nash, J. and Ehrenfeld, J. (1997) Codes of environmental
management practice: assessing their potential as a tool
for change, Annual Review of Energy and the Environment,
22, 487–535.
Nicklas, M. (1993) Energy politics: can we achieve a
sustainable energy path, Solar Energy, 50, (4), 287–296.
Noor-Drugan, N. (1998) Germany: Regulation or volunteer
action? Chemical Week, 160, (25), 125.
Owen, A. (1991) Tradable Emissions as a Greenhouse Response
Measure, National Capital Printing, Department of Arts,
Sport, Environment, Territories and Tourism, Canberra.
Philpot, R. (1992) Externalities policy development project:
energy sector, Department of Minerals and Energy:
innovation, economic change and sustainability, Murdoch
University Reader, 3, 102–112.
Rimich, N.C. Jr. (1996) Are you an envirophile?, Appliance
Manufacturer, 44, (9), 152.
Rondinelli, D.A. and Berry, M.A. (1997) Industry’s role in
air quality improvement: environmental management
opportunities for the 21st century, Environmental Quality
Management, 7, 1, 31–44.
Samdani, G.S. (1995) ISO 14000: new passport to world
markets, Chemical Engineering, 102, 6, 41.
Scott, A. (1998) Europe begins to measure performance,
Chemical Week, 160, 25, 111–112.
Seif, M. (1995) ISO 14000: privatizing environmental
regulation – an idea without borders. [http://www.
dep.state.pa.us/dep/deputate/pollprev/Tech_ Assistance/
Toolbox/iso14001/privat23/06/98].
Sheldon, C. (1997) ISO 14001 and beyond, Environmental
Management Systems in the Real World, Greenleaf,
Sheffield.
Snyder, J.D. (1995) ISO 14000 session in Oslo will air
performance evaluation standards, Environment Today,
6, 5.
Steinzor, R.I. (1998) Reinventing environmental regulation:
the dangerous journey from command to self-control,
Harvard Environmental Law Review, 22, 1, 103.
Stoughton, M. (1994) An Evaluation of Voluntary Programs
as Public Policies for Environmental Protection, http://
web.mit.edu/org/c/ctpid/www/tbe/theses/stough.htm.
Struebing, L. (1996) The standards at a glance, Quality
Progress, 29, 1, 24–25.
Susani, L. (1996) New moves to reduce marine pollution,
Petroleum Review, 50, 594, 320–322.
Tyler Miller, G.J. (1994) Sustaining the Earth – an Integrated
Approach, Wadsworth, California.
Webb, L. (1995) A complex environment for regulation,
Pulp and Paper International, 37, 12, 37–39.
Wilson, R.C. (1997) A variety of drivers influence an EMS
program, Pollution Engineering, 29, 9, 53–54.
Wolf, C.J. (1988) Markets or Governments – Choosing Between
Imperfect Alternatives, MIT Press, Cambridge.
Young, J. (1994) Wisconsin’s Paper Council, DNR complete
program’s first year, Pulp and Paper, 68, 9, 115–116.
W. J. ALTHAM AND T. F. GUERIN
Copyright  1999 John Wiley  Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment. Eco-Mgmt. Aud. 6, 61–75 (1999)
74
BIOGRAPHY
Dr. Turlough F. Guerin can be reached at 248
Gladstone Avenue, Coniston 2500 New South
Wales, Australia.
Email address: turloughg@hotmail.com
Dr. Guerin has expertise in environmental tech-
nology and management systems and has worked
for ICF Kiser, Hamersley Iron and Rio Tinto
RTD. He assists corporations with cross-
industry technology transfer and the integrated
management of business and EHS issues and has
advised to numerous corporations in the USA,
including the Motorola Corporation and Levine-
Fricke Engineering.
William J. Altham can be reached at Institute
for Science and Technology Policy, Murdoch
University, Perth 6510, Western Australia.
Email address: w.altham@central.murdoch.edu.au
William (Jim) Altham holds an Economics
Degree and a Master Degree in ESD. His research
interests include environmental management
systems, green corporate strategy, regulation and
innovation in clean technologies, emissions
trading and renewable energy policy.
SEAMLESS WEB FRAMEWORK
Copyright  1999 John Wiley  Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment. Eco-Mgmt. Aud. 6, 61–75 (1999)
75

Contenu connexe

Tendances

Economy, intl trade & environment
Economy, intl trade & environmentEconomy, intl trade & environment
Economy, intl trade & environmentAlejo Etchart Ortiz
 
Sustainable indicators
Sustainable indicators Sustainable indicators
Sustainable indicators BadrAlsulami1
 
Sustainability concepts
 Sustainability concepts  Sustainability concepts
Sustainability concepts BadrAlsulami1
 
Governing low carbon transitions
Governing low carbon transitionsGoverning low carbon transitions
Governing low carbon transitionsAdrianPaulSmith
 
11.pp.0054www.iiste.org call for paper-71
11.pp.0054www.iiste.org call for paper-7111.pp.0054www.iiste.org call for paper-71
11.pp.0054www.iiste.org call for paper-71Alexander Decker
 
ECO-CONTROL SYSTEM: A LITERATURE REVIEW
ECO-CONTROL SYSTEM: A LITERATURE REVIEWECO-CONTROL SYSTEM: A LITERATURE REVIEW
ECO-CONTROL SYSTEM: A LITERATURE REVIEWAhmad Alastal
 
Policy networks on climate change and ecosystem services in Peru and Brazil
Policy networks on climate change and ecosystem services in Peru and BrazilPolicy networks on climate change and ecosystem services in Peru and Brazil
Policy networks on climate change and ecosystem services in Peru and BrazilCIFOR-ICRAF
 
Agent basedmodelmiscanthus
Agent basedmodelmiscanthusAgent basedmodelmiscanthus
Agent basedmodelmiscanthusManfred Steiner
 
Business sustainabiltiy 33,52,68
Business sustainabiltiy   33,52,68Business sustainabiltiy   33,52,68
Business sustainabiltiy 33,52,68domsr
 
CIFOR’s contribution to ASFCC: evidence, capacity building and engagement
CIFOR’s contribution to ASFCC: evidence, capacity building and engagementCIFOR’s contribution to ASFCC: evidence, capacity building and engagement
CIFOR’s contribution to ASFCC: evidence, capacity building and engagementCIFOR-ICRAF
 
Governing Low Carbon Transitions by Adrian Smith, SPRU – Science & Technology...
Governing Low Carbon Transitions by Adrian Smith, SPRU – Science & Technology...Governing Low Carbon Transitions by Adrian Smith, SPRU – Science & Technology...
Governing Low Carbon Transitions by Adrian Smith, SPRU – Science & Technology...British Sociological Association
 
Build in eco agroindustry park based on environmental management system to in...
Build in eco agroindustry park based on environmental management system to in...Build in eco agroindustry park based on environmental management system to in...
Build in eco agroindustry park based on environmental management system to in...Alexander Decker
 

Tendances (16)

C382135.pdf
C382135.pdfC382135.pdf
C382135.pdf
 
Economy, intl trade & environment
Economy, intl trade & environmentEconomy, intl trade & environment
Economy, intl trade & environment
 
Sustainable indicators
Sustainable indicators Sustainable indicators
Sustainable indicators
 
Sustainability concepts
 Sustainability concepts  Sustainability concepts
Sustainability concepts
 
CH 14 SUSTAINABILITY
CH  14  SUSTAINABILITY CH  14  SUSTAINABILITY
CH 14 SUSTAINABILITY
 
Governing low carbon transitions
Governing low carbon transitionsGoverning low carbon transitions
Governing low carbon transitions
 
Institutions and governance for CCAFS - Heike Schroeder
Institutions and governance for CCAFS - Heike SchroederInstitutions and governance for CCAFS - Heike Schroeder
Institutions and governance for CCAFS - Heike Schroeder
 
11.pp.0054www.iiste.org call for paper-71
11.pp.0054www.iiste.org call for paper-7111.pp.0054www.iiste.org call for paper-71
11.pp.0054www.iiste.org call for paper-71
 
ECO-CONTROL SYSTEM: A LITERATURE REVIEW
ECO-CONTROL SYSTEM: A LITERATURE REVIEWECO-CONTROL SYSTEM: A LITERATURE REVIEW
ECO-CONTROL SYSTEM: A LITERATURE REVIEW
 
Policy networks on climate change and ecosystem services in Peru and Brazil
Policy networks on climate change and ecosystem services in Peru and BrazilPolicy networks on climate change and ecosystem services in Peru and Brazil
Policy networks on climate change and ecosystem services in Peru and Brazil
 
Definitions for Task 24
Definitions for Task 24Definitions for Task 24
Definitions for Task 24
 
Agent basedmodelmiscanthus
Agent basedmodelmiscanthusAgent basedmodelmiscanthus
Agent basedmodelmiscanthus
 
Business sustainabiltiy 33,52,68
Business sustainabiltiy   33,52,68Business sustainabiltiy   33,52,68
Business sustainabiltiy 33,52,68
 
CIFOR’s contribution to ASFCC: evidence, capacity building and engagement
CIFOR’s contribution to ASFCC: evidence, capacity building and engagementCIFOR’s contribution to ASFCC: evidence, capacity building and engagement
CIFOR’s contribution to ASFCC: evidence, capacity building and engagement
 
Governing Low Carbon Transitions by Adrian Smith, SPRU – Science & Technology...
Governing Low Carbon Transitions by Adrian Smith, SPRU – Science & Technology...Governing Low Carbon Transitions by Adrian Smith, SPRU – Science & Technology...
Governing Low Carbon Transitions by Adrian Smith, SPRU – Science & Technology...
 
Build in eco agroindustry park based on environmental management system to in...
Build in eco agroindustry park based on environmental management system to in...Build in eco agroindustry park based on environmental management system to in...
Build in eco agroindustry park based on environmental management system to in...
 

