SlideShare une entreprise Scribd logo
1  sur  33
Télécharger pour lire hors ligne
INFLATION DYMAMICS IN
BRAZIL: AN EMPIRICAL
APPROACH
Mauricio Oreng
Prof. Marco A. Bonomo
This Version: June, 25th
2003
2
I. Introduction
Calvo’s model (1983) implied New Keynesian Phillips Curve (NKPC) addressed some
of the unpleasant features of the New Classical version (NCPC), like the fact that only
unanticipated variations in nominal spending could affect the real economic activity. Such
result, if analyzed more thoroughly, would suggest that monetary policy could influence real
GDP only through its immediate effects, affecting prices only in the medium / long run. This
is, according to empirical evidence, highly counterfactual.
By means of an optimal price setting model, using the hypothesis of staggered prices,
Calvo addressed the issue, obtaining then a so called - by Roberts (1995) - New Keynesian
Phillips Curve. Thereby, one could concluded that the impact of monetary policy on real
economic activity may last until many periods ahead. In addition, this model had on its favor
persuasive empirical evidence, as found by Sbordone (2000), when comparing actual
inflation and its prediction by Calvo’s model.
Nevertheless, according to some economists, we have some reasons one should not
feel very comfortable with such model. There are supposedly two main problems with that
specification of the Phillips Curve proposed by Calvo: (i) first: NKPC implies a negative
relationship between inflation next period and today’s output gap, or, in particular, it predicts
lower inflation following periods when real GDP is above its natural value. Second, such
specification does not allow for any inflation inertia whatsoever, relying too much on agents’
forward looking behavior, in spite of the fact that many central banks around the world use
models incorporating persistence in price acceleration.
With regard to the first issue, we observe that, in fact, most empirical work arrive at a
positive correlation between output gap and inflation acceleration , which contrasts with the
specification of the New Keynesian Curve. Nonetheless, Gali (1999) argues that this may be
due to a methodological problem concerning the way one computes the smooth GDP, when
calculating the output gap. The rationale is that the natural GDP is function of a vector of
structural parameters, whose changes may account for disturbances in natural product
measures. As a result, one could happen to find positive correlation between the current gap
and inflation change next period, in empirical tests using plain measures of output gap. One
solution proposed to address this sticky issue, is to look at the real labor unit cost (marginal
cost equivalent), which, in Calvo´s model, is an increasing function of the output gap. This
could bring us the possibility of using the real labor unit cost as a proxy for the income gap, a
3
methodology that would allow us to test with more precision empirical evidence for Calvo’s
Phillips Curve.
On the second issue concerning the problems in NKPC specification, Christiano et
al.(2001)’s VAR studies bring up some piece of evidence against the purely forward looking
behavior hypothesis, suggested by Calvo’s NKPC. Examining the effects of monetary
disturbances on inflation and output, Christiano found that inflation is affected by changes in
monetary policy only after most of the output response (to the very same shock) has already
occurred. However, as Calvo’s would preach by his model, inflation is determined solely by
future expected output gaps, and thus, following a monetary shock, it should move before
output. In addition those results, and unexpectedly in accordance with theory, Chistiano also
found some high degree of persistence in inflation through this tests, which strengthened the
will to try empirically variations on standard Calvo´s specification, now allowing for the
possibility of existence of a backward looking component in inflation dynamics. The result
then was a another NKPC, mixing agent’s backward and forward looking behavior, so called
the Hybrid NKPC.
Aiming at this discussion above on the NKPC’s problems, and using american data,
Gali and Gertler (1999) tested models that incorporate the approach of using real marginal
costs as a proxy for the (ad-hoc) output gap, and that allow for some degree of persistence in
inflation as well. As one main result, for the US economy, they came up with the
effectiveness of using marginal costs as a proxy to the output gap, yielding the model’s
predicted negative relation between future gaps and inflation acceleration. They also found
evidence of some mild degree of persistence in US economy’s inflation dynamics. In
addition, Gali, Gertler and Salido (2001), performs tests of the same nature for the european
economy, finding that NKPC fits the data very well (even better than in the US), what
becomes another piece of evidence favoring such theory.
How would those results turn out be for the brazilian economy? Our goal, in this
current work, is simply to bring answers to such question. The idea is to perform empirical
tests of the same nature as in Gali and Gertler (1999), always bearing in mind the need to
adjust these experiments to brazilian reality. Hopefully, one will be able to obtain interesting
conclusions about the brazilian inflation path within the Real era and to compare them with
those obtained for the american economy. In addition, this may, in some cases, provide
further robustness to empirical evidence favoring NKPC theorists, and specially in case of
Gali and Gertler´s work.
Having already motivated this work, now we briefly indicate the steps to be taken. In
the next section, we provide methodological information, detailing the sample features,
4
variables and proxies used, and providing some fast information on the econometric
techniques. Later on, we stress, using both theoretical and empirical arguments (specificaly
applied to the brazilian economy), on the advantages of using the marginal costs approach to
estimate the NKPC, sustained byGali and Gertler. The two sections that follow are dedicated
to the estimations of, respectively, the purely NKPC and the hybrid one, always focusing to
apply Gali and Gertler’s test to the brazilian economy. Then we conclude.
II. Methodological Considerations
Given the purpose of this current work - to perform, for the brazilian economy, the
same type of tests Gali and Gertler have conduced for the US economy - our will here was:
trying to perform, as closely as possible in a methodological sense, the very same procedures
followed by the authors. So, it could be interesting to briefly highlight, at this point, some of
the issues that came up whilst we took on the task of adapting the american research to
brazilian reality.
First of all, some problems involving data matters have appeared, which is quite not
surprising, since there are major asymmetries in both availability and reliability of economic
data when we compare Brazil and the US. It is already known to most researchers the scarcity
of economic data faced in developing countries, Brazil in particular. Without a full nor broad
mass of data in hands, there were times when we faced the need to adapt, to brazilian
economy, concepts of economic data (variables and proxies) in the US, so as to reduce the
presence of asymmetries in the tests ran for these economies, and to prevent the generation of
unwanted noise or measurement errors as well. One standard result from econometrics is that
the latter can potentially hurt consistency of OLS (and also GMM) estimates.
To exemplify what we mean here, in the case of labor income data (used to obtain a
measure of marginal costs), the US data comprises only the industrial and retail sectors
(excluding agriculture), meanwhile, for Brazil, the unique of such measure available to us
included the agricultural sector. We had some problems of the same nature with regard to
variables like long term interest rates and broad-inflation. However, such data asymmetries
are not expected to have huge impact on the estimates, for the proxies used herein were
sought so as to maximize their co-movements with the original variables1
. Thus, this problem
1
It might not be completely useless to remind the reader that OLS estimators - naturally GMM as well, being
OLS’ generalization - are robust to linear transformations (like differences in levels between variables, which
is commonly encountered when taking different proxies for a same economic variable).
5
shall not hamper the comparability nor the quality of the results, despite the fact that some
robustness tests (e.g. run the same tests with other proxies) should be performed in later
versions.
One additional issue is that, when it comes to perform the tests and to compare the
results obtained for the different economies, it might not be wasteful to look at countries’
historical differences in both economic and geo-political grounds. In particular, contrarily to
the US, the brazilian economy had been facing in the past severe inflationary process, until
the Real Plan - implemented in June 1994 - succeeded in bringing (relatively) price
stabilization to the economy. In practical terms, this implies that, using time series comprising
periods earlier and after the Real adoption, we are very likely to observe the presence of
structural break(s) in our parameters estimates for Brazil.
Bearing this in mind, we were left with two different alternatives: (1) to use a very
broad sample period for consistency reasons (like Gali and Gertler), albeit generating
somewhat distorted estimates as a result of the applicability of Lucas critique - see Lucas
(1976); (2) or to reduce the sample used in the models’ tests, confining it to the Real period,
loosing in terms of degree of convergence to the real parameter value (consistency), but
reducing dramatically the probability of structural breaks within our dataset. We have found
better to choose the second alternative.
II.A - Observation Sampling Window
Following Gali and Gertler (1999), we chose a dataset of quarterly observations of
brazilian data, covering the interval T = [1994:3, 2002:2]. One must notice that we are left
with only 32 observations, roughly more than one fifth of Gali and Gertler’s dataset for the
US economy, which comprises data across 37 years. Such choice of ours - to shrink the
dataset - can be justified, though, for reasons already mentioned above: by reducing the
sample window, we try to minimize the effects of Lucas’ critique onto the estimates herein
obtained.
One might know that, in brazilian economic history, one can easily divide the
timeline in (at least) two very distinct moments: one phase earlier and another one after the
Real implementation in 1994. The brazilian hyperinflationary process of the past was
reversed by such major change in economic policy, which was crucial to bring yearly
inflation down from figures around 2480% in 1993 to 22% in 19952
. And intuitively, we
know that higher inflation levels become more persistence (i.e. more dependent on the past),
6
as a result of generalized price indexation. This allows us to conclude that the Real
implementation brought not only a huge change in inflation level, but also affected the set of
driving forces behind the inflation dynamics.
One further argument is also applicable to justify the rejection of data prior to 1994:3:
hyperinflationary processes are sometimes linked to trajectories associated with bubbles,
which is hard to be modeled (and therefore estimated).
Therefore, we realized (rather informally, we admit) that there can be little doubt
about the existence of major structural changes in any inflation models’ parameters estimated
with a sample beginning before 1994, as consequence of the Real Plan. In all, aware of the
arguments above, it seemed very reasonable to us to avoid the greater costs of the existence
of structural breaks by the compression of the sample window, even at a (smaller) loss in
terms of convergence of parameters estimates.
II.B - Database and concepts
Bearing in mind the objective of being as close as possible to the methodology
proposed by Gali and Gertler, and trying to minimize possible differences in concepts of data
between the US and the brazilian economy, we set up the sample vector Q(T), for T
established as above:
Q(T) = [ π(T)´ R(T)´ Z(T)´ ]´,
where π(T) is the dependent variable, that is, a broad measure of inflation for the observation
period, and R(T), Z(T) are, respectively, a vector of regressors and a vector of instruments,
i.e.,
R(T) = [ s(T)´ x(T)´ ]´
Z(T) = [ s(T)´ x(T)´ i*(T)´ πw
(T)´ πc
(T)´ πG
(T)´ ]´.
In Z(T), we used some lagged variables, as was the case of st and xt.
A rough characterization of the dataset can be seen below, for all t in T:
2
Data from IBGE’s IPCA, a nationwide consumer price index.
7
(i): πt – Inflation will be represented by percent quarterly variation in FGV’s IGP-M (General
Market Price Index), because of the unavailability (in such a frequency) in Brazil of a measure
like US’ GDP Deflator, used byGali and Gertler. Given that IGP-M is a linear combination of
a consumer price index (IPC), a producer price index (IPA) and a real state price index
(INCC), it is fairly broad measure and thus serve as a good proxy for inflation, given our
purposes. In IGP-M, IPA has weight of 0.6, IPC 0.3, and naturally INCC’s share is 0.1.
(ii): st – Marginal cost is obtained from the following expression:
st = log[St] – log[S*t],
where St = (WtNt)/ (GDPt
n
).
Wt is working people’s income (Rendimento Real das Pessoas Ocupadas –IBGE), Nt is labor
force (Ocupação - IBGE) and NGDPt is nominal gross domestic product (PIB Nominal –
IBGE). So, s(t) represents deviation of labor income share from its steady state value, which
we’ll assume here, as a proxy, to be its long term average. The idea of why one comes to use
such a measure in our tests will be given in Section IV. (See Figure 1)
(iii): xt is the detrended output gap:
xt = yt – y*t,
where, yt is the log of output (i.e., the log of the nominal GDP, released by IBGE, and
deflated by FGV’s IGP-M). Meanwhile, yt* is the a long run trend for the real GDP, a proxy
for the natural output, calculated using Hodrick-Prescott’s methodology (HP-Filter). (See
Figure 2)
(iv): it* is interest rates term spread. It is an instrument, which captures the evolution of the
difference between long run and short run interest rates. Such variable is heavily influenced
by future expected inflation. In our tests, we use the difference between TJLP rate (% per
8
annun) and 30 days CDB rate (bank deposit rates), with the first being a proxy for long run
interest rates, and the latter playing the role of short term interests.
(v): πw
t and πc
t are, respectively, percent change of labor income (a variable also used to
calculate s(t)) and percent change of FIPE’s IPC index (consumer’s price index). The first plays
the role of wage inflation, whilst the latter is just a standard consumer’s inflation measure.
(vi): πG
t is FGV’s IGP-DI index, another broad inflation measure, which comprises the same
imput variables as IGP-M (with the same weights), differing only in the period of observation
(difference of 10 days). It is used as instrument in most of our tests.