En vedette

Environmental and natural resources economics
Environmental and natural resources economicsEnvironmental and natural resources economics
Environmental and natural resources economicsMWAIZAVUZYA
 
Poverty, Environmental Degradation, and Human Rights: Exploring the Nexus
Poverty, Environmental Degradation, and Human Rights: Exploring the NexusPoverty, Environmental Degradation, and Human Rights: Exploring the Nexus
Poverty, Environmental Degradation, and Human Rights: Exploring the NexusJosh Gellers
 
Economics hsc topic 3
Economics hsc topic 3Economics hsc topic 3
Economics hsc topic 3Tom Wilkinson
 
Economics hsc topic 1
Economics hsc topic 1Economics hsc topic 1
Economics hsc topic 1Tom Wilkinson
 
Lewis Theory Of Economic Development
Lewis Theory Of Economic DevelopmentLewis Theory Of Economic Development
Lewis Theory Of Economic Developmentrehan23may
 

En vedette (8)

Environmental and natural resources economics
Environmental and natural resources economicsEnvironmental and natural resources economics
Environmental and natural resources economics
 
Poverty, Environmental Degradation, and Human Rights: Exploring the Nexus
Poverty, Environmental Degradation, and Human Rights: Exploring the NexusPoverty, Environmental Degradation, and Human Rights: Exploring the Nexus
Poverty, Environmental Degradation, and Human Rights: Exploring the Nexus
 
Economics hsc topic 3
Economics hsc topic 3Economics hsc topic 3
Economics hsc topic 3
 
Economics hsc topic 1
Economics hsc topic 1Economics hsc topic 1
Economics hsc topic 1
 
Environmental economics
Environmental economicsEnvironmental economics
Environmental economics
 
Lewis Theory Of Economic Development
Lewis Theory Of Economic DevelopmentLewis Theory Of Economic Development
Lewis Theory Of Economic Development
 
operations management
operations managementoperations management
operations management
 
2.4 Market Failure
2.4 Market Failure2.4 Market Failure
2.4 Market Failure
 

Similaire à ENVIRONMENTAL SELF-REGULATION AND SUSTAINABLE ECONOMIC GROWTH: THE SEAMLESS WEB FRAMEWORK

Effect of ecodesign practices on the financial performance of manufacturing f...
Effect of ecodesign practices on the financial performance of manufacturing f...Effect of ecodesign practices on the financial performance of manufacturing f...
Effect of ecodesign practices on the financial performance of manufacturing f...Martin Otundo
 
Corporate Environmental Management – A New Paradigm Emerges
Corporate Environmental Management – A New Paradigm EmergesCorporate Environmental Management – A New Paradigm Emerges
Corporate Environmental Management – A New Paradigm EmergesTurlough Guerin GAICD FGIA
 
Whitepaper_7.31.14
Whitepaper_7.31.14Whitepaper_7.31.14
Whitepaper_7.31.14Phan Anh
 
Legislative intent behind environmental law
Legislative intent behind environmental lawLegislative intent behind environmental law
Legislative intent behind environmental lawAkash Patel
 
11.pp.0054www.iiste.org call for paper-71
11.pp.0054www.iiste.org call for paper-7111.pp.0054www.iiste.org call for paper-71
11.pp.0054www.iiste.org call for paper-71Alexander Decker
 
The Impacts of EnvironmentalRegulations on Competitiveness.docx
The Impacts of EnvironmentalRegulations on Competitiveness.docxThe Impacts of EnvironmentalRegulations on Competitiveness.docx
The Impacts of EnvironmentalRegulations on Competitiveness.docxarnoldmeredith47041
 
The Impacts of EnvironmentalRegulations on Competitiveness.docx
The Impacts of EnvironmentalRegulations on Competitiveness.docxThe Impacts of EnvironmentalRegulations on Competitiveness.docx
The Impacts of EnvironmentalRegulations on Competitiveness.docxrtodd33
 
An Essay On Innovations For Sustainable Development
An Essay On Innovations For Sustainable DevelopmentAn Essay On Innovations For Sustainable Development
An Essay On Innovations For Sustainable DevelopmentLaurie Smith
 
Role of Green Issues of Mining Supply Chain on Sustainable Development
Role of Green Issues of Mining Supply Chain on Sustainable DevelopmentRole of Green Issues of Mining Supply Chain on Sustainable Development
Role of Green Issues of Mining Supply Chain on Sustainable Developmentirwan zulkifli
 
Role of green issues of mining supply chain on
Role of green issues of mining supply chain onRole of green issues of mining supply chain on
Role of green issues of mining supply chain onAlfi Nugraha
 
Green Rating Project, Environmental Information Disclosure Programme
Green Rating Project, Environmental Information Disclosure ProgrammeGreen Rating Project, Environmental Information Disclosure Programme
Green Rating Project, Environmental Information Disclosure ProgrammeAmit Chauhan
 
9789812871633 c2
9789812871633 c29789812871633 c2
9789812871633 c2Agus Witono
 
Green supply chain management
Green supply chain managementGreen supply chain management
Green supply chain managementAlexander Decker
 
Running Head THE PROSPECTUSTHE PROSPECTUS .docx
Running Head THE PROSPECTUSTHE PROSPECTUS                      .docxRunning Head THE PROSPECTUSTHE PROSPECTUS                      .docx
Running Head THE PROSPECTUSTHE PROSPECTUS .docxagnesdcarey33086
 
An Application of an Ecological Model to Explain the Growth of Strategies of ...
An Application of an Ecological Model to Explain the Growth of Strategies of ...An Application of an Ecological Model to Explain the Growth of Strategies of ...
An Application of an Ecological Model to Explain the Growth of Strategies of ...Claudia Acosta
 
GREEN MANAGEMENT: OPPORTUNITIES AND CHALLENGES IN INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS FOR ...
GREEN MANAGEMENT: OPPORTUNITIES AND CHALLENGES IN INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS FOR ...GREEN MANAGEMENT: OPPORTUNITIES AND CHALLENGES IN INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS FOR ...
GREEN MANAGEMENT: OPPORTUNITIES AND CHALLENGES IN INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS FOR ...Muhammad Nazri Abdul Halim
 
PG in Delhi NCR | Stulity- A Student Utility Portal
PG in Delhi NCR | Stulity- A Student Utility PortalPG in Delhi NCR | Stulity- A Student Utility Portal
PG in Delhi NCR | Stulity- A Student Utility PortalStulity India
 
Green Marketing: A Marketing Mix concept
Green Marketing: A Marketing Mix conceptGreen Marketing: A Marketing Mix concept
Green Marketing: A Marketing Mix conceptEECJOURNAL
 
Why join a carbon club? A study of the banks participating in the Brazilian "...
Why join a carbon club? A study of the banks participating in the Brazilian "...Why join a carbon club? A study of the banks participating in the Brazilian "...
Why join a carbon club? A study of the banks participating in the Brazilian "...FGV Brazil
 
Exploring the Impact of Environmental Sustainability on Firm Performance in t...
Exploring the Impact of Environmental Sustainability on Firm Performance in t...Exploring the Impact of Environmental Sustainability on Firm Performance in t...
Exploring the Impact of Environmental Sustainability on Firm Performance in t...Business, Management and Economics Research
 

Similaire à ENVIRONMENTAL SELF-REGULATION AND SUSTAINABLE ECONOMIC GROWTH: THE SEAMLESS WEB FRAMEWORK (20)

Effect of ecodesign practices on the financial performance of manufacturing f...
Effect of ecodesign practices on the financial performance of manufacturing f...Effect of ecodesign practices on the financial performance of manufacturing f...
Effect of ecodesign practices on the financial performance of manufacturing f...
 
Corporate Environmental Management – A New Paradigm Emerges
Corporate Environmental Management – A New Paradigm EmergesCorporate Environmental Management – A New Paradigm Emerges
Corporate Environmental Management – A New Paradigm Emerges
 
Whitepaper_7.31.14
Whitepaper_7.31.14Whitepaper_7.31.14
Whitepaper_7.31.14
 
Legislative intent behind environmental law
Legislative intent behind environmental lawLegislative intent behind environmental law
Legislative intent behind environmental law
 
11.pp.0054www.iiste.org call for paper-71
11.pp.0054www.iiste.org call for paper-7111.pp.0054www.iiste.org call for paper-71
11.pp.0054www.iiste.org call for paper-71
 
The Impacts of EnvironmentalRegulations on Competitiveness.docx
The Impacts of EnvironmentalRegulations on Competitiveness.docxThe Impacts of EnvironmentalRegulations on Competitiveness.docx
The Impacts of EnvironmentalRegulations on Competitiveness.docx
 
The Impacts of EnvironmentalRegulations on Competitiveness.docx
The Impacts of EnvironmentalRegulations on Competitiveness.docxThe Impacts of EnvironmentalRegulations on Competitiveness.docx
The Impacts of EnvironmentalRegulations on Competitiveness.docx
 
An Essay On Innovations For Sustainable Development
An Essay On Innovations For Sustainable DevelopmentAn Essay On Innovations For Sustainable Development
An Essay On Innovations For Sustainable Development
 
Role of Green Issues of Mining Supply Chain on Sustainable Development
Role of Green Issues of Mining Supply Chain on Sustainable DevelopmentRole of Green Issues of Mining Supply Chain on Sustainable Development
Role of Green Issues of Mining Supply Chain on Sustainable Development
 
Role of green issues of mining supply chain on
Role of green issues of mining supply chain onRole of green issues of mining supply chain on
Role of green issues of mining supply chain on
 
Green Rating Project, Environmental Information Disclosure Programme
Green Rating Project, Environmental Information Disclosure ProgrammeGreen Rating Project, Environmental Information Disclosure Programme
Green Rating Project, Environmental Information Disclosure Programme
 
9789812871633 c2
9789812871633 c29789812871633 c2
9789812871633 c2
 
Green supply chain management
Green supply chain managementGreen supply chain management
Green supply chain management
 
Running Head THE PROSPECTUSTHE PROSPECTUS .docx
Running Head THE PROSPECTUSTHE PROSPECTUS                      .docxRunning Head THE PROSPECTUSTHE PROSPECTUS                      .docx
Running Head THE PROSPECTUSTHE PROSPECTUS .docx
 
An Application of an Ecological Model to Explain the Growth of Strategies of ...
An Application of an Ecological Model to Explain the Growth of Strategies of ...An Application of an Ecological Model to Explain the Growth of Strategies of ...
An Application of an Ecological Model to Explain the Growth of Strategies of ...
 
GREEN MANAGEMENT: OPPORTUNITIES AND CHALLENGES IN INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS FOR ...
GREEN MANAGEMENT: OPPORTUNITIES AND CHALLENGES IN INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS FOR ...GREEN MANAGEMENT: OPPORTUNITIES AND CHALLENGES IN INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS FOR ...
GREEN MANAGEMENT: OPPORTUNITIES AND CHALLENGES IN INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS FOR ...
 