The interested reader will find out that this sample specification is closely connected
to the dataset used by Gali and Gertler, with marginal differences in interpretability, as in the
case of IGP-M substituing a measure like GDP Deflator. Even the choice of the set of
instruments used has respected the standards adopted in Gali and Gertler (1999).
II.C – Econometric Issues
As is commonly done across the literature, when it comes to estimate rational
expectation models, we test models using the generalized method of moments (GMM),
which also follows Gali and Gertler’s way. We shall estimate, for each model, both the
reduced and structural forms (when possible), sometimes imposing restrictions in some
parameters, in order to assess the robustness of results encountered, just like the original
authors have done.
The set of instruments utilized in GMM estimation will be the same for all tests
conduced throughout this work. In this regard, the only diverging point from the original
article is that we used up to 3 lags of each instruments, against 4 in Gali and Gerler (1999).
This was motivated by problem we faced with lack of data - contrarily to what happened in
the american research’s case - for the more lags we use, the less observations we have to
estimate models’ parameters. Comfortably, following that methodological decision, one
should expect no significant effect whatsoever in terms of parameters estimates, and results’
comparability. The set of instruments used is constituted by: lag 3 of wage inflation; lag 3 of
IPC; lag 2 of interest rate term spread; lag 2 of the output gap (HP-Filter); lags 0 until 3 of
IGP-DI and, finally, lags 1 and 2 of marginal cost.
9
For every model estimated, we used Heteroskedastic Autoregressive Consistent (HAC)
Covariance Matrix, proposed by Newey & West (1987), which guarantees more precise
standard error estimates, which are robust to both heteroskedasticity and serial correlation.
This allows us to be more confident on the results generated by the t-statistics, which will be
rejecting (or accepting) the null that the parameter equal zero with greater precision than
otherwise.
In case of models estimated by GMM (the vast majority in this work), we will perform
tests on the overidentifying restrictions, the so called TJ test. Unwilling to go so much deep
into econometric details, for this is not the scope here, the TJ statistic provide a test on the
null hypothesis that the excessive number of moments condition (i.e. the number of
instruments that exceeds the quantity of parameters estimated into the estimated equation) are
indeed valid. One can prove that TJ statistic is distributed by a Chi-Square p.d.f., with
w = r - a degrees of freedom, where r is the number of instruments and a the number of
parameters to be estimated. More details on such test can be found in Hamilton (1994).
III. The Problem of Estimating NKPC Using Output Gap
III.A – Some Theory First
One arrives at the NKPC by solving the problem of a monopolistically competitive
firm (or set of identical firms), which sets its (their) prices optimally, i.e., determining them
such that profits are maximized, subject to the constraint of time-dependent price adjustment.
Accordingly to Calvo, from the hypothesis of constant price elasticity of demand, we
obtain an aggregate price level such as follows (pt is the log of price level, which for
simplicity we name just price level):
pt = θpt-1 + (1-θ) pt* (1),
where θ is the probability that a firm will not change its prices in the current period. So,
aggregate price level is a convex combination of last period’s price level and an optimal price
set by firms (those able to change price in the current period).
10
Letting mct represents the deviation of a firm’s real marginal costs from its steady
state, and β the subjective discount rate, firms maximize their expected discounted profits (by
an stochastic discount factor, which adjusts for the risk), subject to time-dependent price
rules, determining their prices according to the expression below, for k between zero and
infinity:
pt* = (1-θ) Σk(βθ)k
Et{mct+k} (2).
It is interesting to notice that, when θ = 0, we have the case of fully flexible prices,
which in such case is to move accordingly to current marginal costs dynamics.
Letting πt = pt – pt-1 denote the inflation rate in tth
period, the two expressions above
lead us to the following testable equation (for apropriate mct):
πt = λmct + βEt{πt+1} (3),
where λ = θ-1
(1 - θ) (1 - βθ).
Using lead operators, we obtain, for k between zero and infinity:
πt = λ Σkβk
Et{mct+k} (4).
III.B – The econometrics of the NKPC (Traditional Approach)
In the past, researchers used the following relation to estimate expression (3):
mct = κxt (5),
where xt = yt – yt*, being yt the log of the product, and yt* the log of the “natural” product,
econometrically obtained through some smoothing methodology. Such hypothesis of linear
11
marginal cost (implicitly: quadratic cost function) yielded the following Phillips Curve, with κ
being marginal cost elasticity with respect to output:
πt = λκxt + βEt{πt+1} (6).
In consonance with our purposes, and similarly as done by Gali and Gertler, we
tested with brazilian data the following equation, lagging expression (6) by one period and
also imposing β = 1 and α = -λk.
πt = αxt-1 + πt-1 + εt (7).
Using OLS method, we obtained the following results for (7):
Table 1
Parameter Estimate Std. Error t-Statistic Prob.
α 0.152 0.067 2.260 0.0312
R-squared -0.803088 Mean dependent var 0.025894
Adjusted R-squared -0.803088 S.D. dependent var 0.018792
S.E. of regression 0.025233 Akaike info criterion -4.489572
Sum squared resid 0.019102 Schwarz criterion -4.443315
Log likelihood 70.58837 Durbin-Watson stat 2.587593
Notes: IGP-M used as the dependent variable. Exogenous variable is the log of the output gap, obtained by HP-Filter.
IGP-M lagged byone period is another regressor in (7), however the test impose its coefficient to equal to one.
OLS procedure used in estimation, with Newey & West HAC covariance matrix.
Adjusted Sample: 1994:4 – 2002:2, with 31 observations.
In the test shown above, we found a weakly significant (at 5% level, but not in a 1%
sized test) and positive coefficient estimate, which comes relatively in synchrony with results
obtained in the american study, where the authors yielded a significant positive value for
α (trully, they got a equal to 0.081, rejecting the null on T-test at 1% level). The interpretation
for such outcome is the same as in the original work, with this test above providing further
evidence against the old fashioned way of estimating the New Keynesian Phillips Curve. In
fact, such tests for both US and Brazil’s economy are more likely to support the old Phillips
Curve (which uses Et-1{πt} instead of Et{πt+1}), rather than the one formulated by Calvo.
Primarily, this would off course be viewed as a negative empirical result for Calvo’s model,
had researchers not proven (with both american, and later on, with european data) the
12
validity of the marginal cost approach to estimate parameters from the NKPC in Calvo’s
fashion. We shall verify, in the sections that follow, if such results also hold true for the
brazilian economy as well.
IV. Marginal Costs Approach: The Purely Forward
Looking NKPC
IV.A – Motivating The New Specification
The poor empirical results obtained by Calvo’s NKPC, using data from both US and
Brazil’s economy (the latter testified by the earlier section of this current work), when
computing the output gap by some smooth technique, might not be a decisive evidence
against Calvo’s model. In other words, these bad results should not lead to the rejection of its
empirical validity, as some might conclude at a first glance. Gali and Gartler’s point is that
such results are directly influenced by the methodology used to obtain the natural output, and
the outcome of empirical tests on NKPC may be quite different conditional on the smoothing
technique deployed. The authors claim that structural shocks, like change in tastes and
variations in government spending may have an impact such that it offsets the forecasted
negative relation between inflation acceleration today and the output gap last period. So it
would be useful if we had a proxy for the output gap which did not suffer from this problem.
The approach used here (for brazilian data), originally proposed in Gali and Gertler (1999), is
to use marginal costs as a proxy to the output gap.
Gali and Gertler sustain that an alternative way to test the NKPC model is, instead of
estimating equation (6), estimating the expression (3), replacing therefore the output gap (xt)
by the marginal costs (mct). Since the latter are not directly observable, we must use theory to
guide efforts on how to obtain such variable, so allowing us to go into estimation procedures.
Section II.B of this current work shows details on how we obtained the measure of marginal
costs (for the brazilian economy) which is deployed here. It is important to highlight here that
the procedure used to get the marginal costs measure is meant to be as near as possible to the
one proposed by the authors in this paper’s “original (american) version”.
Let’s go straight to the point, now. Suppose a Cobb Douglas production function like
13
Yt = AtKt
αk
Nt
αn
(8).
Real marginal costs can be expressed by the ratio of the real wage to the labor’s
marginal product:
MCt = (Wt/Pt)( ?Yt/?Nt)-1
(9).
Some algebraic manipulations, i.e., inserting using expression (8) and the partial
derivative of Yt with respect to Nt into (9), yields the following expression below:
MCt = Stαn
-1
(10),
where St = WtNt(PtYt)-1
.
From St, the share of labor income, we obtain st, which represents the percent
deviations of St from its steady state level (the latter is estimated by use of HP-Filter):
st = log[St] – log[St*] (10*).
Then, st will then be used in the NKPC’s specifications that we test here, providing
our measure of marginal cost that will replace (as a proxy for) the standard measure of the
output gap.
So, in the next section, we test the following version of Calvo’s NKPC:
πt = λst + βEt{πt+1} (11),
where λ = θ-1
(1 - θ) (1 - βθ).
14
IV.B – Testing Calvo’s NKPC Using Marginal Costs
IV.B.1 – Reduced Form Estimates
As we have mentioned earlier, the estimation technique chosen to be applied to (11)
is GMM, Generalized Method of Moments, very handy and widely deployed to test rational
expectation models (as is the case now). One can show, by means of the iterated expectations
law, that expression (11) implies the following moment condition, in the reduced form:
Et{(πt - λst - βπt+1)Zt } = 0 (12).
Here, Zt denotes the set of instruments defined in section II.B, the very same one that will be
used in all tests henceforth.
Table 2
Parameter
Estimate
Std. Error t-Statistic Prob.
λ 0.167 0.081 2.061 0.0494
β 0.947 0.049 19.148 0.0000
S.E. of regression 0.027701 Sum squared resid 0.019950
Durbin-Watson stat 2.846987 J-statistic 0.145939
Notes: IGP-M used as inflation measure. Marginal cost obtained by expression (10*). Instruments list can be viewed in Section II.B.
GMM estimation procedure used, with Newey & West HAC covariance matrix estimation
Convergence achieved after 54 iterations.
Adjusted Sample: 1995:2 – 2002:1, with 28 observations.
TJ test failed to reject the null hypothesis of validity of overidentifying restrictions at 10%, 5% and 1% levels - Chi-Square pdf at 8 d.f..
For the american economy, Gali and Gertler (1999) had:
πt = 0.023st + 0.942Et{πt+1}
(0.012) (0.045)
And for the european economy, Gali, Gertler and Salido (2001) found:
πt = 0.088st + 0.914Et{πt+1}
(0.041) (0.040)
15
Thus, what we got a positive (and significant at 5%) value for λ, using marginal cost
replacing as a proxy to the “actual” output gap. These results exposed in the table above are
not so different to those obtained for the american economy (listed below). The great
discrepancy concerns the estimates for λ, given that output elasticity obtained for brazilian
data is 7 times as high as the one gotten in the american case, and almost the double of
estimates from european economy. In addition, the significance of λ is rather weak in
brazilian case, for we fail to reject the null at 1% level, contrarily to what happens for the
Europe and US economies. Nevertheless, it is also interesting to notice the similar values
obtained for the betas (not only coefficient estimates, but also standard deviations), implying
impatience rates relatively consistent, and not very contradictory, across the three economies
tested.
It could also be worthwhile to provide, at this point, some information on the TJ test.
In the test of (12), we failed to reject the null hypothesis about the validity of the (r – a)
overidentifying restrictions, where r is the quantity of instruments (10) and a is the number of
parameters estimated (2). At 5%, the critical value of Chi-Square at 8 degrees of freedom is
15.51, greater than the value of 4.09 obtained for the TJ statistic. In fact, the same will
happen to all conditions tested henceforth, so we shall not waste time in detailing further TJ
results on these tests.
For symmetry ends, allowing us to compare this new approach to estimate the NKPC
with the traditional one, we replaced st for xt in (12), and estimated its parameters for the
brazilian economy, yielding the following results:
Table 3
Parameter
Estimate
Std. Error t-Statistic Prob.
λ -0.543 0.076 -7.141 0.0000
β 1.088 0.110 9.929 0.0000
S.E. of regression 0.036116 Sum squared resid 0.033913
Durbin-Watson stat 1.877362 J-statistic 0.164286
Notes: IGP-M used as inflation measure. Log of the output gap used (HP-Filter). Instruments list can be viewed in Section II.B.
GMM estimation procedure used, with Newey & West HAC covariance matrix estimation
Convergence achieved after 500 iterations.
Adjusted Sample: 1995:2 – 2002:1, with 28 observations.
TJ test failed to reject the null hypothesis of validity of overidentifying restrictions at 10%, 5% and 1% levels - Chi-Square pdf at 8 d.f..
16
With regard to this particular test, results for the US economy were3
:
πt = -0.016xt + 0.988Et{πt+1}
(0.005) (0.030)
For Europe, it was found that:
πt = -0.003xt + 0.990Et{πt+1}
(0.007) (0.018)
Although our test above has come up with an estimate for λ differing considerably
from those obtained in Gali and Gertler (1999) for american data, and in Gali, Gertler and
Salido (2001) for european data, in general, the evidence found here is roughly the same as in
the papers cited above: results of empirical tests on NKPC have been poorer replacing
marginal costs by conventional output gap measure (i.e. log-output detrended by HP-Filter).
And, at the margin, results encountered for the brazilian sample have become even worse
using the standard output gap, in comparison to the tests performed for the other economies.
To justify this claim, we have the observation here of a negativeλ (the same sign as in
the test for US and Europe), as well as the finding of β> 1, similarly as new estmates for the
US economy. Using results from ours and other previous experiments, we robustly find that
results on NKPC estimation, mainly those concerning the sign of parameter λ, depend heavily
on type the instrument chosen to proxy the output gap. Furthermore, the value found for the