PG in Delhi NCR | Stulity- A Student Utility Portal
PG in Delhi NCR | Stulity- A Student Utility PortalPG in Delhi NCR | Stulity- A Student Utility Portal
PG in Delhi NCR | Stulity- A Student Utility Portal
 
Green Marketing: A Marketing Mix concept
Green Marketing: A Marketing Mix conceptGreen Marketing: A Marketing Mix concept
Green Marketing: A Marketing Mix concept
 
Why join a carbon club? A study of the banks participating in the Brazilian "...
Why join a carbon club? A study of the banks participating in the Brazilian "...Why join a carbon club? A study of the banks participating in the Brazilian "...
Why join a carbon club? A study of the banks participating in the Brazilian "...
 
Exploring the Impact of Environmental Sustainability on Firm Performance in t...
Exploring the Impact of Environmental Sustainability on Firm Performance in t...Exploring the Impact of Environmental Sustainability on Firm Performance in t...
Exploring the Impact of Environmental Sustainability on Firm Performance in t...
 

Plus de Turlough Guerin GAICD FGIA

How to work with petroleum hydrocarbon suppliers to reduce and eliminate cont...
How to work with petroleum hydrocarbon suppliers to reduce and eliminate cont...How to work with petroleum hydrocarbon suppliers to reduce and eliminate cont...
How to work with petroleum hydrocarbon suppliers to reduce and eliminate cont...Turlough Guerin GAICD FGIA
 
Harvard x Course Notes - Technology Entrepreneurship: Lab to Market
Harvard x Course Notes - Technology Entrepreneurship: Lab to MarketHarvard x Course Notes - Technology Entrepreneurship: Lab to Market
Harvard x Course Notes - Technology Entrepreneurship: Lab to MarketTurlough Guerin GAICD FGIA
 
Using Telecommunications to Reduce Your Organisation's Carbon Footprint
Using Telecommunications to Reduce Your Organisation's Carbon FootprintUsing Telecommunications to Reduce Your Organisation's Carbon Footprint
Using Telecommunications to Reduce Your Organisation's Carbon FootprintTurlough Guerin GAICD FGIA
 
Precincts to Support the Delivery of Zero Energy
Precincts to Support the Delivery of Zero EnergyPrecincts to Support the Delivery of Zero Energy
Precincts to Support the Delivery of Zero EnergyTurlough Guerin GAICD FGIA
 
Are your sustainability projects resonating with the business?
Are your sustainability projects resonating with the business?Are your sustainability projects resonating with the business?
Are your sustainability projects resonating with the business?Turlough Guerin GAICD FGIA
 
Harvardx - Technology Entreprenuership - Lab to Market
Harvardx - Technology Entreprenuership - Lab to MarketHarvardx - Technology Entreprenuership - Lab to Market
Harvardx - Technology Entreprenuership - Lab to MarketTurlough Guerin GAICD FGIA
 
Foundations for Net Zero Target Setting Using a Science Based Approach
Foundations for Net Zero Target Setting Using a Science Based ApproachFoundations for Net Zero Target Setting Using a Science Based Approach
Foundations for Net Zero Target Setting Using a Science Based ApproachTurlough Guerin GAICD FGIA
 
Health of-the-australian-construction-industry-research-report
Health of-the-australian-construction-industry-research-reportHealth of-the-australian-construction-industry-research-report
Health of-the-australian-construction-industry-research-reportTurlough Guerin GAICD FGIA
 

Plus de Turlough Guerin GAICD FGIA (20)

Climate Risk Governance Guide
Climate Risk Governance GuideClimate Risk Governance Guide
Climate Risk Governance Guide
 
Australian Bushfire Climate Plan
Australian Bushfire Climate PlanAustralian Bushfire Climate Plan
Australian Bushfire Climate Plan
 
How to work with petroleum hydrocarbon suppliers to reduce and eliminate cont...
How to work with petroleum hydrocarbon suppliers to reduce and eliminate cont...How to work with petroleum hydrocarbon suppliers to reduce and eliminate cont...
How to work with petroleum hydrocarbon suppliers to reduce and eliminate cont...
 
Harvard x Course Notes - Technology Entrepreneurship: Lab to Market
Harvard x Course Notes - Technology Entrepreneurship: Lab to MarketHarvard x Course Notes - Technology Entrepreneurship: Lab to Market
Harvard x Course Notes - Technology Entrepreneurship: Lab to Market
 
The Rise of Megaprojects
The Rise of MegaprojectsThe Rise of Megaprojects
The Rise of Megaprojects
 
Using Telecommunications to Reduce Your Organisation's Carbon Footprint
Using Telecommunications to Reduce Your Organisation's Carbon FootprintUsing Telecommunications to Reduce Your Organisation's Carbon Footprint
Using Telecommunications to Reduce Your Organisation's Carbon Footprint
 
Bringing Embodied Carbon Upfront
Bringing Embodied Carbon UpfrontBringing Embodied Carbon Upfront
Bringing Embodied Carbon Upfront
 
A New Choice Australias Climate for Growth
A New Choice Australias Climate for GrowthA New Choice Australias Climate for Growth
A New Choice Australias Climate for Growth
 
Roadmap Reducing Food Waste
Roadmap Reducing Food WasteRoadmap Reducing Food Waste
Roadmap Reducing Food Waste
 
Building the Case-for Net Zero
Building the Case-for Net ZeroBuilding the Case-for Net Zero
Building the Case-for Net Zero
 
PWC State of Climate Tech 2020
PWC State of Climate Tech 2020PWC State of Climate Tech 2020
PWC State of Climate Tech 2020
 
First Low Emissions Technology Statement 2020
First Low Emissions Technology Statement 2020First Low Emissions Technology Statement 2020
First Low Emissions Technology Statement 2020
 
The Next Normal in Construction
The Next Normal in Construction The Next Normal in Construction
The Next Normal in Construction
 
Helping Australia Bounce Back
Helping Australia Bounce BackHelping Australia Bounce Back
Helping Australia Bounce Back
 
Sustainable Finance Industry Guide
Sustainable Finance Industry GuideSustainable Finance Industry Guide
Sustainable Finance Industry Guide
 
Precincts to Support the Delivery of Zero Energy
Precincts to Support the Delivery of Zero EnergyPrecincts to Support the Delivery of Zero Energy
Precincts to Support the Delivery of Zero Energy
 
Are your sustainability projects resonating with the business?
Are your sustainability projects resonating with the business?Are your sustainability projects resonating with the business?
Are your sustainability projects resonating with the business?
 
Harvardx - Technology Entreprenuership - Lab to Market
Harvardx - Technology Entreprenuership - Lab to MarketHarvardx - Technology Entreprenuership - Lab to Market
Harvardx - Technology Entreprenuership - Lab to Market
 
Foundations for Net Zero Target Setting Using a Science Based Approach
Foundations for Net Zero Target Setting Using a Science Based ApproachFoundations for Net Zero Target Setting Using a Science Based Approach
Foundations for Net Zero Target Setting Using a Science Based Approach
 
Health of-the-australian-construction-industry-research-report
Health of-the-australian-construction-industry-research-reportHealth of-the-australian-construction-industry-research-report
Health of-the-australian-construction-industry-research-report
 

Dernier

Mumbai Call Girls, 💞 Prity 9892124323, Navi Mumbai Call girls
Mumbai Call Girls, 💞  Prity 9892124323, Navi Mumbai Call girlsMumbai Call Girls, 💞  Prity 9892124323, Navi Mumbai Call girls
Mumbai Call Girls, 💞 Prity 9892124323, Navi Mumbai Call girlsPooja Nehwal
 
Call Girls Pune Airport Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance Booking
Call Girls Pune Airport Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance BookingCall Girls Pune Airport Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance Booking
Call Girls Pune Airport Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance Bookingtanu pandey
 
VIP Call Girl Gorakhpur Aashi 8250192130 Independent Escort Service Gorakhpur
VIP Call Girl Gorakhpur Aashi 8250192130 Independent Escort Service GorakhpurVIP Call Girl Gorakhpur Aashi 8250192130 Independent Escort Service Gorakhpur
VIP Call Girl Gorakhpur Aashi 8250192130 Independent Escort Service GorakhpurSuhani Kapoor
 
(DIYA) Call Girls Sinhagad Road ( 7001035870 ) HI-Fi Pune Escorts Service
(DIYA) Call Girls Sinhagad Road ( 7001035870 ) HI-Fi Pune Escorts Service(DIYA) Call Girls Sinhagad Road ( 7001035870 ) HI-Fi Pune Escorts Service
(DIYA) Call Girls Sinhagad Road ( 7001035870 ) HI-Fi Pune Escorts Serviceranjana rawat
 
(ANAYA) Call Girls Hadapsar ( 7001035870 ) HI-Fi Pune Escorts Service
(ANAYA) Call Girls Hadapsar ( 7001035870 ) HI-Fi Pune Escorts Service(ANAYA) Call Girls Hadapsar ( 7001035870 ) HI-Fi Pune Escorts Service
(ANAYA) Call Girls Hadapsar ( 7001035870 ) HI-Fi Pune Escorts Serviceranjana rawat
 
NO1 Verified kala jadu karne wale ka contact number kala jadu karne wale baba...
NO1 Verified kala jadu karne wale ka contact number kala jadu karne wale baba...NO1 Verified kala jadu karne wale ka contact number kala jadu karne wale baba...
NO1 Verified kala jadu karne wale ka contact number kala jadu karne wale baba...Amil baba
 
VIP Call Girls Service Chaitanyapuri Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
VIP Call Girls Service Chaitanyapuri Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130VIP Call Girls Service Chaitanyapuri Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
VIP Call Girls Service Chaitanyapuri Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130Suhani Kapoor
 
The Most Attractive Pune Call Girls Shirwal 8250192130 Will You Miss This Cha...
The Most Attractive Pune Call Girls Shirwal 8250192130 Will You Miss This Cha...The Most Attractive Pune Call Girls Shirwal 8250192130 Will You Miss This Cha...
The Most Attractive Pune Call Girls Shirwal 8250192130 Will You Miss This Cha...ranjana rawat
 
DENR EPR Law Compliance Updates April 2024
DENR EPR Law Compliance Updates April 2024DENR EPR Law Compliance Updates April 2024
DENR EPR Law Compliance Updates April 2024itadmin50
 
Contact Number Call Girls Service In Goa 9316020077 Goa Call Girls Service
Contact Number Call Girls Service In Goa  9316020077 Goa  Call Girls ServiceContact Number Call Girls Service In Goa  9316020077 Goa  Call Girls Service
Contact Number Call Girls Service In Goa 9316020077 Goa Call Girls Servicesexy call girls service in goa
 
(PARI) Viman Nagar Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pune ...
(PARI) Viman Nagar Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pune ...(PARI) Viman Nagar Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pune ...
(PARI) Viman Nagar Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pune ...ranjana rawat
 