beta (yielding an estimate greater than one for both US and Brazil, see footnote 3) is very
implausible, for agents should not like better the future than the present, a widely accepted
economic hypothesis unobserved by a negative impatience rate implied by β> 1. In all, the
tests with brazilian data shown here may strengthen the conclusion that the use of marginal
cost approach is indeed valid to estimate the NKPC. It also reinforce empirical evidence
favoring Calvo’s model.
IV.B.2 – Structural Form Estimates
The tests displayed above were performed using reduced form equations. An
additional exercise useful at this point is try to estimate equation (12) in the structural form,
that is, to test an specification where (in particular) parameter λ is written as function of θ and
β. In case of (12), by the use of (11), we have:
3
In Gali, Gertler and Salido (2001), they show new(updated)estimates for the american economy, where it
17
Et{(θπt – (1-θ)(1-θβ)st – θβπt+1)Zt} = 0 (13).
So, our next step is to estimate equation (13), using exactly the same set of
instruments used before, which will now allow us to obtain estimates for the structural
parameter θ. The importance of such parameter is that, in Calvo’s model, it denotes the
probability that a given price setter will leave price unchanged in the current period. With
knowledge of this parameters, one is able to determine the average time that a certain price is
to remain unchanged, which is given by:
(1-θ)Σkkθk-1
= (1-θ)-1
(E).
More details on that can be found in Gali and Gertler (1999b). By use of this
expression above, we find an interesting empirical measure: how often, in average, agents
change their prices. In a comparative basis across countries, we expect the brazilian data to
show agents changing prices more frequently than in US and Europe, regions where inflation
has let few “scars” in the recent decades.
Tests performed on equation (13) gave us the following results:
Table 4
Parameter
Estimate
Std.
Error
t-Statistic Prob.
θ 0.593 0.035 16.705 0.0000
β 0.875 0.052 16.814 0.0000
λa
0.330 - - -
S.E. of regression 0.016848 Sum squared resid 0.007380
Durbin-Watson stat 2.738034 J-statistic 0.151415
Notes: IGP-M used as inflation measure. Marginal cost obtained by expression (10*). Instruments list can be viewed in Section II.B.
GMM estimation procedure used, with Newey & West HAC covariance matrix estimation
Convergence achieved after 43 iterations.
Adjusted Sample: 1995:2 – 2002:1, with 28 observations.
TJ test failed to reject the null hypothesis of validity of overidentifying restrictions at 10%, 5% and 1% levels - Chi-Square pdf at 8 d.f..
a
Implied value for λ obtained by replacing estimatedθ and β in expression (11).
turned out that λ = 0.021, and β = 1.012, both significant at 1% level.
18
For the same test, results gotten with US and European:
Table 5
US Economy
Results
Euro Economy Results
Parameter
Estimate
Std.
Error Estimate
Std. Error
θ 0.829 0.013 0.904 0.011
β 0.926 0.024 0.886 0.042
λa
0.047 - 0.021 -
a
Implied value for λ obtained by replacing estimatedθ and β in expression (11).
In order to assess the robustness of our estimates, and also following Gali and Gertler (1999),
we tested (13) imposing β = 1:
Table 6
Parameter
Estimate
Std.
Error
t-Statistic Prob.
θ -0.353463 0.116952 -3.022291 0.0054
λa
-5.182613 - - -
S.E. of regression 0.037159 Sum squared resid 0.037281
Durbin-Watson stat 1.519811 J-statistic 0.191011
Notes: IGP-M used as inflation measure. Marginal cost obtained by expression (10*). Instruments list can be viewed in Section II.B.
GMM estimation procedure used, with Newey & West HAC covariance matrix estimation
Convergence achieved after 40 iterations.
Adjusted Sample: 1995:2 – 2002:1, with 28 observations.
TJ test failed to reject the null hypothesis of validity of overidentifying restrictions at 10%, 5% and 1% levels - Chi-Square pdf at 8 d.f..
a
Implied value for λ obtained by replacing estimatedθ and imposition ofβ =1 in expression (11).
For the US economy4
, our benchmark, results in Gali and Gertler (1999) imposingβ = 1:
Table 7
US Economy Results
Parameter Estimate Std. Error
θ 0.829 0.016
λa
0.035 -
a
Implied value for λ obtained by replacing estimatedθ and β in expression (11).
4
Tests with restricted β (equal to one) were not performed in Gali, Gertler and Salido (2001).
19
Since GMM is quite sensible to the way one performs normalizations on the estimated
moments conditions, similarly as done by the authors, we will test an alternative form of
equation (13). This alternative equation, expressed by (14), is characterized to be obtained by
trivial manipulation of (13), i.e., being just a another way to write down such formula. So, we
estimate (14) using the very same procedure, in order to observe the robustness of estimation
results obtained in tests on condition (13).
Et{(πt – θ−1
(1-θ)(1-θβ)st – βπt+1)Zt} = 0 (14).
For equation (14), we got, using brazilian data:
Table 8
Parameter
Estimate
Std.
Error
t-Statistic Prob.
θ 0.642 0.047 13.714 0.0000
β 0.902 0.049 18.302 0.0000
λa
0.235 - - -
S.E. of regression 0.027789 Sum squared resid 0.020078
Durbin-Watson stat 2.795883 J-statistic 0.150605
Notes: IGP-M used as inflation measure. Marginal cost obtained by expression (10*). Instruments list can be viewed in Section II.B.
GMM estimation procedure used, with Newey & West HAC covariance matrix estimation
Convergence achieved after 15 iterations.
Adjusted Sample: 1995:2 – 2002:1, with 28 observations.
TJ test failed to reject the null hypothesis of validity of overidentifying restrictions at 10%, 5% and 1% levels - Chi-Square pdf at 8 d.f..
a
Implied value for λ obtained by replacing estimatedθ and β in expression (11).
For the same type of test, results for US and European data had been:
Table 9
US Economy
Results
Euro Economy Results
Parameter
Estimate
Std.
Error Estimate
Std. Error
θ 0.884 0.020 0.918 0.015
β 0.941 0.018 0.914 0.040
λa
0.021 - 0.014 -
a
Implied value for λ obtained by replacing estimatedθ and β in expression (11).
20
Analogously, imposing β = 1:
Table 10
Parameter
Estimate
Std.
Error
t-Statistic Prob.
θ 0.699 0.073 9.618 0.0000
λa
0.130 - - -
S.E. of regression 0.027523 Sum squared resid 0.020452
Durbin-Watson stat 2.878300 J-statistic 0.147589
Notes: IGP-M used as inflation measure. Marginal cost obtained by expression (10*). Instruments list can be viewed in Section II.B.
GMM estimation procedure used, with Newey & West HAC covariance matrix estimation
Convergence achieved after 35 iterations.
Adjusted Sample: 1995:2 – 2002:1, with 28 observations.
TJ test failed to reject the null hypothesis of validity of overidentifying restrictions at 10%, 5% and 1% levels - Chi-Square pdf at 8 d.f..
a
Implied value for λ obtained by replacing estimatedθ and β in expression (11).
For the US economy5
, our benchmark, results in Gali and Gertler (1999) were:
Table 11
US Economy
Results
Parameter
Estimate
Std.
Error
θ 0.915 0.035
λa
0.007 -
a
Implied value for λ obtained by replacing estimatedθ and β in expression (11).
It is worthwhile at this time to establish some comments on the results shown above.
In what refers to parameter λ, results robustly indicate a higher estimated value for brazilian
economy (comparing to those gotten from US and Europe), with our estimates ranging in
general on (0.13,0.33). This is an evidence that the output-gap6
elasticity of inflation is greater
for Brazil’s economy, implying that, in this country, inflation responds more (generally
upwards, we know) to given changes in output gap, in comparison to other developed
countries. This is a somewhat intuitive result, for historical reasons, since Brazil has lived
periods of huge inflation, and this may institutionally have affected the way inflation (through
5
Tests with restricted β (equal to one) were not performed in Gali, Gertler and Salido (2001).
6
Using marginal costs as a proxy.
21
price setters) responds to output movements, despite the fact that we cannot rule out the
possibility that maybe the difference is to high to be true.
Furthermore, after estimating the structural form equation, in both ways of
normalization, the vector (θ,β) of brazilian unrestricted always came with values in a very
reasonable range. The estimated values for β were confined in the (0.87,0.91) interval,
implying some acceptable levels of agents’ impatience rate, quite in line with estimates from
Europe and the US. Meanwhile, estimates for θ stayed within (0.59,0.65), a somewhat lower
level than results obtained with american and european data, but still valid. Trully, we have
an explanation for such difference between brazilian and foreign estimates: as one is able to
see, in Table 12, that the lower estimated values for brazilian θ (in both normalizations)
imply quite robustly that brazilian price setters, in average, tend to change prices more
frequently than its american and european counterparts. As we have stated earlier this results
comes acordingly to our expectations. For instance, accordingly to the estimates performed
by us and the authors, and using results on equation (14), in a period when european price
setters (in average) have changed their prices only once, and the americans roughly less than
twice, brazilians would have changed prices more than four times. Such result is firmly
backed-up by economic intuition, since we know that inflationary culture is latent in Brazil, a
consequence of the long years economic agents were forced to live in a hyperinflationary
environment.
Table 12
Still commenting the estimation results, when we imposed the β to equal one, our
results were not so good when we tested condition (13), though things were notoriously
different for expression (14). In the first case, the imposition of beta yielded a negative
estimate for θ, which does not make any sense at all, for θ is a probability, which obviously
22
must lie in the interval [0,1]. In the latter case, however, the estimate for θ was very robust to
the restriction imposed, and the estimates lied within (0.64, 0.70), not much different from
the unrestricted estimate of (13).
The sticky result obtained in (13), which did not resist to the imposition of β =1,
contrasting with american results, proven to be more robust, is indeed something that lead us
to seek explanations. One excuse we have is that is sample size asymmetries between the
two studies (our and Gali and Gertler’s), with the american work having much more data
available - around 37 years of quarterly observations - compared to the 32 quarterly
observations within our dataset. We can speculate that this sets a toll into the robustness of
our results, because of consistency reasons.
Notwithstanding, in the overall, having obtained some reasonable estimates for
parameters in the tests performed here, one should be quite satisfied with the results herein
mentioned. They should, indeed, be considered as another good evidence for Calvo’s
implied NKPC, supporting Gali and Gertler’s argument.
V. Marginal Costs Approach: The Hybrid NKPC
V.A – Motivating The New Specification
As we pointed out earlier, some of the criticism on Calvo’s derivation of the NKPC is
aimed at the purely forward looking agent’s behavior it implies. In fact, NKPC supposes
unrealistically that only current and future events in the economy (more specifically, the ones
affecting the output gap) will be important in inflation determination. Nevertheless, no single
economist, who roughly watches empirical economic events, can feel comfortable with such
an idea. It underestimates the phenomenon of persistence in inflation trajectory, which has
already been documented by empirical work like Christiano et al.(2001).
In addition, most central banks around the world use inflation models incorporating
such feature. In particular, the Central Bank of Brazil is no exception to such rule, with all
versions of its inflation targeting model hypothesizing a variant of Phillips Curve which
allows for the presence of inertia in inflation stochastic process7
. With this regard, inflation
inertia in Brazil is considered by economists as key issue for the pathological
hyperinflationary process observed in the country’s economic past.
23
In order to test for the presence of a backward looking component in the inflation
trajectory, we run some models for the Brazilian economy, still in the Gali and Gertler’s
flavor. In their paper, using Calvo’s framework, they attach to the purely forward looking
NKPC a backward looking inflation component, in order to capture the persistence effects in
inflationary process.
V.B – Some Theory, Just for The Record
Respecting the same set of assumptions adopted in Calvo’s model, we might now
suppose, additionally (in ad hoc way), that some fraction ω of firms use an easy rule of thumb
to set their prices, based on past information. This is somewhat different from what we had
before: a bunch (randomly selected) companies setting prices by solving their profit
maximization problem, subject to time-dependent adjustments constraints, using all
information available to foresee future economic conditions, mainly, future marginal costs.
We shall now classify these firms as Forward Looking (FL), henceforth. In addition to these
firms, our new economy has another class of price setters - firms that set prices depending on
what they observed in the past – using history-dependent price rules. They constitute the
group of Backward Looking firms (BL).
In such environment, aggregate prices are determined by the following expressions:
pt = θpt-1 + (1-θ)pt* (15),
pt* = (1-ω)pt
f
+ ωpt
b
(16),
where pt* is the restricted aggregate price index, for prices set in the current period, pt
f
and
pt
b
are, respectively, new prices for (FL) and (BL) firms. They obey the following rules (let k be
a time-index from period zero to infinity):
pt
f
= (1-θβ)Σk(θβ)k
Et{mct+k} (17),
pt
b
= p t-1* + π t-1 (18).
7
The interested reader is referred to Bogdanski, Tombini and Werlang (2000) and Bogdanski et al.(2001).
24
One can observe that pt
f
is just the optimal price chosen in the purely forward looking
model. It is worth to verify that the (ad hoc) establishment of pt
b
has an interesting property:
for stationary inflation dynamics, the rule converges to the optimal forward looking price
setting rule, as time goes by.
Closing the derivation of this variant of NKPC – called the hybrid Phillips Curve – one
is able to obtain the expression below from combining equations (15) to (18):
πt = λmct + γf
Et{πt+1} + γb
πt-1 (19),
where
λ = (1 - ω)(1 - θ)(1 - θβ)φ-1
,
γf
= θβφ-1
,
γb
=ωφ-1
,
φ = θ +ω[1 – θ(1 - β)].
V.C – Estimating the Hybrid Model
V.C.1 – Structural Form Estimates
By the substitution in (19) of λ, γf
and γb
, as well as the replacement of mct by st
8
, we
get the following moments conditions, in the structural form:
Et{(φπt – (1-ω)(1-θ)(1-θβ)st – θβπt+1)Zt} = 0
(20),
Et{(πt – φ-1
(1-ω)(1-θ)(1-θβ)st – φ-1
θβπt+1)Zt} = 0 (21).
Unfortunately, our empirical tests on this structural form, for brazilian data, has been
disappointing. For neither (20) nor (21) we could estimate the moment condition’s
parameters, for we invariantly obtained singular covariance matrices, which violate necessary
8
Reminding the reader that St is the measure of marginal costs’ percent deviation from its steady state,