(RIYA) Kalyani Nagar Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...
(RIYA) Kalyani Nagar Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...(RIYA) Kalyani Nagar Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...
(RIYA) Kalyani Nagar Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...ranjana rawat
 
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Parvati Darshan 6297143586 Call Hot I...
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Parvati Darshan  6297143586 Call Hot I...Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Parvati Darshan  6297143586 Call Hot I...
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Parvati Darshan 6297143586 Call Hot I...Call Girls in Nagpur High Profile
 
VVIP Pune Call Girls Koregaon Park (7001035870) Pune Escorts Nearby with Comp...
VVIP Pune Call Girls Koregaon Park (7001035870) Pune Escorts Nearby with Comp...VVIP Pune Call Girls Koregaon Park (7001035870) Pune Escorts Nearby with Comp...
VVIP Pune Call Girls Koregaon Park (7001035870) Pune Escorts Nearby with Comp...Call Girls in Nagpur High Profile
 
Low Rate Call Girls Bikaner Anika 8250192130 Independent Escort Service Bikaner
Low Rate Call Girls Bikaner Anika 8250192130 Independent Escort Service BikanerLow Rate Call Girls Bikaner Anika 8250192130 Independent Escort Service Bikaner
Low Rate Call Girls Bikaner Anika 8250192130 Independent Escort Service BikanerSuhani Kapoor
 

Dernier (20)

Green Marketing
Green MarketingGreen Marketing
Green Marketing
 
Mumbai Call Girls, 💞 Prity 9892124323, Navi Mumbai Call girls
Mumbai Call Girls, 💞  Prity 9892124323, Navi Mumbai Call girlsMumbai Call Girls, 💞  Prity 9892124323, Navi Mumbai Call girls
Mumbai Call Girls, 💞 Prity 9892124323, Navi Mumbai Call girls
 
Call Girls Pune Airport Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance Booking
Call Girls Pune Airport Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance BookingCall Girls Pune Airport Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance Booking
Call Girls Pune Airport Call Me 7737669865 Budget Friendly No Advance Booking
 
VIP Call Girl Gorakhpur Aashi 8250192130 Independent Escort Service Gorakhpur
VIP Call Girl Gorakhpur Aashi 8250192130 Independent Escort Service GorakhpurVIP Call Girl Gorakhpur Aashi 8250192130 Independent Escort Service Gorakhpur
VIP Call Girl Gorakhpur Aashi 8250192130 Independent Escort Service Gorakhpur
 
(DIYA) Call Girls Sinhagad Road ( 7001035870 ) HI-Fi Pune Escorts Service
(DIYA) Call Girls Sinhagad Road ( 7001035870 ) HI-Fi Pune Escorts Service(DIYA) Call Girls Sinhagad Road ( 7001035870 ) HI-Fi Pune Escorts Service
(DIYA) Call Girls Sinhagad Road ( 7001035870 ) HI-Fi Pune Escorts Service
 
(ANAYA) Call Girls Hadapsar ( 7001035870 ) HI-Fi Pune Escorts Service
(ANAYA) Call Girls Hadapsar ( 7001035870 ) HI-Fi Pune Escorts Service(ANAYA) Call Girls Hadapsar ( 7001035870 ) HI-Fi Pune Escorts Service
(ANAYA) Call Girls Hadapsar ( 7001035870 ) HI-Fi Pune Escorts Service
 
NO1 Verified kala jadu karne wale ka contact number kala jadu karne wale baba...
NO1 Verified kala jadu karne wale ka contact number kala jadu karne wale baba...NO1 Verified kala jadu karne wale ka contact number kala jadu karne wale baba...
NO1 Verified kala jadu karne wale ka contact number kala jadu karne wale baba...
 
Call Girls In Pratap Nagar꧁❤ 🔝 9953056974🔝❤꧂ Escort ServiCe
Call Girls In Pratap Nagar꧁❤ 🔝 9953056974🔝❤꧂ Escort ServiCeCall Girls In Pratap Nagar꧁❤ 🔝 9953056974🔝❤꧂ Escort ServiCe
Call Girls In Pratap Nagar꧁❤ 🔝 9953056974🔝❤꧂ Escort ServiCe
 
VIP Call Girls Service Chaitanyapuri Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
VIP Call Girls Service Chaitanyapuri Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130VIP Call Girls Service Chaitanyapuri Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
VIP Call Girls Service Chaitanyapuri Hyderabad Call +91-8250192130
 
The Most Attractive Pune Call Girls Shirwal 8250192130 Will You Miss This Cha...
The Most Attractive Pune Call Girls Shirwal 8250192130 Will You Miss This Cha...The Most Attractive Pune Call Girls Shirwal 8250192130 Will You Miss This Cha...
The Most Attractive Pune Call Girls Shirwal 8250192130 Will You Miss This Cha...
 
Model Call Girl in Rajiv Chowk Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝
Model Call Girl in Rajiv Chowk Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝Model Call Girl in Rajiv Chowk Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝
Model Call Girl in Rajiv Chowk Delhi reach out to us at 🔝9953056974🔝
 
DENR EPR Law Compliance Updates April 2024
DENR EPR Law Compliance Updates April 2024DENR EPR Law Compliance Updates April 2024
DENR EPR Law Compliance Updates April 2024
 
Contact Number Call Girls Service In Goa 9316020077 Goa Call Girls Service
Contact Number Call Girls Service In Goa  9316020077 Goa  Call Girls ServiceContact Number Call Girls Service In Goa  9316020077 Goa  Call Girls Service
Contact Number Call Girls Service In Goa 9316020077 Goa Call Girls Service
 
(PARI) Viman Nagar Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pune ...
(PARI) Viman Nagar Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pune ...(PARI) Viman Nagar Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pune ...
(PARI) Viman Nagar Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pune ...
 
(RIYA) Kalyani Nagar Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...
(RIYA) Kalyani Nagar Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...(RIYA) Kalyani Nagar Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...
(RIYA) Kalyani Nagar Call Girls Just Call 7001035870 [ Cash on Delivery ] Pun...
 
E Waste Management
E Waste ManagementE Waste Management
E Waste Management
 
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Parvati Darshan 6297143586 Call Hot I...
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Parvati Darshan  6297143586 Call Hot I...Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Parvati Darshan  6297143586 Call Hot I...
Booking open Available Pune Call Girls Parvati Darshan 6297143586 Call Hot I...
 
VVIP Pune Call Girls Koregaon Park (7001035870) Pune Escorts Nearby with Comp...
VVIP Pune Call Girls Koregaon Park (7001035870) Pune Escorts Nearby with Comp...VVIP Pune Call Girls Koregaon Park (7001035870) Pune Escorts Nearby with Comp...
VVIP Pune Call Girls Koregaon Park (7001035870) Pune Escorts Nearby with Comp...
 
Low Rate Call Girls Bikaner Anika 8250192130 Independent Escort Service Bikaner
Low Rate Call Girls Bikaner Anika 8250192130 Independent Escort Service BikanerLow Rate Call Girls Bikaner Anika 8250192130 Independent Escort Service Bikaner
Low Rate Call Girls Bikaner Anika 8250192130 Independent Escort Service Bikaner
 
young Whatsapp Call Girls in Delhi Cantt🔝 9953056974 🔝 escort service
young Whatsapp Call Girls in Delhi Cantt🔝 9953056974 🔝 escort serviceyoung Whatsapp Call Girls in Delhi Cantt🔝 9953056974 🔝 escort service
young Whatsapp Call Girls in Delhi Cantt🔝 9953056974 🔝 escort service
 

ENVIRONMENTAL SELF-REGULATION AND SUSTAINABLE ECONOMIC GROWTH: THE SEAMLESS WEB FRAMEWORK

  • 1. Eco-Management and Auditing Eco-Mgmt. Aud. 6, 61–75 (1999) ENVIRONMENTAL SELF-REGULATION AND SUSTAINABLE ECONOMIC GROWTH: THE SEAMLESS WEB FRAMEWORK William J. Altham1 and Turlough F. Guerin2 * 1 Murdoch University, Australia 2 Environmental Adviser, USA A ‘seamless web’ framework of environmental regulation is emerging. The seamless web provides a comprehensive and holistic framework for facilitating the transition to ecologically sustainable development (ESD). This seamless web comprises numerous threads, that is regulators and regulatory mechanisms, which provide the framework in which society may attain effective protection from environmental degradation. Regulatory bodies include government and state regulators, NGOs, industry peers, investors and consumers. Regulatory mechanisms and incentives range through lower costs, increased market share and long term resource access and sanctions ranging through incarceration of directors, license withdrawal, fines, falling profits, loss of market share and falling investor confidence. We conclude that self-regulation is a useful mechanism to promote environmental protection, and that industry will increasingly face pressure to improve its environmental performance from many stakeholders. The seamless web framework recognizes the pivotal role of industry in environmental regulation, catering for a range of corporate cultures, and thereby stimulating innovation of appropriate technology. Copyright 1999 John Wiley Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment. Accepted 3 February 1999 INTRODUCTION T he environment, according to many opinion polls, is the issue of the ‘future’ (Gunningham, 1994a). Concern for the environment has led to many innovations, fora and institutions that study, discuss or attempt to provide solutions for our environmentally unsus- tainable social and economic system. The World Business Council for Sustainable Development, Brundtland Report, Agenda 21 and the Earth Summit, Climate Change Convention and Ozone Conventions are just some examples of institu- tional responses to environmental problems. Many of these responses see industry involve- ment, through self-regulation in a broad sense, as a critical component of a successful resolution of these issues (Anonymous, 1996; Deavenport, *Correspondence to: Dr. Turlough F. Guerin, 1691 E Green Briars Drive, Suite 3821, Schaumburg, IL 60173, USA. CCC 0968-9427/99/020061–15 $17.50 Copyright 1999 John Wiley Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment.
  • 2. 1996; Hemphill, 1996; Nash and Ehrenfeld, 1997; Jackson, 1998; Mullin, 1998a b; Noor-Drugan, 1998; Scott, 1998). There is ongoing debate regarding the most effective forms of environmental regulation (Mullin and Sissell, 1996). Environmental regula- tions are required to correct market failures, while offering protection to the environment and future generations. Full costs should be considered by the market to ensure the correct allocation of resources. However, environmental regulations are open to political interference in a climate where there are high levels of uncertainty as to future technology, resource availability, industry growth, innovation and employment. Self-regulation is increasingly being promoted as an efficient form of regulation and is being incorporated into corporate environmental policy making and implementation (Seif, 1995; Sheldon, 1997). However, this has created heated debate within society. Industry fears that self-regulation may become part of standard regulatory practice (Colby, 1997) under political pressure from envi- ronmentalists. Industry also fears that a voluntary industry framework, to allow companies to go beyond environmental compliance within their own time-frame, could become another regulatory weapon by which they will be controlled, that it would hit small business particularly hard and that it could become a barrier to trade and increase commodity prices (Blau, 1995; Samdani, 1995; Bridgen, 1996; Dwyer, 1996). Certain industries also see the introduction of further environmen- tal standards as additional, non-business work (Webb, 1995). On the other hand, environmental- ists maintain that self-regulation is a move to ‘pull the wool’ over the public’s eyes, with the environ- mental movement having a distrust of initiatives from industry (Mullin, 1998a b). Others argue that the command-and-control framework, which is the basis for most environmental regulations, is economically inefficient and have proposed a variety of market-based alternatives. The most prominent alternative is industry self-regulation, which affords industry the opportunity to gain exemptions from specific command-and-control requirements by proposing different methods for achieving underlying environmental goals (Steinzor, 1998). Industry needs to take an active role in the development of all forms of environmental regulation if it wishes to ensure a balanced debate with workable solutions. To encourage proactive industry involvement in setting and implementing corporate environmental policy will require the development of institutions and government and state policies that manage risk and uncer- tainty for industry (Lepkowski, 1994; Jaffe and Stavins, 1995). The development of feedback loops, or improvement cycles, within company management systems, which leads to continuous improvement, is important if industry is going to demonstrate environmental leadership. The commercial benefits of such a proactive approach to environmental management are becoming clear in numerous industries (Greis, 1995; Ferrone, 1998; Jancsurak, 1998). Traditionally, environ- mental issues and concerns have been viewed as a constraint to businesses and have resulted in environmental managers relying heavily on a reactive, compliance-based approach to justify change. Businesses are now recognizing that efficient management in the environmental arena can benefit the entire company and open new opportunities for increased profits. Managers have acknowledged that environmental issues can be integrated into daily business trends and activities (Metcalf et al., 1996). Not only does sound environmental management decrease liability, but also, in current markets, a ‘green’ image can attract investors and customers. It is argued in the current paper that a seamless web of environmental regulation has an ability to provide the greatest protection to the environ- ment while stimulating the innovation and diffu- sion of environmental technology, catering for different corporate cultures and providing a holis- tic approach to environmental regulation. This paper describes the development of a seamless web framework of environmental regulation. The paper divides the evolution of environmental regulation into three stages in order of develop- ment (Figure 1(A) – (C)). These represent the major groups of stakeholders in the setting of environmental regulation for each of the stages (Table 1). The ISO 14000 environmental manage- ment system (EMS) standards (Begley, 1996) have been used as an example of self-regulation in this paper and the specific definitions used are given in Table 2. W. J. ALTHAM AND T. F. GUERIN Copyright 1999 John Wiley Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment. Eco-Mgmt. Aud. 6, 61–75 (1999) 62
  • 3. Figure 1. (A) Stage one – traditional environmental regulation. (B) Stage two – traditional environmental regulation influenced by market mechanisms. (C) Stage three – seamless web model of environmental self-regulation. (A) (B) (C) SEAMLESS WEB FRAMEWORK Copyright 1999 John Wiley Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment. Eco-Mgmt. Aud. 6, 61–75 (1999) 63
  • 4. MARKET FAILURE AND THE DEVELOPMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL REGULATIONS A market failure occurs when the market does not produce the allocation of resources that maxi- mizes the total level of social welfare. In other words, such failures occur when an important economic factor is overlooked and therefore left unpriced. Underpricing can lead to the rapid overexploitation of a given resource and regulat- ory institutions should operate on the assumption that higher prices must be assigned to limited resources (Brown, 1996). Hawken (1993) comments that ‘markets are superb at setting prices, but incapable of recog- nizing costs’. The costs referred to here are externalities, and these create a market failure. An externality occurs when a third party has to bear the cost of the action of others, and is not fully compensated (Philpot, 1992). Pollution is the classic example of an externality. This cost of pollution is largely borne by the community as a social cost. Because the community and not the consumer of the product carries some of these costs, the price of the product is reduced and demand is increased. A range of environmental regulatory mechan- isms are available to correct such market failures (Harris, 1996; Hyde, 1997). These vary in the degree of their government and state authority. Such mechanisms include traditional (command- and-control) regulation, market mechanisms and self-regulation measures. The effectiveness of these mechanisms varies depending on many factors. These include the culture of the organiz- ation under these regulatory mechanisms, the nature of the market failure, the opportunities for the industry to alter their production methods and substitute materials, the resources allocated to the regulator, the visibility of the industry sector in the market place and the expectations of the community and other stakeholders. THE ROLE OF TRADITIONAL REGULATION Traditional environmental regulation involves what is commonly called ‘command-and-control’. This includes flat taxes and charges, and direct environmental regulations. They involve a gov- ernment or state institution legislating industry behaviour (Gunningham, 1994b), in effect telling industry what it can and cannot do, and how much it will cost them (Figure 1(A)). Industry responds to the regulations by addressing the specific concerns with limited view to any greater environmental impact reduction (Wilson, 1997). Table 1. Stakeholders in environmental regulation. Stakeholder Influence Government Set industry standards under political pressure State Set industry environmental performance standards under direction of government Industry organization Influence industry standard settings Industry Influence industry standard settings Peers Influence industry standard settings Participate in trading under market regulation Environmental regulators Set and enforce industry standards Market Place where market regulation are traded Community Influence environmental performance and standards through political pressure Consumers Influence sales, therefore profit of company Environmental NGOs Influence industry standard settings through political pressure Financial institutions Influence industry behaviour through reduced cost if environmental risk is managed Insurance sector Influence industry behaviour through reduced cost if environmental risk is managed Investors Influence industry behaviour through supply of capital if environmental risk is managed Work force Affect worker productivity and staff turn-over W. J. ALTHAM AND T. F. GUERIN Copyright 1999 John Wiley Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment. Eco-Mgmt. Aud. 6, 61–75 (1999) 64
  • 5. Many problems with traditional environmental regulation have been identified (Bovy, 1989; Susani, 1996). These including their inflexiblility (Wolf, 1988) and tendency to be directed by political consideration (Brozen et al., 1990). In addition, limited power and resources available to the regulator often leads to inadequate enforcement of regulations. As far back as the late 1960s economists and industrialists were questioning the economic ef- ficiency of traditional environmental regulations (BIE, 1992; Tyler Miller, 1994). The BIE (1992) provides a summary of concerns with traditional regulations, while highlighting the benefits of the market mechanism: Many economists argue that direct regu- lations are static, inflexible and sub-optimal in terms of environmental and economic ef- ficiency. Direct regulation, despite its accept- ability by government, is cost-ineffective in reducing emissions when compared to both pollution taxes and permits. These statements were supported by studies of the costs of the two types of policy (traditional versus market) on industry in the US’s Clean Air Act policy changes, with the shift to market requirements producing an estimated saving of $US900 million up to 1985 (BIE, 1992). Tyler- Miller (1994) claims that the current US bill for environmental protection of over $US120 billion per year could be cut by 33–50% if more effective market-based policies were used. However, possibly the greatest drawback with traditional regulation is that, in general, it has resulted in ‘end-of-pipe’ solutions to environ- mental problems (Nash and Ehrenfeld, 1997). End-of-pipe solutions are short-term, regulatory- driven solutions, which do not generally address the cause of the problem (Klassen and Angell, 1998). Examples include where equipment is added to the end of a process, such as filters and scrubbers to pollution discharge points. Although sound and well enforced environ- mental regulations are an essential foundation for improving environmental quality, command-and- control systems alone are not achieving the lower levels of pollution that will be necessary to achieve ecologically sustainable development (Rondinelli and Berry, 1997). THE ROLE OF MARKET MECHANISMS Market mechanisms require the establishment of property rights for pollution emission and natural resources, and