already deployed in previous tests of ours.
25
boundness condition and impede us to obtain valid estimates. This also happened for other
instrument sets than Zt also tested.
One hypothetical explanation is that micronumerosity is showing its ugly head here,
setting a huge toll on the estimation procedures. Moreover, it is worth highlighting that when
we imposed a restriction that ω = 1, the singular matrix problem could be solved for the set
of instruments deployed throughout this work (i.e. Zt), but this would not resolve our
problem.
In all, this is quite bad for empirical reasons, for it would be useful to have further
estimates that could (luckily) strengthen our conclusions already reached over θ, β and λ,as
well as it could provide (brand new) estimates for ω, γb
and γf
, parameters for which we have
no results whatsoever this far.
In the paper that inspired this current work, Gali and Gertler have only tested the
structural form equations, and they never mention anything about reduced form estimation
results on the hybrid curve. So, in order to observe empirical evidence on such important
issue - the degree of brazilian inflation’s persistence or, if one will, the ‘backwardness’ of the
inflationary dynamics in Brazil - we detach for a while from the procedures adopted in Gali
and Gertler (1999). From now on, we will be encharged to perform tests on the reduced form
of the hybrid NKPC.
V.C.1 – Reduced Form Estimates
As just stated above, in this sub-section, with will to obtain estimates for important
inflation dynamics’ parameters, we mean to test the reduced form of the hybrid curve. In
order to do so, and likewise the procedure followed in the previous tests, we will be using
the marginal costs approach. From expression (19) we get the following testable equation,
substituting mct for our measure of marginal costs percent deviations from its steady-state:
πt = λst + γf
Et{πt+1} + γb
πt-1(22).
Through the application of the Iterated Expectations Law in (22), one obtain the next
moment condition:
Et{(πt – λst – γf
πt+1 – γb
πt-1)Zt} = 0 (23).
26
Using the same set of instruments as in our previous tests (Zt), the estimation results of (23)
are shown in Table 13:
Table 13
Parameter Estimate Std. Error t-Statistic Prob.
λ 0.480 0.088 5.429 0.0000
γf
-0.140 0.087 -1.608 0.1203
γb
0.704 0.083 8.445 0.0000
S.E. of regression 0.029469 Sum squared resid 0.021710
Durbin-Watson stat 2.225785 J-statistic 0.158096
Notes: IGP-M used as inflation measure. Marginal cost obtained by expression (10*). Instruments list can be viewed in Section II.B.
GMM estimation procedure used, with Newey & West HAC covariance matrix estimation
Convergence achieved after 47 iterations.
Adjusted Sample: 1995:2 – 2002:1, with 28 observations.
TJ test failed to reject the null hypothesis of validity of overidentifying restrictions at 10%, 5% and 1% levels - Chi-Square pdf at 8 d.f..
In order to gain further interpretability, we compare our estimates with results obtained in
Gali and Gertler (1999) for the US economy, and Gali, Gertler and Salido (2001) for the
european economy. One should be cautious at this point here, for these authors have
estimated only the structural form of the hybrid NKPC, which hampers somewhat the
symmetry of the comparison established herein. Nevertheless, it might not completely
invalidate it, so we display the “foreign” results (for both types of normalization) in Table 14
and 15:
Table 14
US Economy Results
Normalization (20) Normalization (21)
Parameter
Estimate
Std.
Error Estimate
Std. Error
λ 0.037 - 0.015 -
γf
0.682 0.020 0.591 0.016
γb
0.252 0.023 0.378 0.020
27
Table 15
European Economy Results
Normalization (20) Normalization (21)
Parameter
Estimate
Std.
Error Estimate
Std. Error
λ 0.018 - 0.006 -
γf
0.877 0.045 0.689 0.044
γb
0.025 0.127 0.272 0.072
The results obtained this far for the hybrid NKPC in the brazilian economy allows us
to establish the following parallel to the analogous estimates in the US and european
economies. First of all, in the meantime, theλ are still much higher for the brazilian economy
than for our benchmark economies, which comes very much in line to previous estimates for
the same parameter contained in the NKPC specifications tested before (the levels are
proportional too).
Second, as expected for the historical reasons already mentioned, the brazilian
inflationary dynamics was the one with the highest degree of persistence (or inertia, if one
will). This might well be a consequence of a “price indexation culture” present in Brazil: after
many years of high inflation, price setters became used to observe past inflation and reset
their prices likewise. Maybe this culture or habit has not been left aside yet by a considerable
fraction of brazilian price setters, even after the Real Plan implementation (which indeed
stabilized prices). In other words, our view is that the highly persistent inflation dynamics in
Brazil might be result of sluggish agents’ behavior, who got used to living in a widespread
price indexation environment, as was the case for the Brazilian economy in the past.
Third, one bizarre result that we found is the lack of significance in the forward
looking component in brazilian inflation process. This could hint to some the possibility that
brazilian inflation expectations are, even in the Real era, purely adaptative, implying a high
level of irrationality from price setters in Brazil. This last result is very strong, and may force
us to go into further tests in order to validate it.
Therefore, for robustness assessment purposes, we also estimated variants of (23)
allowing inflation lags of higher order to enter into the hybrid NKPC specification. The
empirical tests for them in Brazil gave us the following results:
28
Table 16
Parameter
Estimate
Std.
Error
t-
Statistic
Prob.
λ 0.242 0.073 3.318 0.0029
γf
0.968 0.320 3.028 0.0058
γb
(L1
) 0.685 0.175 3.914 0.0007
γb
(L2
) -0.664 0.192 -3.460 0.0020
Mean dependent var 0.000000 S.D. dependent var 0.000000
S.E. of regression 0.031845 Sum squared resid 0.024339
Durbin-Watson stat 3.176994 J-statistic 0.111940
Notes: IGP-M used as inflation measure. Marginal cost obtained by expression (10*). Instruments list can be viewed in Section II.B.
GMM estimation procedure used, with Newey & West HAC covariance matrix estimation
Convergence achieved after 93 iterations.
Adjusted Sample: 1995:2 – 2002:1, with 28 observations.
TJ test failed to reject the null hypothesis of validity of overidentifying restrictions at 10%, 5% and 1% levels - Chi-Square pdf at 8 d.f..
Table 17
Parameter
Estimate
Std.
Error
t-
Statistic
Prob.
λ 0.089 0.034 2.643 0.0145
γf
0.562 0.155 3.614 0.0015
γb
(L1
) 0.478 0.136 3.522 0.0018
γb
(L2
) -0.650 0.123 -5.290 0.0000
γb
(L3
) 0.499 0.061 8.152 0.0000
Mean dependent var 0.000000 S.D. dependent var 0.000000
S.E. of regression 0.025332 Sum squared resid 0.014760
Durbin-Watson stat 3.396762 J-statistic 0.068357
Notes: IGP-M used as inflation measure. Marginal cost obtained by expression (10*). Instruments list can be viewed in Section II.B.
GMM estimation procedure used, with Newey & West HAC covariance matrix estimation
Convergence achieved after 37 iterations.
Adjusted Sample: 1995:2 – 2002:1, with 28 observations.
TJ test failed to reject the null hypothesis of validity of overidentifying restrictions at 10%, 5% and 1% levels - Chi-Square pdf at 8 d.f..
The estimates displayed in Tables 16 and 17 may show us a weird result for the
brazilian economy. As we allow a greater number of inflation lags to enter into the hybrid
NKPC, some phenomenon occur: (i) the elasticity of inflation with respect to the output gap
(marginal cost as a proxy), denoted by the parameter λ, shrinks as more lags of inflation are
used. In the last test, one can notice that the estimated value comes very close to those
estimates for the US and Europe’s economy, though brazilian figures are still higher (possibly
for the economic reasons already explained previously); (ii) the forward looking component
of inflation expectations becomes significant as more inflation lags are added; (iii) the
estimated value for γb
(L1
) is monotonically decreasing in the number of inflation lags being
29
inserted into the hybrid NKPC. Perhaps all issues from (i) to (iii) are a symptom of some
excluded variable bias in coefficient estimates. This is even more clear in case of (iii), when it
seems that γb
(L1
) gives back the due credit merited by γb
(L3
) on pushing the current inflation
movements, when the latter is included in the specification.
Anyway, in the last estimation of (23) performed (which includes three inflation lags)
the reasonable estimate for some parameters like λ and γf
, which come not only in line with
previous brazilian estimates (in other models) but also compatible to international estimated
values, may be interpreted as a strong hint that this may be the a nice specification to
approximate (i.e. to fit the data on) brazilian inflation dynamics.
Another curious result, and quite robust, we might say, is the negative impact that
inflation lagged by two periods has in current inflation, yielding values close to –0.65 in the
two last tests. This result lacks intuitiveness. The only explanation found this far for this
implied sinusoidal inflation dynamics in Brazil is the possibility that brazilian inflation (in the
Real era) displays a mean-revertion property, which impedes it to diverge. However, we shall
be conservative now and treat this issue more like a puzzle to be resolved, instead of being
satisfied with such explanation (speculation) just given.
One last (but not least) point refers to inflation persistence. As our tests could show as
empirical evidence, brazilian inflation displays huge degree of inertia in prices acceleration.
Such results comes much in line with our expectations based on theory and empirical
literature. This is a quite important issue for policy makers, since at the margin, monetary
policy tends to be less effective in controlling inflation when agents actions are so much
dependent on the past. Or equivalently, such high degree of irrationality may worsen the so
called (and theoretically supported) by Mankiw (2000) “inexorable” tradeoff between
inflation and output.
30
VI. Conclusions
In general, the results obtained in this replication of Gali and Gertler’s experiments,
for the Brazilian economy, were supportive for Calvo´s theory when tests were performed
using real marginal costs as proxy for the true output gap, as was done by the authors. This
outcome comes in line with those obtained for the both US and european economy, despite
some natural differences in estimated parameters. Here, in most tests, we had reasonable
parameter values (i.e. estimates lying in a very acceptable range, accordingly to the theory).
Considering data deficiencies in Brazil, this is something positive.
On empirical grounds, one key conclusion we could obtain with our tests is the deep
and notorious inflationary culture, which is present in Brazil’s economy. Our tests verified
that not only inflationary inertia is a key issue in this country, much more than in the US and
Europe, but also that brazilian price setters, compared to their american and european
counterpart have (in average) habit to change prices much more frequently. In Brazil, one can
say that this is a quite “inflationary” habit, given empirical resistance from price setters to
lower their prices. Another evidence of an inflationary culture is the greater sensibility of
brazilian inflation to the output gap, when compared to the inflation dynamics in both the US
and in Europe. Such conclusion is intuitive, since, in the recent decades, Brazil has suffered
from hyperinflationary maladies, contrarily to what happened for the two other regions
tested.
Notwithstanding, methodologically, one should not disguise the fact that this work
here still needs to be improved in terms of robustness of the results. Some of the parameters
estimated, in spite of being in reasonable parameter range, are still varying undesirably. In
some tests, results changed more than we wanted it to by altering the normalization of
moment’s condition or imposing parameters restrictions.
Robustness is, in fact, the main point that need development in this work. Our guess
is that the smaller degree of robustness in our estimates is caused by the lack of observations
we had (32 points, compared to more than 140 in the american work). In addition to have
hampered any robustness analysis to be performed in sub-periods, the lack of data might have
affected some estimates (the ones showing counter-intuitive results), for parameter estimates’
consistency require greater number of observations. This may explain, also, in our opinion,
the variability of estimates results, because GMM is only asymptotically efficient, and
micronumerosity might have set a toll on variance estimates as well.
31
References
Bogdanski, J., Tombini, A.A., Werlang, S.R.C., 2000, “Implementing Inflation
Targeting in Brazil”, Central Bank of Brazil Working Paper #1.
Bogdanski, J., Freitas, P.S., Goldfajn, I., Tombini, A.A., 2001, “Inflation Targeting in
Brazil: Shocks, Backward-Looking Prices and IMF Conditionality”, Central
Bank of Brazil Working Paper #24, August.
Christiano, L., Eichenbaum, M., Evans, C., 2000, “Monetary Policy Shocks: What Have
We Learned and To What End?”, Handbook of Macroeconomics.
Clarida, R., Gali, J. and Gertler, M., 1999b, “The Science of Monetary Policy: a New
Keynesian Perspective”, Journal of Economic Literature 37 #2, 1661-1707.
Gali, J., 1999, “Technology, Employment, and the Business Cycle: Do
Technology Shocks Explain Aggregate Fluctuations?”, American Economic
Review, March, 249-271.
Gali, J. and Gertler, M., 1999, “Inflation Dynamics: A Structural Econometric
Analysis”, Journal of Monetary Economics 44, 195-222.
Gali, J. and Gertler, M., Salido, J.D.L., 2001, “European Inflation Dynamics”, NBER
Working Paper # 8218.
Hamilton, J.D., 1994, “Time Series Analysis”, Princeton University Press.
Lucas, R.E., 1976, “Econometric Policy Evaluation: A Critique”, Carnegie-
Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy. (1), 19-46.
32
Mankiw, N.G., 2000, “The Inexorable and Mysterious Tradeoff Between
Inflation and Unemployment”, NBER Working Paper # 7884.
Newey, W.K., West, K.D., 1987, “A Simple Positive Semi-Definite
Heteroskedasticity and Autocorrelation Covariance Matrix”, Econometrica (55),
703-708.
Roberts, J.M., 1995, “New Keynesian Economics and the Phillips Curve”, Journal
of Money, Credit and Banking Vol. 27 (4), 975-984.
Sbordone, A.M., 2000, “Prices and Unit Labor Costs: A New Test of Price
Stickiness”, Institute of International Economic Studies, Stockholm, Seminar Paper
#653, April (revised).
Woodford, M., 2001, “Interest and Prices”, mimeo.
33
Figure 1. Marginal Costs and Its Long-Term Trend (HP-Filter)
This graph shows marginal costs and its trend (by HP Filter)
Figure 2. Smoothing Log-Output By Use of Hodrick Prescott Filter
This graph displays log output and natural log output (obtained by HP-Filter)
3.70
3.75
3.80
3.85
3.90
3.95
4.00
4.05
95 96 97 98 99 00 01 02
LOG_MGCOST HP_LOGMGCOST
11.6
11.8
12.0
12.2
12.4
12.6
12.8
95 96 97 98 99 00 01 02
LOG_GDP HP_LOGGDP