a market in which to trade these rights, with the price determined by market forces. In theory, market mechanisms allow natu- ral resources to be used for their highest market value end use, by the most economically efficient operators. Pollution is generated by sectors of industry with the greatest potential to pay, or the highest control costs (though not strictly always the case). This leads to the ‘polluter pays principle’, in which Trade occurs because low-cost polluters will find it financially advantageous to cut pol- lution levels and sell permits, whereas high cost polluters find it financially advantageous to purchase permits rather than decrease pollution (Owen, 1991). This trading mechanism allows the maximum production for any loading of total emissions. In addition, market mechanisms and tradeable permit systems, in theory, are dynamic, allow for tech- nological innovation, allow new entrants into the industry, expand markets and are self-adjusting for inflation. All of these factors reduce the involvement of the state in environmental regu- lation (Figure 1(B)). An example of market mech- anisms is that of air emissions trading. Under the US Acid Rain Program, and California’s Regional Reclaim Program, the US has demonstrated the economic and environmental feasibility of these so-called ‘cap-and-trade’ programs. Now, emis- sions trading is being considered in other areas e.g. northeastern US, where trading schemes are under development to curb ozone precursors. A variety of states have implemented trading programs to reduce NOx and volatile organic compounds. Emissions trading is becoming inter- national as governments attempt to curb greenhouse-gas emissions (Hairston et al., 1998). Such initiatives represent a fundamental change in environmental management. A key element of emissions trading is the degree of compliance flexibility it affords individual operators (Hairston et al., 1998). The type of environmental regulation also affects the organizations’ incentive to adopt new technology for pollution control (Jaffe and SEAMLESS WEB FRAMEWORK Copyright 1999 John Wiley Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment. Eco-Mgmt. Aud. 6, 61–75 (1999) 65
  • 6. Stavins, 1995). In work by Milliman and Prince (1989) they concluded that Direct controls, which are common regulatory tools, usually provide the lowest relative firm incentives to promote technology. On a rela- tive basis, emission taxes and auctioned per- mits provide the highest firm incentive for the adoption of new technology. The major limitation of market mechanisms is that they cannot set the physical limits to the level of harvesting of natural resources or the assimilative capacity of the environment. This is a role for science, but clearly our scientific knowl- edge is incomplete (BIE, 1992). For example, if timber allocations or fishing quotas are set too high, the level of harvesting will be unsustainable. Alternatively, if the level of emission quotas allocated within a region is higher than the area can assimilate there will be social costs associated with the activity. The potential role market mechanisms may play in effective management of environmental issues have recently been discussed (Gustafsson, 1998). Although some assert that environmental problems could be solved by appropriate pricing of the environment and liberal application of market mechanisms for environmental manage- ment, these types of simplification may overlook the many complicating factors inherent in environmental degradation and the limitations of market mechanisms as a means of coping with environmental problems. These limitations include problems in defining and enforcing prop- erty rights concerning functions and services provided by nature (Gustafsson, 1998). THE ROLE OF SELF-REGULATION AND CODES OF PRACTICES Self-regulation, including codes of practice and standards, are developed by industry for many diverse reasons, including as a means of showing social responsibility and a desire by industry to reclaim the agenda-setting of their industry from other stakeholders. The development of EMS standards (ISO 14001, BS7750 and EMAS) can be seen as the latest stage in the development of modern environmental regulation (Nash and Ehrenfeld, 1997). Self-regulation can include either performance, content or process standards. It is the process standard of ISO 14001 which is now contemporary and is being adopted internationally (Hemenway, 1995; Snyder, 1995; Hemenway, 1996; Label and Tandy, 1998). Simply defined, a standard is anything, a rule or principle, that is used as a basis for judgment, an average or normal requirement, quality, quantity, level, grade, established by authority, custom or an individual as acceptable. Standardization, and its application to business systems, is one of the most important aspects of effective environmental management, a prerequisite for management, and empowering employees to understand where the company is vis-a-vis work and performance (Johannson, 1994). The improvement process can- not be undertaken successfully until standards are established and understood. Self-regulatory mechanisms, including the ISO 14000 series, accept the legislative regulations as a minimum standard that industry must achieve. The standards then encourage industry to be proactive, encouraging continuous improvement through the management process. ISO 14000 is a series of voluntary EMS standards, developed by the International Standards Organization (Struebing, 1996; Burns and Fredericks, 1997; Iwanski et al., 1997; Hersey, 1998). These stan- dards provide a framework by which an organ- ization can focus attention on its internal management activities. This allows the organiz- ation to integrate environmental management with other existing management considerations (such as production, sales, finance, safety and quality), with the aim of achieving continuous improvements in the organization’s environ- mental performance. The overall aim of ISO 14000 is to support environmental protection and prevention of pollution in balance with socio- economic needs. This series of standards cover the following major areas: (i) environmental management systems, (ii) environmental auditing, (iii) environmental performance evaluation, (iv) eco-labeling and (v) life-cycle analysis. Self-regulation implies (to a large extent) no legal requirement to comply. Therefore some other type of incentive for organizations to adopt W. J. ALTHAM AND T. F. GUERIN Copyright 1999 John Wiley Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment. Eco-Mgmt. Aud. 6, 61–75 (1999) 66
  • 7. such mechanisms is required. The major initial incentive for organizations to adopt self- regulation, including ISO 14001, is provided by the market. That is, organizations adopting them will, it is commonly claimed by advocates, be more efficient and competitive, gaining a marketing advantage in the longer term (Johannson, 1995). Codes of practices can act as a trail to see how industry is affected by changes in regulation. On occasions, sections of these codes have even become incorporated into law, such as the dangerous goods code in Australia, which has become Federal law. There is the problem of verifying that individual industry organizations, claiming compliance to a particular code, are in fact complying with that code. To minimize this problem and increase the public’s confidence in the minerals industry, the Minerals Council of Australia (MCA), for example, requires member organizations to be externally audited at least every three years against the MCA Code for Environmental Management. INTEGRATING THE COMPONENTS OF ENVIRONMENTAL REGULATION INTO A SEAMLESS WEB With continuous additions to the regulatory mechanisms, it is often difficult to determine where any particular regulator or regulation fits. One way of understanding the situation is through the concept of a seamless web of regu- lation (Figure 1(C)). A seamless web of environ- mental regulation implies an integrated set of regulations, regulators and incentives. Regulations involve a mix of traditional regulation, market mechanisms and self-regulation. Regulators in- clude federal and state regulators, NGOs, peers, other companies along the supply chain, service providers, investors and consumers. Incentives for improved environmental performance range from lower costs to increased market share and long term resource access, with sanctions ranging across incarceration of directors, license with- drawal, loss of resource access, fines, falling profits, loss of market share and falling investor confidence. Even within an industry, individual organiz- ations will respond to environmental regulations in different ways, depending on management culture, size of the organization and the environ- mental sensitivity of the operation. Improving environmental performance requires regulatory mechanisms that cater for a range of variables and stimulate industry to adopt new environmental technologies. Traditional, direct environmental regulation will always be required to motivate laggards who are the slowest to adopt the most appropriate course of action (Guerin and Guerin, 1994). Proactive companies (innovators and leaders), on the other hand, will respond to the opportunities and incentives that self-regulation offers to improve environmental performance. Command-and-control environmental regu- lations and reactive organizations are unlikely to develop management improvement cycles because the aim of the organization under this mechanism is to meet their legal requirement (Figure 2). Further, market mechanisms generate only limited incentive for organizations to develop a continuous improvement cycle, because the aim of the organization is to meet their legal requirements (and no more), at least cost. Industry self-regulation, through an EMS, can create a greater incentive for management to develop the improvement cycle, which leads to a process of continuous improvement in environmental per- formance (Kirschner, 1995; Crognale, 1997). Con- tinuous improvement is created because changes in environmental performance are measured against present performance and not past per- formance or an arbitrary legal standard (Figure 3). Moreover this level of performance is continually Table 2. Definitions. Environmental regulation Means that control or modify organizational behaviour towards the environment Regulators Stakeholders playing a role in creating and enforcing this modified behaviour State The unelected institutions and bureaucracy that carry out the affairs of state Government The elected representative of the people SEAMLESS WEB FRAMEWORK Copyright 1999 John Wiley Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment. Eco-Mgmt. Aud. 6, 61–75 (1999) 67
  • 8. under review by the organization to determine whether it can be improved. The concept of a seamless web removes some of the limitations of a regulatory system that relies on a single traditional regulatory mechan- ism, or single agency, to enforce environmental regulations. These limitations include the problem of regulatory capture, skills shortages, budgetary cutbacks and political interference into the oper- ations of the regulators. Furthermore, it allows companies more flexibility in reducing costs associated with dealing with the environmental impact(s) (Hesse, 1989; Young, 1994). Within the concept of the seamless web there is no single best method of environmental regu- lation. As soon as an organization identifies under what category of environmental regulation they will be controlled, they investigate methods to reduce that regulation’s impact on their operation. This action will often lead to measures that will reduce the effectiveness of the original regu- lation, and in some cases lead to an inefficient ‘ratcheting-up’ effect of environmental regulation. Citizen Legal Standing The proper functioning of the seamless web requires two factors that are becoming more prevalent in modern environmental policy. The first is the granting of legal standing to all stakeholders under the relevant environmental regulation. This provision allows individuals or organizations to instigate legal action against parties who in their opinion are not complying with legislative environmental regulation. This provision supplements the resources the state has to devote to enforcing environmental regulations while preventing regulatory capture. Industry sometimes claims that granting private standing will lead to large numbers of ‘nuisance’ claims. However this does not appear to be the case. This citizen legal standing can also be used to force public authorities to comply with relevant environmental regulations and to en- sure environmental regulators act on breaches of environmental regulations carried out by organizations. Figure 2. The environmental management improvement cycle. W. J. ALTHAM AND T. F. GUERIN Copyright 1999 John Wiley Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment. Eco-Mgmt. Aud. 6, 61–75 (1999) 68
  • 9. Public Disclosure For environmental regulations to work efficiently, all stakeholders need access to the relevant infor- mation. Therefore, the second factor required is environmental reporting by organizations in order to aid informed debate and correct decision making by stakeholders (Chynoweth, 1994; Nash and Ehrenfeld, 1997). This information must be complete, accurate, relevant, easily understand- able and made available at short regular intervals such as in external company reports. The Toxic Release Inventory (TRI) initiative introduced by the US EPA is an example of this practice at work. Under this programme, companies reported as having the highest levels of emissions had the largest stock price decline and subsequently reduced emissions more than their industry peers (Konar and Cohen, 1997). Best Practice Licencing To further illustrate the development of this seamless web model of environmental regulation, the Western Australian Environmental Protection Authority’s (WAEPA’s) Best Practice License initiat- ive (DEP, 1996) is described. Prior to the intro- duction of this initiative, most industries in Western Australia operated within a system of traditional regulation. All organizations received the same incentive and the same legislative sanc- tions. With the introduction of the system, WAEPA offered a range of alternatives for organizations, catering for differences in corporate culture and varying the level of monitoring required. There are four levels of licence available: a regulated licence, a partially monitored licence, a monitored licence and a best practice licence (BPL) (Baker, 1996). The system was introduced from 1 October 1996 for all forms of licence except the BPL, whose criteria were released in 1998. After 1 October 1996, organizations could choose to adopt their preferred licence as their licence renewals occurred, provided the regulators accept the organization’s application. It is likely that in this Western Australian situation laggards will continue to operate as before, that is under the regulated (command-and-control) licence. How- ever, organizations that are proactive have the opportunity to show leadership and obtain a BPL. If such organizations can demonstrate proactive environmental management and go beyond com- pliance, they receive a benefit in accordance with their efforts. These benefits include lower license fees (the theoretical maximum can be as high as $180 000AUS), reduced external monitoring of their operation and longer periods between license renewals. An Example of Stakeholder Influence A contrast of the influence that stakeholder press- ure can have on company behaviour, management and environmental performance is illustrated by Shell’s Brent Spar Oil Platform activity in the North Sea, and the Exxon Valdez oil spill in Prince William Sound, Alaska. The community and the market sanctioned Shell, although Shell complied with legislation and with the support of the relevant government departments, when they attempted to sink their oil platform, the Brent Spar (Greenpeace, 1996). In the case of the Exxon Valdez oil spill, though many regulations were breached, anecdotal evidence indicates that, despite the urgings of high profile environmental campaigners, neither the community nor the mar- ket sanctioned the Exxon Oil Company to the same extent as Shell. This example demonstrates for modern business the need to be aware of the stakeholder’s view, together with willingness by stakeholders to act on these views, as it should affect a company’s environmental strategy if the company is to operate in their own long term best interest. THE ROLE OF ISO 14001 IN THE SEAMLESS WEB OF ENVIRONMENTAL REGULATION Industry Involvement Industry is expected to play an increasingly important role in developing clean, sustainable production systems. This is in response to regu- latory failures, increasing public expectation of industry’s environmental performance, and the uncertainty surrounding the effect of state environmental regulations on growth and inno- vation (Heaton and Banks, 1997). The adoption of ISO 14001 should encourage organizations to SEAMLESS WEB FRAMEWORK Copyright 1999 John Wiley Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment. Eco-Mgmt. Aud. 6, 61–75 (1999) 69
  • 10. develop an environmental strategy as an import- ant element of overall management decision mak- ing, together with a framework by which this strategy can be put into operation. Through this framework, self-regulation can lead to significant improvements in environmental performance (Gunningham, 1994b). Models of Corporate Culture and Beyond Compliance There are various models for corporate cultures, company actions and the benefits to firms and the environmental impacts of these actions. The re- lationship between actions and benefits varies between companies depending on their particular priorities, and it is expected that there would be differences between and within industries. Any given firm will establish their EMS with specific goals in mind. There are two important points for management to consider: (i) the development of an EMS is a learning process for the organization and (ii) the benefits are compounding. Any firm can start with the simple inexpensive changes first, then with experience, develop their EMS to a higher level at a rate and in a manner which is compatible with the organization. For example, any company doing the minimum required for ISO 14001 certification could be classified as Observe and Comply, while another certified firm, which is ‘truly’ environmentally proactive with a large commitment to RD into environmental technology, can be classified as Proactive. This point illustrates a problem with ISO 14001 in its present form. It should be recognized that the implementation of ISO 14001 on its own is unlikely to bring about maximum benefits to the company, if the company or corporate culture does not accept the need for a continuous improvement in environmental management (Anonymous, 1995; Kanegsberg, 1996; Rimich, 1996; Epstein and Roy, 1997). Any company, at any point in time, will be somewhere along the continuum of environ- mental performance. A company may shift to the left of their present position, to observe and comply. This would represent deterioration in the company’s concern for environmental issues. If a company has no history in EMS and attempts to move to True ESD, then it is likely it will have great difficulty in doing so. Such companies can speed up the process of learning by devoting more resources to their EMS. Components of an effective EMS such as worker participation and changes to corporate culture and mechanisms to integrate environmental factors with other man- agement considerations take time and substantial resources to develop. Fortunately, there is a process of learning by doing. Figure 3. Improvement of environmental performance in a company. W. J. ALTHAM AND T. F. GUERIN Copyright 1999 John Wiley Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment. Eco-Mgmt. Aud. 6, 61–75 (1999) 70
  • 11. The Prospects of a Market Solution to a Market Failure The public’s expectation of how industry should act regarding the environment has changed in recent years. The natural environment cannot now be treated as a free commodity or a dumping ground. More importantly, sections of society are prepared to act on these expectations, either by changing spending patterns (Grabosky, 1995) or through direct actions (such as illustrated in Shell’s Brent Spar case). The US Superfund legislation is another example where political and social press- ure is being used to make industry more account- able for their actions and correct past market failures. Surveys of the public in the US concluded that more than 75% of participants classified themselves as environmentalists (Nicklas, 1993; McInerney and White, 1995). Similar results were shown from a survey conducted by the Australian Bureau of Statistics (1996) where 75% of Australians were concerned about environmental issues. Companies are having to assess and manage the environmental risks of their operation(s), and demonstrate this to service providers, investors and other stakeholders, to ensure the long-term support of the stakeholders, and indeed the sur- vival of the company. These changes create the potential for market pressure to be brought against a market failure. However, if we were to leave it up to the market to trigger the change, the results would be much slower and more erratic than socially desirable or acceptable. Hence there is a requirement for public policies to complement the incentive for industry to adopt new technologies. This could be achieved through legislative reform and recommendations in rela- tion to the US environmental laws and regulatory framework have been presented by Heaton and Banks (1997). This shift in organizational culture towards the environment, for whatever reason, is paralleled in other areas of organizational management. Areas such as unfair dismissal, health and safety issues, childcare, maternity leave and redundancy pay- outs are examples where corporate attitudes have changed in recent times. There are likely to be many sceptics to the argument being mounted that the market and industry can protect the environment, claiming that self-regulatory standards are another way by which industry can ‘pull the wool’ over the public’s eyes. This is being too cynical. Few advocate the removal of other types of environ- mental regulation. Both environmentally pro- active companies and ISO maintain there will always be a need for the ‘carrot’ and the ‘stick’. Both approaches are important threads of the seamless web of regulation. To this effect, Gunningham (1994a) states The bigger the stick at the disposal of the regulators, the more it is able to achieve results by speaking softly. This is supported by Stoughton (1994), who argues that Voluntary programs have the potential to affect significant changes in environmental behaviors, and can be effective policies for environmental protection. They often depend, however, on a strong enforcement role for the agency under its regulatory mandates, and thus must be a supplement, rather than a replacement for regulation. These statements support the argument put forward in this paper that the time has come when the ‘carrot’ can play a greater part, by rewarding companies for being proactive in the field of environmental management. For this process to be successful, however, legislative environmental regulations are required, and the size of the ‘stick’ maintained or increased. To obtain the maximum environmental benefit of environmental manage- ment systems (including those based on ISO 14001), these regulations should be integrated into the seamless web, providing another thread, and complementing, not replacing, existing regu- latory measures. The use of economic incentives is normally preferable to the power of the law to alter human behaviour. We assert that both need to be available. CONCLUSION There can be a win – win outcome in the ESD debate – when industry produces and the en- vironment is protected. Furthermore, the current ESD debate is not between environment and SEAMLESS WEB FRAMEWORK Copyright 1999 John Wiley Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment. Eco-Mgmt. Aud. 6, 61–75 (1999) 71
  • 12. development, but rather between sustainable and unsustainable technology. Economies are achiev- ing growth with reduced environmental impacts, through the appropriate use of innovations in environmental technology. There is a clear indication that a combination of a specific type of environmental regulation, cor- porate culture and public policy will stimulate innovation in environmental technology. How- ever, the use of environmental regulation alone is an indirect and inefficient method of stimulating innovation in environmental technology. Insti- tutions and policies that manage risk and uncer- tainty should assist industry to adopt cleaner production methods. The ‘evolution’ of environmental regulation identified a problem with traditional environ- mental regulations in that they encouraged ineffi- cient, ‘end-of-pipe’ solutions. Market mechanisms generate incentives for the economically most efficient solution, but they retain many of the problems of traditional legislative environmental regulation, including the absence of sufficient incentives for organizations to go beyond com- pliance. This evolution has led to the development of self-regulations that include ISO 14001. ISO 14001 is a process or management standard that is forming an important thread in the seamless web model of environmental regulation. ISO 14001 supplies the framework for industry to go beyond compliance and it encourages continous improve- ment in environmental performance, based on a feedback loop that measures improvement from present performance, not an arbitrary benchmark. The environmental result desired by organiz- ations under traditional regulation is to meet the required legislative standards. The result desired by organizations under a market mechanism is to meet the required legislative standard at the least cost. These are contrary to the desire of organiz- ations with a continuous improvement cycle in their management system, and therefore, a desire and behaviour to improve environmental per- formance, and to move beyond compliance. Under traditional and market regulations, organi- zations have very little incentive to review their environmental impacts, unless for legal reasons, and therefore a ‘set-and-forget’ mentality may ensue. The incentive for adopting ISO 14001 is at present provided by the market, although this is starting to change as environmental regulators begin to recognize benefits in having organiz- ations develop environmental management systems. The framework presented here, of a seamless web, requires the maintenance of tra- ditional environmental regulation; however, it allows the ‘carrot’ to play a greater part in the development and adoption of environmental technology. Modern environmental policy needs to be developed so that industry and society gains the maximum benefit from all the threads and inter- actions of the seamless web, leading to better environmental protection with the least impact on production and competitiveness for any organizations that accept this challenge. A key attribute of the seamless web model is that it provides a framework that does not rely on any one mechanism or stakeholder, so, where one mechanism or stakeholder may fail, another will fill the gap, allowing for on-going environmental protection. Furthermore, advocating a single regu- latory mechanism is prone to failure because those being regulated implement management changes that reduce the effect of the relevant regulation on their behaviour. In addition, complex authori- tative environmental regulations require large amounts of public resources to be fully imple- mented and these resources are not always pro- vided. The seamless web model provides the flexibility to cater for different corporate cultures, a major requirement of modern environmental policy. It also reduces the demand on public funds to enforce legislative environmental regulations. Policy makers need to actively reduce risk and uncertainty while giving incentives for industry to be proactive, for these are the organizations which will help solve many of our environmental problems. The stick will still need to be main- tained as an important mechanism to activate laggards. It is recognized that there is a large amount of enlightened self-interest in the process of self- regulation for industry. Therefore the process of self-regulation will require external monitoring if it is to attain credibility amongst stakeholders. Self-regulation allows companies to be flexible about how and when they address their environ- mental problems, reducing associated costs and improving efficiency. However, industry must realize that this process will not necessarily reduce W. J. ALTHAM AND T. F. GUERIN Copyright 1999 John Wiley Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment. Eco-Mgmt. Aud. 6, 61–75 (1999) 72