Contenu connexe

En vedette

Fiscal Multipliers in Brazil (IADB Brasilia 2012)_MO_FINAL
Fiscal Multipliers in Brazil (IADB Brasilia 2012)_MO_FINALFiscal Multipliers in Brazil (IADB Brasilia 2012)_MO_FINAL
Fiscal Multipliers in Brazil (IADB Brasilia 2012)_MO_FINALMauricio Oreng
 
III Foro Alternativas de Sostenibilidad - Jaume Garau
III Foro Alternativas de Sostenibilidad - Jaume GarauIII Foro Alternativas de Sostenibilidad - Jaume Garau
III Foro Alternativas de Sostenibilidad - Jaume GarauFundación Alternativas
 
Ajankohtaista Kansallisesta rokotusohjelmasta
Ajankohtaista Kansallisesta rokotusohjelmastaAjankohtaista Kansallisesta rokotusohjelmasta
Ajankohtaista Kansallisesta rokotusohjelmastaTHL
 
"Méthodologie alternative au FAOSTAT Atelier du Groupe Technique Régional (GT...
"Méthodologie alternative au FAOSTAT Atelier du Groupe Technique Régional (GT..."Méthodologie alternative au FAOSTAT Atelier du Groupe Technique Régional (GT...
"Méthodologie alternative au FAOSTAT Atelier du Groupe Technique Régional (GT...FAO
 
Pertinent Primer: Social Media in Health Care
Pertinent Primer: Social Media in Health CarePertinent Primer: Social Media in Health Care
Pertinent Primer: Social Media in Health CareMakala Arce
 
III Foro Alternativas de Sostenibilidad - Macià Blázquez-Salom
III Foro Alternativas de Sostenibilidad - Macià Blázquez-SalomIII Foro Alternativas de Sostenibilidad - Macià Blázquez-Salom
III Foro Alternativas de Sostenibilidad - Macià Blázquez-SalomFundación Alternativas
 
Writing for Translation
Writing for TranslationWriting for Translation
Writing for TranslationClearPath, LLC
 
mHealth Israel_Rhoen Innovations_B2B2C Bootcamp_Dec 8, 2016
mHealth Israel_Rhoen Innovations_B2B2C Bootcamp_Dec 8, 2016mHealth Israel_Rhoen Innovations_B2B2C Bootcamp_Dec 8, 2016
mHealth Israel_Rhoen Innovations_B2B2C Bootcamp_Dec 8, 2016Levi Shapiro
 
DETERMINANTS OF INFLATION IN INDIA: AN ECONOMETRIC ANALYSIS
DETERMINANTS OF INFLATION IN INDIA: AN ECONOMETRIC ANALYSISDETERMINANTS OF INFLATION IN INDIA: AN ECONOMETRIC ANALYSIS
DETERMINANTS OF INFLATION IN INDIA: AN ECONOMETRIC ANALYSISSCHOLEDGE R&D CENTER
 
FDA Labeling for Medical Devices in the Age of Social Media
FDA Labeling for Medical Devices in the Age of Social MediaFDA Labeling for Medical Devices in the Age of Social Media
FDA Labeling for Medical Devices in the Age of Social MediaJoyce Lee
 
SAScon beta 5 ingredients for a successful digital PR campaign
SAScon beta   5 ingredients for a successful digital PR campaignSAScon beta   5 ingredients for a successful digital PR campaign
SAScon beta 5 ingredients for a successful digital PR campaignLaura Crimmons
 
Varhainen tuki ja hoito terveys- ja sosiaalipalveluissa
Varhainen tuki ja hoito terveys- ja sosiaalipalveluissaVarhainen tuki ja hoito terveys- ja sosiaalipalveluissa
Varhainen tuki ja hoito terveys- ja sosiaalipalveluissaTHL
 
FUS NEW EMERGING MODELS
FUS NEW EMERGING MODELSFUS NEW EMERGING MODELS
FUS NEW EMERGING MODELSINSIGHTEC Ltd
 
Twitter Q4 2015 Earnings Deck
Twitter Q4 2015 Earnings DeckTwitter Q4 2015 Earnings Deck
Twitter Q4 2015 Earnings DeckJan Dawson
 
Booz Allen Field Guide to Data Science
Booz Allen Field Guide to Data Science Booz Allen Field Guide to Data Science
Booz Allen Field Guide to Data Science Booz Allen Hamilton
 
DAMA Webinar - Big and Little Data Quality
DAMA Webinar - Big and Little Data QualityDAMA Webinar - Big and Little Data Quality
DAMA Webinar - Big and Little Data QualityDATAVERSITY
 

En vedette (18)

Fiscal Multipliers in Brazil (IADB Brasilia 2012)_MO_FINAL
Fiscal Multipliers in Brazil (IADB Brasilia 2012)_MO_FINALFiscal Multipliers in Brazil (IADB Brasilia 2012)_MO_FINAL
Fiscal Multipliers in Brazil (IADB Brasilia 2012)_MO_FINAL
 
III Foro Alternativas de Sostenibilidad - Jaume Garau
III Foro Alternativas de Sostenibilidad - Jaume GarauIII Foro Alternativas de Sostenibilidad - Jaume Garau
III Foro Alternativas de Sostenibilidad - Jaume Garau
 
Ajankohtaista Kansallisesta rokotusohjelmasta
Ajankohtaista Kansallisesta rokotusohjelmastaAjankohtaista Kansallisesta rokotusohjelmasta
Ajankohtaista Kansallisesta rokotusohjelmasta
 
"Méthodologie alternative au FAOSTAT Atelier du Groupe Technique Régional (GT...
"Méthodologie alternative au FAOSTAT Atelier du Groupe Technique Régional (GT..."Méthodologie alternative au FAOSTAT Atelier du Groupe Technique Régional (GT...
"Méthodologie alternative au FAOSTAT Atelier du Groupe Technique Régional (GT...
 
Pertinent Primer: Social Media in Health Care
Pertinent Primer: Social Media in Health CarePertinent Primer: Social Media in Health Care
Pertinent Primer: Social Media in Health Care
 
III Foro Alternativas de Sostenibilidad - Macià Blázquez-Salom
III Foro Alternativas de Sostenibilidad - Macià Blázquez-SalomIII Foro Alternativas de Sostenibilidad - Macià Blázquez-Salom
III Foro Alternativas de Sostenibilidad - Macià Blázquez-Salom
 
Writing for Translation
Writing for TranslationWriting for Translation
Writing for Translation
 
mHealth Israel_Rhoen Innovations_B2B2C Bootcamp_Dec 8, 2016
mHealth Israel_Rhoen Innovations_B2B2C Bootcamp_Dec 8, 2016mHealth Israel_Rhoen Innovations_B2B2C Bootcamp_Dec 8, 2016
mHealth Israel_Rhoen Innovations_B2B2C Bootcamp_Dec 8, 2016
 
journal
journaljournal
journal
 
DETERMINANTS OF INFLATION IN INDIA: AN ECONOMETRIC ANALYSIS
DETERMINANTS OF INFLATION IN INDIA: AN ECONOMETRIC ANALYSISDETERMINANTS OF INFLATION IN INDIA: AN ECONOMETRIC ANALYSIS
DETERMINANTS OF INFLATION IN INDIA: AN ECONOMETRIC ANALYSIS
 
Customer development
Customer development Customer development
Customer development
 
FDA Labeling for Medical Devices in the Age of Social Media
FDA Labeling for Medical Devices in the Age of Social MediaFDA Labeling for Medical Devices in the Age of Social Media
FDA Labeling for Medical Devices in the Age of Social Media
 
SAScon beta 5 ingredients for a successful digital PR campaign
SAScon beta   5 ingredients for a successful digital PR campaignSAScon beta   5 ingredients for a successful digital PR campaign
SAScon beta 5 ingredients for a successful digital PR campaign
 
Varhainen tuki ja hoito terveys- ja sosiaalipalveluissa
Varhainen tuki ja hoito terveys- ja sosiaalipalveluissaVarhainen tuki ja hoito terveys- ja sosiaalipalveluissa
Varhainen tuki ja hoito terveys- ja sosiaalipalveluissa
 
FUS NEW EMERGING MODELS
FUS NEW EMERGING MODELSFUS NEW EMERGING MODELS
FUS NEW EMERGING MODELS
 
Twitter Q4 2015 Earnings Deck
Twitter Q4 2015 Earnings DeckTwitter Q4 2015 Earnings Deck
Twitter Q4 2015 Earnings Deck
 
Booz Allen Field Guide to Data Science
Booz Allen Field Guide to Data Science Booz Allen Field Guide to Data Science
Booz Allen Field Guide to Data Science
 
DAMA Webinar - Big and Little Data Quality
DAMA Webinar - Big and Little Data QualityDAMA Webinar - Big and Little Data Quality
DAMA Webinar - Big and Little Data Quality
 

Similaire à Inflation Dynamics in Brazil (M.Oreng, 2003)

Regress and Progress! An econometric characterization of the short-run relati...
Regress and Progress! An econometric characterization of the short-run relati...Regress and Progress! An econometric characterization of the short-run relati...
Regress and Progress! An econometric characterization of the short-run relati...Matheus Albergaria
 
Nunes_Tiago_ES20069. (edited)
Nunes_Tiago_ES20069. (edited)Nunes_Tiago_ES20069. (edited)
Nunes_Tiago_ES20069. (edited)Tiago Nunes
 
Finnish fiscal multipliers with a structural VAR model
Finnish fiscal multipliers with a structural VAR modelFinnish fiscal multipliers with a structural VAR model
Finnish fiscal multipliers with a structural VAR modelPalkansaajien tutkimuslaitos
 
MT IS-LM-AD-AS___Big Picture Summary with illustrations, explanations and lin...
MT IS-LM-AD-AS___Big Picture Summary with illustrations, explanations and lin...MT IS-LM-AD-AS___Big Picture Summary with illustrations, explanations and lin...
MT IS-LM-AD-AS___Big Picture Summary with illustrations, explanations and lin...Ari Wibowo
 
Applying the Daily Inflation to Forecast the Broad Consumer Price Index (IPCA...
Applying the Daily Inflation to Forecast the Broad Consumer Price Index (IPCA...Applying the Daily Inflation to Forecast the Broad Consumer Price Index (IPCA...
Applying the Daily Inflation to Forecast the Broad Consumer Price Index (IPCA...FGV Brazil
 
Empirical investigation of the validation of peacock wiseman hypothesis- impl...
Empirical investigation of the validation of peacock wiseman hypothesis- impl...Empirical investigation of the validation of peacock wiseman hypothesis- impl...
Empirical investigation of the validation of peacock wiseman hypothesis- impl...Alexander Decker
 
Is fiscal policy effective in Brazil? An empirical analysis
Is fiscal policy effective in Brazil? An empirical analysisIs fiscal policy effective in Brazil? An empirical analysis
Is fiscal policy effective in Brazil? An empirical analysisFGV Brazil
 
An Innovation-Based Endogenous Growth Model With Equilibrium Unemployment
An Innovation-Based Endogenous Growth Model With Equilibrium UnemploymentAn Innovation-Based Endogenous Growth Model With Equilibrium Unemployment
An Innovation-Based Endogenous Growth Model With Equilibrium UnemploymentWendy Berg
 
Klomp de haan-jes_2010_inflation_and_cbi
Klomp de haan-jes_2010_inflation_and_cbiKlomp de haan-jes_2010_inflation_and_cbi
Klomp de haan-jes_2010_inflation_and_cbigabrielsteven
 
Final Group Paper ECON 123 Group 10
Final Group Paper ECON 123 Group 10Final Group Paper ECON 123 Group 10
Final Group Paper ECON 123 Group 10Scott Fry
 
QUALITY ASSURANCE FOR ECONOMY CLASSIFICATION BASED ON DATA MINING TECHNIQUES
QUALITY ASSURANCE FOR ECONOMY CLASSIFICATION BASED ON DATA MINING TECHNIQUESQUALITY ASSURANCE FOR ECONOMY CLASSIFICATION BASED ON DATA MINING TECHNIQUES
QUALITY ASSURANCE FOR ECONOMY CLASSIFICATION BASED ON DATA MINING TECHNIQUESIJDKP
 
SSRN-id2717905
SSRN-id2717905SSRN-id2717905
SSRN-id2717905Jinpeng Ma
 
Coreinflation
CoreinflationCoreinflation
CoreinflationG Garcia
 
Coreinflation
CoreinflationCoreinflation
CoreinflationG Garcia
 
Critical Review
Critical ReviewCritical Review
Critical ReviewZhu Yanran
 
Debt and the effects of fiscal policy
Debt and the effects of fiscal policyDebt and the effects of fiscal policy
Debt and the effects of fiscal policyLuyen Nguyen
 
An empirical analysis of the incidence of corporate income tax
An empirical analysis of the incidence of corporate income taxAn empirical analysis of the incidence of corporate income tax
An empirical analysis of the incidence of corporate income taxAlexander Decker
 

Similaire à Inflation Dynamics in Brazil (M.Oreng, 2003) (20)

Regress and Progress! An econometric characterization of the short-run relati...
Regress and Progress! An econometric characterization of the short-run relati...Regress and Progress! An econometric characterization of the short-run relati...
Regress and Progress! An econometric characterization of the short-run relati...
 
Nunes_Tiago_ES20069. (edited)
Nunes_Tiago_ES20069. (edited)Nunes_Tiago_ES20069. (edited)
Nunes_Tiago_ES20069. (edited)
 
Finnish fiscal multipliers with a structural VAR model
Finnish fiscal multipliers with a structural VAR modelFinnish fiscal multipliers with a structural VAR model
Finnish fiscal multipliers with a structural VAR model
 
W9443
W9443W9443
W9443
 
MT IS-LM-AD-AS___Big Picture Summary with illustrations, explanations and lin...
MT IS-LM-AD-AS___Big Picture Summary with illustrations, explanations and lin...MT IS-LM-AD-AS___Big Picture Summary with illustrations, explanations and lin...
MT IS-LM-AD-AS___Big Picture Summary with illustrations, explanations and lin...
 
Applying the Daily Inflation to Forecast the Broad Consumer Price Index (IPCA...
Applying the Daily Inflation to Forecast the Broad Consumer Price Index (IPCA...Applying the Daily Inflation to Forecast the Broad Consumer Price Index (IPCA...
Applying the Daily Inflation to Forecast the Broad Consumer Price Index (IPCA...
 
Empirical investigation of the validation of peacock wiseman hypothesis- impl...
Empirical investigation of the validation of peacock wiseman hypothesis- impl...Empirical investigation of the validation of peacock wiseman hypothesis- impl...
Empirical investigation of the validation of peacock wiseman hypothesis- impl...
 
Is fiscal policy effective in Brazil? An empirical analysis
Is fiscal policy effective in Brazil? An empirical analysisIs fiscal policy effective in Brazil? An empirical analysis
Is fiscal policy effective in Brazil? An empirical analysis
 
Answer 1
Answer 1Answer 1
Answer 1
 
An Innovation-Based Endogenous Growth Model With Equilibrium Unemployment
An Innovation-Based Endogenous Growth Model With Equilibrium UnemploymentAn Innovation-Based Endogenous Growth Model With Equilibrium Unemployment
An Innovation-Based Endogenous Growth Model With Equilibrium Unemployment
 
Klomp de haan-jes_2010_inflation_and_cbi
Klomp de haan-jes_2010_inflation_and_cbiKlomp de haan-jes_2010_inflation_and_cbi
Klomp de haan-jes_2010_inflation_and_cbi
 
Final Group Paper ECON 123 Group 10
Final Group Paper ECON 123 Group 10Final Group Paper ECON 123 Group 10
Final Group Paper ECON 123 Group 10
 
QUALITY ASSURANCE FOR ECONOMY CLASSIFICATION BASED ON DATA MINING TECHNIQUES
QUALITY ASSURANCE FOR ECONOMY CLASSIFICATION BASED ON DATA MINING TECHNIQUESQUALITY ASSURANCE FOR ECONOMY CLASSIFICATION BASED ON DATA MINING TECHNIQUES
QUALITY ASSURANCE FOR ECONOMY CLASSIFICATION BASED ON DATA MINING TECHNIQUES
 
SSRN-id2717905
SSRN-id2717905SSRN-id2717905
SSRN-id2717905
 
Coreinflation
CoreinflationCoreinflation
Coreinflation
 
Coreinflation
CoreinflationCoreinflation
Coreinflation
 
Can the Disparity between GDP and GDP Forecast Cause Economic Instability? Th...
Can the Disparity between GDP and GDP Forecast Cause Economic Instability? Th...Can the Disparity between GDP and GDP Forecast Cause Economic Instability? Th...
Can the Disparity between GDP and GDP Forecast Cause Economic Instability? Th...
 
Critical Review
Critical ReviewCritical Review
Critical Review
 
Debt and the effects of fiscal policy
Debt and the effects of fiscal policyDebt and the effects of fiscal policy
Debt and the effects of fiscal policy
 
An empirical analysis of the incidence of corporate income tax
An empirical analysis of the incidence of corporate income taxAn empirical analysis of the incidence of corporate income tax
An empirical analysis of the incidence of corporate income tax
 

Inflation Dynamics in Brazil (M.Oreng, 2003)