  • 13. the level of scrutiny industry faces, but rather the direction from which this scrutiny comes from will shift from the government and state to other sectors of society. Further, the required level of environmental protection may not in all cases be able to be achieved at no cost to industry, and in these cases traditional regulation and market mechanisms will be required. The stakeholders involved in environmental regulation do not operate in isolation. To protect the environment, in balance with economic devel- opment, the core aim of ESD, will require that all stakeholders play their part in an integrated seamless web of environmental regulation. REFERENCES Anonymous. (1995) What can ISO 14000 do for your company?, Environmental Manager, 7, (5), 5–8. Anonymous. (1996) Winning green strategies, Environ- mental Manager, 7, (7), 11–13. Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS). (1996) Environmen- tal Issues: People’s Views and Practices, ABS, Australian Government Publishing Services, Canberra. Baker, A. (1996) Proposed Changes to Environmental Protection Act Licensing and Fee Structure, Department of Environmental Protection, Perth. Begley, R. (1996) ISO 14000: a step toward industry self-regulation, Environmental Science and Technology, 30, (7), 298A–302A. Blau, J.R. (1995) New ISO standard aims at leveling the playing field for green manufacturers, Machine Design, 67, (17), 48–50. Bovy, M.W.L. (1989) Acid rain policy in The Netherlands – Application of mediation techniques, Ambio, 18, (8), 416. Bridgen, P.J. (1996) ISO 14000: the worldwide reaction of industry and governments, Environmental Quality Management, 6, (1), 45–49. Brown, H. (1996) Pragmatic ethics and the new consult- ant, Total Quality Environmental Management, 5, (4), 1–6. Brozen, Y., Groenveld, K., Maks, A. and Muysken, J. (1990) Economic Policy and the Market – Austrian and Mainstream Economics, Elsevier, New York. Bureau of Industry Economics (BIE). (1992) Environmental Regulation: the Economics of Tradable Permits – a Survey of Theory and Practice, BIE, Australian Government Publishing Service, Canberra. Burns, R. and Fredericks, I. (eds). (1997) Using ISO 14001 for Environmental Management Systems to Develop a Risk Based Integrated Management System Throughout NOVA Corpora- tion, Air and Waste Management Association, Pittsburgh, PA, p 6. Chynoweth, E. (1994) Focus on stewardship, reporting, and small firms, Chemical Week, 155, (1), 103–104. Colby, P.W. (1997) ISO 14000: a return to command and control?, Environmental Quality Management, 7, (2), 61–64. Crognale, G. (1997) Financial incentives, Environmental Protection, 8, (5), 36–38. Deavenport, E. (1996) Doing the right thing, Executive Excellence, 13, (5), 12–13. Department of Environmental Protection (DEP). (1996) Achieving Best Practice Environmental Management, DEP, Perth. Dwyer, M. (1996) ISO 14001: setting a new standard in red tape, Australian Financial Review, July 10, 18. Epstein, M.J. and Roy, M.-J. (1997) Using ISO for improved organizational learning and environmental management, Environmental Quality Management, 7, (1), 21–30. Ferrone, R. (1998) Technology 1998 analysis forecast: the environment, IEEE Spectrum, 35, (1), 95–99. Grabosky, P. (1995) in: Eckersley, R. (ed.), Governing at a Distance: Self-Regulating Green Markets. Markets, the State and the Environment, Macmillan, Melbourne, pp 197–228. Greenpeace. (1996) Brent Spar Protect in North Sea, 21 November, http://www.greenpeace.org/comms/brent/ brent.html. Greis, N.P. (1995) Technology adoption, product design, and process change: a case study in the machine tool industry, IEEE Transactions on Engineering Management, 42, (3). Guerin, L.J. and Guerin, T.F. (1994) Constraints to the adoption of agricultural and environmental innovations and technologies: a review, Australian Journal of Exper- imental Agriculture, 34, 549–571. Gunningham, N. (1994a) Proactive environmental manage- ment:business and regulatory strategies, Australian Journal of Environmental Management, 1, (2), 121–133, (September). Gunningham, N. (1994b) Going beyond compliance: man- agement of environmental risk. Environmental outlook: law and policy, Boer, B., Fowler, R. and Gunningham, N., Federation Press, Leichhardt, N.S.W., 254–279. Gustafsson, B. (1998) Scope and limits of the market mechanism in environmental management, Ecological Economics, 24, 2–3. Hairston, D., Shelley, S. and Crabb, C. (1998) Emissions- trading programs hit their stride, Chemical Engineering, 105, (6), 32–37. Harris, P. (1996) Textile makers tap DOE labs for enviro- technologies, Environmental Management Today, 7, (4), 22–24. Hawken, P. (1993) The Ecology of Commerce, Weidenfeld and Nicolson, London. Heaton, G.R. and Banks, R.D. (1997) Towards a new generation of environmental technology – the need for legislative reform, Journal of Industrial Ecology, 1, (2), 23–32. Hemenway, C.G. (1995) From Oslo with love: ISO 14001 moves towards adoption, Environment Today, 6, (7), 17–19. Hemenway, C.G. (1996) International e-standards head toward adoption, Environmental Management Today, 7, (3), 30. SEAMLESS WEB FRAMEWORK Copyright 1999 John Wiley Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment. Eco-Mgmt. Aud. 6, 61–75 (1999) 73
  • 14. Hemphill, T.A. (1996) The new era of business regulation, Business Horizons, 39, (4), 26–30. Hersey, K. (1998) A close look at ISO 14000, Professional Safety, 43, (7), 26–29. Hesse, M.O. (1989) A new era in energy regulation, Public Utility Fortnightly, 123, (6), 18. Hyde, P. (1997) Environmental management, Safety and Health Practitioner, 15, (6), 52–55. Iwanski, M.L., Loney, J.M. and Howell, V.L. (eds). (1997) Experiences of a Restructured Corporation in Establishing a Corporate EMS and Audit Program in a Changing Marketplace, Air and Waste Management Association, Pittsburgh, PA. Jackson, D. (1998) Product stewardship takes center stage, Chemical Week, 160, (25), 116. Jaffe, A.B. and Stavins, R.N. (1995) Dynamic incentives of environmental regulations: the effects of alternative policy instruments on technology diffusion, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 29, (3 (Part 2)), 543–563. Jancsurak, J. (1998) In pursuit of a greener-bottom line, Appliance Manufacturer, 46, (1), E23–E25. Johannson, L. (1994) Voluntary standards at the dawn of ISO 14000: fit or folly for TQEM?, Total Quality Environ- mental Management, 4, (2), 101–112. Johannson, L. (1995) Tuning to Station WIIFY on ISO 14000: what’s in it for you? Total Quality Environmental Management, 5, (2), 107–117. Kanegsberg, B. (1996) Quality means business, Chemical Marketing Reporter, 249, (15), 3–4. Kirschner, E. (1995) Environmental management systems get worldwide benchmark, Chemical Engineering News, 73, (14), 13. Klassen, R.D. and Angell, L.C. (1998) An international comparison of environmental management in operations: the impact of manufacturing flexibility in the US and Germany. Journal of Operations Management, 16, (2,3), 177–194. Konar, S. and Cohen, M. (1997) Information as regulation: the effect of community right to know laws on toxic emissions, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 32, (1), 109–204. Label, W.A. and Tandy, P.R. (1998) ISO 14000 envrionmen- tal management systems: new opportunities and respon- sibilities for internal auditors, Internal Auditing, 13, (4), 3–8. Lepkowski, W. (1994) Export outlook modest for green technologies, Chemical and Engineering News, 72, (14), 23. McInerney, F. and White, S. (1995) The Total Quality Corporation; how 10 Major Companies Turned Quality and Environmental Challenges to Competitive Advantage in the 1990s, New York, Truman Talley. Metcalf, K.R., Williams, P.L., Minter, J.R. and Hobson, C.M. (1996) Environmental performance indicators for en- hancing environmental management, Total Quality Environmental Management, 5, (4). Milliman, S. and Prince, R. (1989) Firm incentives to pro- mote technological change in pollution control, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 17, 247–265. Mullin, R. (1998a) Critics look for greater commitment, Chemical Week, 160, (25), 39–42. Mullin, R. (1998b) Setting tough internal goals, Chemical Week, 160, (25), 98–101. Mullin, R. and Sissell, K. (1996) Merging business and environment, Chemical Week, 158, (38), 52–53. Nash, J. and Ehrenfeld, J. (1997) Codes of environmental management practice: assessing their potential as a tool for change, Annual Review of Energy and the Environment, 22, 487–535. Nicklas, M. (1993) Energy politics: can we achieve a sustainable energy path, Solar Energy, 50, (4), 287–296. Noor-Drugan, N. (1998) Germany: Regulation or volunteer action? Chemical Week, 160, (25), 125. Owen, A. (1991) Tradable Emissions as a Greenhouse Response Measure, National Capital Printing, Department of Arts, Sport, Environment, Territories and Tourism, Canberra. Philpot, R. (1992) Externalities policy development project: energy sector, Department of Minerals and Energy: innovation, economic change and sustainability, Murdoch University Reader, 3, 102–112. Rimich, N.C. Jr. (1996) Are you an envirophile?, Appliance Manufacturer, 44, (9), 152. Rondinelli, D.A. and Berry, M.A. (1997) Industry’s role in air quality improvement: environmental management opportunities for the 21st century, Environmental Quality Management, 7, 1, 31–44. Samdani, G.S. (1995) ISO 14000: new passport to world markets, Chemical Engineering, 102, 6, 41. Scott, A. (1998) Europe begins to measure performance, Chemical Week, 160, 25, 111–112. Seif, M. (1995) ISO 14000: privatizing environmental regulation – an idea without borders. [http://www. dep.state.pa.us/dep/deputate/pollprev/Tech_ Assistance/ Toolbox/iso14001/privat23/06/98]. Sheldon, C. (1997) ISO 14001 and beyond, Environmental Management Systems in the Real World, Greenleaf, Sheffield. Snyder, J.D. (1995) ISO 14000 session in Oslo will air performance evaluation standards, Environment Today, 6, 5. Steinzor, R.I. (1998) Reinventing environmental regulation: the dangerous journey from command to self-control, Harvard Environmental Law Review, 22, 1, 103. Stoughton, M. (1994) An Evaluation of Voluntary Programs as Public Policies for Environmental Protection, http:// web.mit.edu/org/c/ctpid/www/tbe/theses/stough.htm. Struebing, L. (1996) The standards at a glance, Quality Progress, 29, 1, 24–25. Susani, L. (1996) New moves to reduce marine pollution, Petroleum Review, 50, 594, 320–322. Tyler Miller, G.J. (1994) Sustaining the Earth – an Integrated Approach, Wadsworth, California. Webb, L. (1995) A complex environment for regulation, Pulp and Paper International, 37, 12, 37–39. Wilson, R.C. (1997) A variety of drivers influence an EMS program, Pollution Engineering, 29, 9, 53–54. Wolf, C.J. (1988) Markets or Governments – Choosing Between Imperfect Alternatives, MIT Press, Cambridge. Young, J. (1994) Wisconsin’s Paper Council, DNR complete program’s first year, Pulp and Paper, 68, 9, 115–116. W. J. ALTHAM AND T. F. GUERIN Copyright 1999 John Wiley Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment. Eco-Mgmt. Aud. 6, 61–75 (1999) 74
  • 15. BIOGRAPHY Dr. Turlough F. Guerin can be reached at 248 Gladstone Avenue, Coniston 2500 New South Wales, Australia. Email address: turloughg@hotmail.com Dr. Guerin has expertise in environmental tech- nology and management systems and has worked for ICF Kiser, Hamersley Iron and Rio Tinto RTD. He assists corporations with cross- industry technology transfer and the integrated management of business and EHS issues and has advised to numerous corporations in the USA, including the Motorola Corporation and Levine- Fricke Engineering. William J. Altham can be reached at Institute for Science and Technology Policy, Murdoch University, Perth 6510, Western Australia. Email address: w.altham@central.murdoch.edu.au William (Jim) Altham holds an Economics Degree and a Master Degree in ESD. His research interests include environmental management systems, green corporate strategy, regulation and innovation in clean technologies, emissions trading and renewable energy policy. SEAMLESS WEB FRAMEWORK Copyright 1999 John Wiley Sons, Ltd and ERP Environment. Eco-Mgmt. Aud. 6, 61–75 (1999) 75