  • 1. INFLATION DYMAMICS IN BRAZIL: AN EMPIRICAL APPROACH Mauricio Oreng Prof. Marco A. Bonomo This Version: June, 25th 2003
  • 2. 2 I. Introduction Calvo’s model (1983) implied New Keynesian Phillips Curve (NKPC) addressed some of the unpleasant features of the New Classical version (NCPC), like the fact that only unanticipated variations in nominal spending could affect the real economic activity. Such result, if analyzed more thoroughly, would suggest that monetary policy could influence real GDP only through its immediate effects, affecting prices only in the medium / long run. This is, according to empirical evidence, highly counterfactual. By means of an optimal price setting model, using the hypothesis of staggered prices, Calvo addressed the issue, obtaining then a so called - by Roberts (1995) - New Keynesian Phillips Curve. Thereby, one could concluded that the impact of monetary policy on real economic activity may last until many periods ahead. In addition, this model had on its favor persuasive empirical evidence, as found by Sbordone (2000), when comparing actual inflation and its prediction by Calvo’s model. Nevertheless, according to some economists, we have some reasons one should not feel very comfortable with such model. There are supposedly two main problems with that specification of the Phillips Curve proposed by Calvo: (i) first: NKPC implies a negative relationship between inflation next period and today’s output gap, or, in particular, it predicts lower inflation following periods when real GDP is above its natural value. Second, such specification does not allow for any inflation inertia whatsoever, relying too much on agents’ forward looking behavior, in spite of the fact that many central banks around the world use models incorporating persistence in price acceleration. With regard to the first issue, we observe that, in fact, most empirical work arrive at a positive correlation between output gap and inflation acceleration , which contrasts with the specification of the New Keynesian Curve. Nonetheless, Gali (1999) argues that this may be due to a methodological problem concerning the way one computes the smooth GDP, when calculating the output gap. The rationale is that the natural GDP is function of a vector of structural parameters, whose changes may account for disturbances in natural product measures. As a result, one could happen to find positive correlation between the current gap and inflation change next period, in empirical tests using plain measures of output gap. One solution proposed to address this sticky issue, is to look at the real labor unit cost (marginal cost equivalent), which, in Calvo´s model, is an increasing function of the output gap. This could bring us the possibility of using the real labor unit cost as a proxy for the income gap, a
  • 3. 3 methodology that would allow us to test with more precision empirical evidence for Calvo’s Phillips Curve. On the second issue concerning the problems in NKPC specification, Christiano et al.(2001)’s VAR studies bring up some piece of evidence against the purely forward looking behavior hypothesis, suggested by Calvo’s NKPC. Examining the effects of monetary disturbances on inflation and output, Christiano found that inflation is affected by changes in monetary policy only after most of the output response (to the very same shock) has already occurred. However, as Calvo’s would preach by his model, inflation is determined solely by future expected output gaps, and thus, following a monetary shock, it should move before output. In addition those results, and unexpectedly in accordance with theory, Chistiano also found some high degree of persistence in inflation through this tests, which strengthened the will to try empirically variations on standard Calvo´s specification, now allowing for the possibility of existence of a backward looking component in inflation dynamics. The result then was a another NKPC, mixing agent’s backward and forward looking behavior, so called the Hybrid NKPC. Aiming at this discussion above on the NKPC’s problems, and using american data, Gali and Gertler (1999) tested models that incorporate the approach of using real marginal costs as a proxy for the (ad-hoc) output gap, and that allow for some degree of persistence in inflation as well. As one main result, for the US economy, they came up with the effectiveness of using marginal costs as a proxy to the output gap, yielding the model’s predicted negative relation between future gaps and inflation acceleration. They also found evidence of some mild degree of persistence in US economy’s inflation dynamics. In addition, Gali, Gertler and Salido (2001), performs tests of the same nature for the european economy, finding that NKPC fits the data very well (even better than in the US), what becomes another piece of evidence favoring such theory. How would those results turn out be for the brazilian economy? Our goal, in this current work, is simply to bring answers to such question. The idea is to perform empirical tests of the same nature as in Gali and Gertler (1999), always bearing in mind the need to adjust these experiments to brazilian reality. Hopefully, one will be able to obtain interesting conclusions about the brazilian inflation path within the Real era and to compare them with those obtained for the american economy. In addition, this may, in some cases, provide further robustness to empirical evidence favoring NKPC theorists, and specially in case of Gali and Gertler´s work. Having already motivated this work, now we briefly indicate the steps to be taken. In the next section, we provide methodological information, detailing the sample features,
  • 4. 4 variables and proxies used, and providing some fast information on the econometric techniques. Later on, we stress, using both theoretical and empirical arguments (specificaly applied to the brazilian economy), on the advantages of using the marginal costs approach to estimate the NKPC, sustained byGali and Gertler. The two sections that follow are dedicated to the estimations of, respectively, the purely NKPC and the hybrid one, always focusing to apply Gali and Gertler’s test to the brazilian economy. Then we conclude. II. Methodological Considerations Given the purpose of this current work - to perform, for the brazilian economy, the same type of tests Gali and Gertler have conduced for the US economy - our will here was: trying to perform, as closely as possible in a methodological sense, the very same procedures followed by the authors. So, it could be interesting to briefly highlight, at this point, some of the issues that came up whilst we took on the task of adapting the american research to brazilian reality. First of all, some problems involving data matters have appeared, which is quite not surprising, since there are major asymmetries in both availability and reliability of economic data when we compare Brazil and the US. It is already known to most researchers the scarcity of economic data faced in developing countries, Brazil in particular. Without a full nor broad mass of data in hands, there were times when we faced the need to adapt, to brazilian economy, concepts of economic data (variables and proxies) in the US, so as to reduce the presence of asymmetries in the tests ran for these economies, and to prevent the generation of unwanted noise or measurement errors as well. One standard result from econometrics is that the latter can potentially hurt consistency of OLS (and also GMM) estimates. To exemplify what we mean here, in the case of labor income data (used to obtain a measure of marginal costs), the US data comprises only the industrial and retail sectors (excluding agriculture), meanwhile, for Brazil, the unique of such measure available to us included the agricultural sector. We had some problems of the same nature with regard to variables like long term interest rates and broad-inflation. However, such data asymmetries are not expected to have huge impact on the estimates, for the proxies used herein were sought so as to maximize their co-movements with the original variables1 . Thus, this problem 1 It might not be completely useless to remind the reader that OLS estimators - naturally GMM as well, being OLS’ generalization - are robust to linear transformations (like differences in levels between variables, which is commonly encountered when taking different proxies for a same economic variable).
  • 5. 5 shall not hamper the comparability nor the quality of the results, despite the fact that some robustness tests (e.g. run the same tests with other proxies) should be performed in later versions. One additional issue is that, when it comes to perform the tests and to compare the results obtained for the different economies, it might not be wasteful to look at countries’ historical differences in both economic and geo-political grounds. In particular, contrarily to the US, the brazilian economy had been facing in the past severe inflationary process, until the Real Plan - implemented in June 1994 - succeeded in bringing (relatively) price stabilization to the economy. In practical terms, this implies that, using time series comprising periods earlier and after the Real adoption, we are very likely to observe the presence of structural break(s) in our parameters estimates for Brazil. Bearing this in mind, we were left with two different alternatives: (1) to use a very broad sample period for consistency reasons (like Gali and Gertler), albeit generating somewhat distorted estimates as a result of the applicability of Lucas critique - see Lucas (1976); (2) or to reduce the sample used in the models’ tests, confining it to the Real period, loosing in terms of degree of convergence to the real parameter value (consistency), but reducing dramatically the probability of structural breaks within our dataset. We have found better to choose the second alternative. II.A - Observation Sampling Window Following Gali and Gertler (1999), we chose a dataset of quarterly observations of brazilian data, covering the interval T = [1994:3, 2002:2]. One must notice that we are left with only 32 observations, roughly more than one fifth of Gali and Gertler’s dataset for the US economy, which comprises data across 37 years. Such choice of ours - to shrink the dataset - can be justified, though, for reasons already mentioned above: by reducing the sample window, we try to minimize the effects of Lucas’ critique onto the estimates herein obtained. One might know that, in brazilian economic history, one can easily divide the timeline in (at least) two very distinct moments: one phase earlier and another one after the Real implementation in 1994. The brazilian hyperinflationary process of the past was reversed by such major change in economic policy, which was crucial to bring yearly inflation down from figures around 2480% in 1993 to 22% in 19952 . And intuitively, we know that higher inflation levels become more persistence (i.e. more dependent on the past),
  • 6. 6 as a result of generalized price indexation. This allows us to conclude that the Real implementation brought not only a huge change in inflation level, but also affected the set of driving forces behind the inflation dynamics. One further argument is also applicable to justify the rejection of data prior to 1994:3: hyperinflationary processes are sometimes linked to trajectories associated with bubbles, which is hard to be modeled (and therefore estimated). Therefore, we realized (rather informally, we admit) that there can be little doubt about the existence of major structural changes in any inflation models’ parameters estimated with a sample beginning before 1994, as consequence of the Real Plan. In all, aware of the arguments above, it seemed very reasonable to us to avoid the greater costs of the existence of structural breaks by the compression of the sample window, even at a (smaller) loss in terms of convergence of parameters estimates. II.B - Database and concepts Bearing in mind the objective of being as close as possible to the methodology proposed by Gali and Gertler, and trying to minimize possible differences in concepts of data between the US and the brazilian economy, we set up the sample vector Q(T), for T established as above: Q(T) = [ π(T)´ R(T)´ Z(T)´ ]´, where π(T) is the dependent variable, that is, a broad measure of inflation for the observation period, and R(T), Z(T) are, respectively, a vector of regressors and a vector of instruments, i.e., R(T) = [ s(T)´ x(T)´ ]´ Z(T) = [ s(T)´ x(T)´ i*(T)´ πw (T)´ πc (T)´ πG (T)´ ]´. In Z(T), we used some lagged variables, as was the case of st and xt. A rough characterization of the dataset can be seen below, for all t in T: 2 Data from IBGE’s IPCA, a nationwide consumer price index.
  • 7. 7 (i): πt – Inflation will be represented by percent quarterly variation in FGV’s IGP-M (General Market Price Index), because of the unavailability (in such a frequency) in Brazil of a measure like US’ GDP Deflator, used byGali and Gertler. Given that IGP-M is a linear combination of a consumer price index (IPC), a producer price index (IPA) and a real state price index (INCC), it is fairly broad measure and thus serve as a good proxy for inflation, given our purposes. In IGP-M, IPA has weight of 0.6, IPC 0.3, and naturally INCC’s share is 0.1. (ii): st – Marginal cost is obtained from the following expression: st = log[St] – log[S*t], where St = (WtNt)/ (GDPt n ). Wt is working people’s income (Rendimento Real das Pessoas Ocupadas –IBGE), Nt is labor force (Ocupação - IBGE) and NGDPt is nominal gross domestic product (PIB Nominal – IBGE). So, s(t) represents deviation of labor income share from its steady state value, which we’ll assume here, as a proxy, to be its long term average. The idea of why one comes to use such a measure in our tests will be given in Section IV. (See Figure 1) (iii): xt is the detrended output gap: xt = yt – y*t, where, yt is the log of output (i.e., the log of the nominal GDP, released by IBGE, and deflated by FGV’s IGP-M). Meanwhile, yt* is the a long run trend for the real GDP, a proxy for the natural output, calculated using Hodrick-Prescott’s methodology (HP-Filter). (See Figure 2) (iv): it* is interest rates term spread. It is an instrument, which captures the evolution of the difference between long run and short run interest rates. Such variable is heavily influenced by future expected inflation. In our tests, we use the difference between TJLP rate (% per
  • 8. 8 annun) and 30 days CDB rate (bank deposit rates), with the first being a proxy for long run interest rates, and the latter playing the role of short term interests. (v): πw t and πc t are, respectively, percent change of labor income (a variable also used to calculate s(t)) and percent change of FIPE’s IPC index (consumer’s price index). The first plays the role of wage inflation, whilst the latter is just a standard consumer’s inflation measure. (vi): πG t is FGV’s IGP-DI index, another broad inflation measure, which comprises the same imput variables as IGP-M (with the same weights), differing only in the period of observation (difference of 10 days). It is used as instrument in most of our tests. The interested reader will find out that this sample specification is closely connected to the dataset used by Gali and Gertler, with marginal differences in interpretability, as in the case of IGP-M substituing a measure like GDP Deflator. Even the choice of the set of instruments used has respected the standards adopted in Gali and Gertler (1999). II.C – Econometric Issues As is commonly done across the literature, when it comes to estimate rational expectation models, we test models using the generalized method of moments (GMM), which also follows Gali and Gertler’s way. We shall estimate, for each model, both the reduced and structural forms (when possible), sometimes imposing restrictions in some parameters, in order to assess the robustness of results encountered, just like the original authors have done. The set of instruments utilized in GMM estimation will be the same for all tests conduced throughout this work. In this regard, the only diverging point from the original article is that we used up to 3 lags of each instruments, against 4 in Gali and Gerler (1999). This was motivated by problem we faced with lack of data - contrarily to what happened in the american research’s case - for the more lags we use, the less observations we have to estimate models’ parameters. Comfortably, following that methodological decision, one should expect no significant effect whatsoever in terms of parameters estimates, and results’ comparability. The set of instruments used is constituted by: lag 3 of wage inflation; lag 3 of IPC; lag 2 of interest rate term spread; lag 2 of the output gap (HP-Filter); lags 0 until 3 of IGP-DI and, finally, lags 1 and 2 of marginal cost.
  • 9. 9 For every model estimated, we used Heteroskedastic Autoregressive Consistent (HAC) Covariance Matrix, proposed by Newey & West (1987), which guarantees more precise standard error estimates, which are robust to both heteroskedasticity and serial correlation. This allows us to be more confident on the results generated by the t-statistics, which will be rejecting (or accepting) the null that the parameter equal zero with greater precision than otherwise. In case of models estimated by GMM (the vast majority in this work), we will perform tests on the overidentifying restrictions, the so called TJ test. Unwilling to go so much deep into econometric details, for this is not the scope here, the TJ statistic provide a test on the null hypothesis that the excessive number of moments condition (i.e. the number of instruments that exceeds the quantity of parameters estimated into the estimated equation) are indeed valid. One can prove that TJ statistic is distributed by a Chi-Square p.d.f., with w = r - a degrees of freedom, where r is the number of instruments and a the number of parameters to be estimated. More details on such test can be found in Hamilton (1994). III. The Problem of Estimating NKPC Using Output Gap III.A – Some Theory First One arrives at the NKPC by solving the problem of a monopolistically competitive firm (or set of identical firms), which sets its (their) prices optimally, i.e., determining them such that profits are maximized, subject to the constraint of time-dependent price adjustment. Accordingly to Calvo, from the hypothesis of constant price elasticity of demand, we obtain an aggregate price level such as follows (pt is the log of price level, which for simplicity we name just price level): pt = θpt-1 + (1-θ) pt* (1), where θ is the probability that a firm will not change its prices in the current period. So, aggregate price level is a convex combination of last period’s price level and an optimal price set by firms (those able to change price in the current period).
  • 10. 10 Letting mct represents the deviation of a firm’s real marginal costs from its steady state, and β the subjective discount rate, firms maximize their expected discounted profits (by an stochastic discount factor, which adjusts for the risk), subject to time-dependent price rules, determining their prices according to the expression below, for k between zero and infinity: pt* = (1-θ) Σk(βθ)k Et{mct+k} (2). It is interesting to notice that, when θ = 0, we have the case of fully flexible prices, which in such case is to move accordingly to current marginal costs dynamics. Letting πt = pt – pt-1 denote the inflation rate in tth period, the two expressions above lead us to the following testable equation (for apropriate mct): πt = λmct + βEt{πt+1} (3), where λ = θ-1 (1 - θ) (1 - βθ). Using lead operators, we obtain, for k between zero and infinity: πt = λ Σkβk Et{mct+k} (4). III.B – The econometrics of the NKPC (Traditional Approach) In the past, researchers used the following relation to estimate expression (3): mct = κxt (5), where xt = yt – yt*, being yt the log of the product, and yt* the log of the “natural” product, econometrically obtained through some smoothing methodology. Such hypothesis of linear
  • 11. 11 marginal cost (implicitly: quadratic cost function) yielded the following Phillips Curve, with κ being marginal cost elasticity with respect to output: πt = λκxt + βEt{πt+1} (6). In consonance with our purposes, and similarly as done by Gali and Gertler, we tested with brazilian data the following equation, lagging expression (6) by one period and also imposing β = 1 and α = -λk. πt = αxt-1 + πt-1 + εt (7). Using OLS method, we obtained the following results for (7): Table 1 Parameter Estimate Std. Error t-Statistic Prob. α 0.152 0.067 2.260 0.0312 R-squared -0.803088 Mean dependent var 0.025894 Adjusted R-squared -0.803088 S.D. dependent var 0.018792 S.E. of regression 0.025233 Akaike info criterion -4.489572 Sum squared resid 0.019102 Schwarz criterion -4.443315 Log likelihood 70.58837 Durbin-Watson stat 2.587593 Notes: IGP-M used as the dependent variable. Exogenous variable is the log of the output gap, obtained by HP-Filter. IGP-M lagged byone period is another regressor in (7), however the test impose its coefficient to equal to one. OLS procedure used in estimation, with Newey & West HAC covariance matrix. Adjusted Sample: 1994:4 – 2002:2, with 31 observations. In the test shown above, we found a weakly significant (at 5% level, but not in a 1% sized test) and positive coefficient estimate, which comes relatively in synchrony with results obtained in the american study, where the authors yielded a significant positive value for α (trully, they got a equal to 0.081, rejecting the null on T-test at 1% level). The interpretation for such outcome is the same as in the original work, with this test above providing further evidence against the old fashioned way of estimating the New Keynesian Phillips Curve. In fact, such tests for both US and Brazil’s economy are more likely to support the old Phillips Curve (which uses Et-1{πt} instead of Et{πt+1}), rather than the one formulated by Calvo. Primarily, this would off course be viewed as a negative empirical result for Calvo’s model, had researchers not proven (with both american, and later on, with european data) the
  • 12. 12 validity of the marginal cost approach to estimate parameters from the NKPC in Calvo’s fashion. We shall verify, in the sections that follow, if such results also hold true for the brazilian economy as well. IV. Marginal Costs Approach: The Purely Forward Looking NKPC IV.A – Motivating The New Specification The poor empirical results obtained by Calvo’s NKPC, using data from both US and Brazil’s economy (the latter testified by the earlier section of this current work), when computing the output gap by some smooth technique, might not be a decisive evidence against Calvo’s model. In other words, these bad results should not lead to the rejection of its empirical validity, as some might conclude at a first glance. Gali and Gartler’s point is that such results are directly influenced by the methodology used to obtain the natural output, and the outcome of empirical tests on NKPC may be quite different conditional on the smoothing technique deployed. The authors claim that structural shocks, like change in tastes and variations in government spending may have an impact such that it offsets the forecasted negative relation between inflation acceleration today and the output gap last period. So it would be useful if we had a proxy for the output gap which did not suffer from this problem. The approach used here (for brazilian data), originally proposed in Gali and Gertler (1999), is to use marginal costs as a proxy to the output gap. Gali and Gertler sustain that an alternative way to test the NKPC model is, instead of estimating equation (6), estimating the expression (3), replacing therefore the output gap (xt) by the marginal costs (mct). Since the latter are not directly observable, we must use theory to guide efforts on how to obtain such variable, so allowing us to go into estimation procedures. Section II.B of this current work shows details on how we obtained the measure of marginal costs (for the brazilian economy) which is deployed here. It is important to highlight here that the procedure used to get the marginal costs measure is meant to be as near as possible to the one proposed by the authors in this paper’s “original (american) version”. Let’s go straight to the point, now. Suppose a Cobb Douglas production function like
  • 13. 13 Yt = AtKt αk Nt αn (8). Real marginal costs can be expressed by the ratio of the real wage to the labor’s marginal product: MCt = (Wt/Pt)( ?Yt/?Nt)-1 (9). Some algebraic manipulations, i.e., inserting using expression (8) and the partial derivative of Yt with respect to Nt into (9), yields the following expression below: MCt = Stαn -1 (10), where St = WtNt(PtYt)-1 . From St, the share of labor income, we obtain st, which represents the percent deviations of St from its steady state level (the latter is estimated by use of HP-Filter): st = log[St] – log[St*] (10*). Then, st will then be used in the NKPC’s specifications that we test here, providing our measure of marginal cost that will replace (as a proxy for) the standard measure of the output gap. So, in the next section, we test the following version of Calvo’s NKPC: πt = λst + βEt{πt+1} (11), where λ = θ-1 (1 - θ) (1 - βθ).
  • 14. 14 IV.B – Testing Calvo’s NKPC Using Marginal Costs IV.B.1 – Reduced Form Estimates As we have mentioned earlier, the estimation technique chosen to be applied to (11) is GMM, Generalized Method of Moments, very handy and widely deployed to test rational expectation models (as is the case now). One can show, by means of the iterated expectations law, that expression (11) implies the following moment condition, in the reduced form: Et{(πt - λst - βπt+1)Zt } = 0 (12). Here, Zt denotes the set of instruments defined in section II.B, the very same one that will be used in all tests henceforth. Table 2 Parameter Estimate Std. Error t-Statistic Prob. λ 0.167 0.081 2.061 0.0494 β 0.947 0.049 19.148 0.0000 S.E. of regression 0.027701 Sum squared resid 0.019950 Durbin-Watson stat 2.846987 J-statistic 0.145939 Notes: IGP-M used as inflation measure. Marginal cost obtained by expression (10*). Instruments list can be viewed in Section II.B. GMM estimation procedure used, with Newey & West HAC covariance matrix estimation Convergence achieved after 54 iterations. Adjusted Sample: 1995:2 – 2002:1, with 28 observations. TJ test failed to reject the null hypothesis of validity of overidentifying restrictions at 10%, 5% and 1% levels - Chi-Square pdf at 8 d.f.. For the american economy, Gali and Gertler (1999) had: πt = 0.023st + 0.942Et{πt+1} (0.012) (0.045) And for the european economy, Gali, Gertler and Salido (2001) found: πt = 0.088st + 0.914Et{πt+1} (0.041) (0.040)
  • 15. 15 Thus, what we got a positive (and significant at 5%) value for λ, using marginal cost replacing as a proxy to the “actual” output gap. These results exposed in the table above are not so different to those obtained for the american economy (listed below). The great discrepancy concerns the estimates for λ, given that output elasticity obtained for brazilian data is 7 times as high as the one gotten in the american case, and almost the double of estimates from european economy. In addition, the significance of λ is rather weak in brazilian case, for we fail to reject the null at 1% level, contrarily to what happens for the Europe and US economies. Nevertheless, it is also interesting to notice the similar values obtained for the betas (not only coefficient estimates, but also standard deviations), implying impatience rates relatively consistent, and not very contradictory, across the three economies tested. It could also be worthwhile to provide, at this point, some information on the TJ test. In the test of (12), we failed to reject the null hypothesis about the validity of the (r – a) overidentifying restrictions, where r is the quantity of instruments (10) and a is the number of parameters estimated (2). At 5%, the critical value of Chi-Square at 8 degrees of freedom is 15.51, greater than the value of 4.09 obtained for the TJ statistic. In fact, the same will happen to all conditions tested henceforth, so we shall not waste time in detailing further TJ results on these tests. For symmetry ends, allowing us to compare this new approach to estimate the NKPC with the traditional one, we replaced st for xt in (12), and estimated its parameters for the brazilian economy, yielding the following results: Table 3 Parameter Estimate Std. Error t-Statistic Prob. λ -0.543 0.076 -7.141 0.0000 β 1.088 0.110 9.929 0.0000 S.E. of regression 0.036116 Sum squared resid 0.033913 Durbin-Watson stat 1.877362 J-statistic 0.164286 Notes: IGP-M used as inflation measure. Log of the output gap used (HP-Filter). Instruments list can be viewed in Section II.B. GMM estimation procedure used, with Newey & West HAC covariance matrix estimation Convergence achieved after 500 iterations. Adjusted Sample: 1995:2 – 2002:1, with 28 observations. TJ test failed to reject the null hypothesis of validity of overidentifying restrictions at 10%, 5% and 1% levels - Chi-Square pdf at 8 d.f..
  • 16. 16 With regard to this particular test, results for the US economy were3 : πt = -0.016xt + 0.988Et{πt+1} (0.005) (0.030) For Europe, it was found that: πt = -0.003xt + 0.990Et{πt+1} (0.007) (0.018) Although our test above has come up with an estimate for λ differing considerably from those obtained in Gali and Gertler (1999) for american data, and in Gali, Gertler and Salido (2001) for european data, in general, the evidence found here is roughly the same as in the papers cited above: results of empirical tests on NKPC have been poorer replacing marginal costs by conventional output gap measure (i.e. log-output detrended by HP-Filter). And, at the margin, results encountered for the brazilian sample have become even worse using the standard output gap, in comparison to the tests performed for the other economies. To justify this claim, we have the observation here of a negativeλ (the same sign as in the test for US and Europe), as well as the finding of β> 1, similarly as new estmates for the US economy. Using results from ours and other previous experiments, we robustly find that results on NKPC estimation, mainly those concerning the sign of parameter λ, depend heavily on type the instrument chosen to proxy the output gap. Furthermore, the value found for the beta (yielding an estimate greater than one for both US and Brazil, see footnote 3) is very implausible, for agents should not like better the future than the present, a widely accepted economic hypothesis unobserved by a negative impatience rate implied by β> 1. In all, the tests with brazilian data shown here may strengthen the conclusion that the use of marginal cost approach is indeed valid to estimate the NKPC. It also reinforce empirical evidence favoring Calvo’s model. IV.B.2 – Structural Form Estimates The tests displayed above were performed using reduced form equations. An additional exercise useful at this point is try to estimate equation (12) in the structural form, that is, to test an specification where (in particular) parameter λ is written as function of θ and β. In case of (12), by the use of (11), we have: 3 In Gali, Gertler and Salido (2001), they show new(updated)estimates for the american economy, where it
  • 17. 17 Et{(θπt – (1-θ)(1-θβ)st – θβπt+1)Zt} = 0 (13). So, our next step is to estimate equation (13), using exactly the same set of instruments used before, which will now allow us to obtain estimates for the structural parameter θ. The importance of such parameter is that, in Calvo’s model, it denotes the probability that a given price setter will leave price unchanged in the current period. With knowledge of this parameters, one is able to determine the average time that a certain price is to remain unchanged, which is given by: (1-θ)Σkkθk-1 = (1-θ)-1 (E). More details on that can be found in Gali and Gertler (1999b). By use of this expression above, we find an interesting empirical measure: how often, in average, agents change their prices. In a comparative basis across countries, we expect the brazilian data to show agents changing prices more frequently than in US and Europe, regions where inflation has let few “scars” in the recent decades. Tests performed on equation (13) gave us the following results: Table 4 Parameter Estimate Std. Error t-Statistic Prob. θ 0.593 0.035 16.705 0.0000 β 0.875 0.052 16.814 0.0000 λa 0.330 - - - S.E. of regression 0.016848 Sum squared resid 0.007380 Durbin-Watson stat 2.738034 J-statistic 0.151415 Notes: IGP-M used as inflation measure. Marginal cost obtained by expression (10*). Instruments list can be viewed in Section II.B. GMM estimation procedure used, with Newey & West HAC covariance matrix estimation Convergence achieved after 43 iterations. Adjusted Sample: 1995:2 – 2002:1, with 28 observations. TJ test failed to reject the null hypothesis of validity of overidentifying restrictions at 10%, 5% and 1% levels - Chi-Square pdf at 8 d.f.. a Implied value for λ obtained by replacing estimatedθ and β in expression (11). turned out that λ = 0.021, and β = 1.012, both significant at 1% level.
  • 18. 18 For the same test, results gotten with US and European: Table 5 US Economy Results Euro Economy Results Parameter Estimate Std. Error Estimate Std. Error θ 0.829 0.013 0.904 0.011 β 0.926 0.024 0.886 0.042 λa 0.047 - 0.021 - a Implied value for λ obtained by replacing estimatedθ and β in expression (11). In order to assess the robustness of our estimates, and also following Gali and Gertler (1999), we tested (13) imposing β = 1: Table 6 Parameter Estimate Std. Error t-Statistic Prob. θ -0.353463 0.116952 -3.022291 0.0054 λa -5.182613 - - - S.E. of regression 0.037159 Sum squared resid 0.037281 Durbin-Watson stat 1.519811 J-statistic 0.191011 Notes: IGP-M used as inflation measure. Marginal cost obtained by expression (10*). Instruments list can be viewed in Section II.B. GMM estimation procedure used, with Newey & West HAC covariance matrix estimation Convergence achieved after 40 iterations. Adjusted Sample: 1995:2 – 2002:1, with 28 observations. TJ test failed to reject the null hypothesis of validity of overidentifying restrictions at 10%, 5% and 1% levels - Chi-Square pdf at 8 d.f.. a Implied value for λ obtained by replacing estimatedθ and imposition ofβ =1 in expression (11). For the US economy4 , our benchmark, results in Gali and Gertler (1999) imposingβ = 1: Table 7 US Economy Results Parameter Estimate Std. Error θ 0.829 0.016 λa 0.035 - a Implied value for λ obtained by replacing estimatedθ and β in expression (11). 4 Tests with restricted β (equal to one) were not performed in Gali, Gertler and Salido (2001).
  • 19. 19 Since GMM is quite sensible to the way one performs normalizations on the estimated moments conditions, similarly as done by the authors, we will test an alternative form of equation (13). This alternative equation, expressed by (14), is characterized to be obtained by trivial manipulation of (13), i.e., being just a another way to write down such formula. So, we estimate (14) using the very same procedure, in order to observe the robustness of estimation results obtained in tests on condition (13). Et{(πt – θ−1 (1-θ)(1-θβ)st – βπt+1)Zt} = 0 (14). For equation (14), we got, using brazilian data: Table 8 Parameter Estimate Std. Error t-Statistic Prob. θ 0.642 0.047 13.714 0.0000 β 0.902 0.049 18.302 0.0000 λa 0.235 - - - S.E. of regression 0.027789 Sum squared resid 0.020078 Durbin-Watson stat 2.795883 J-statistic 0.150605 Notes: IGP-M used as inflation measure. Marginal cost obtained by expression (10*). Instruments list can be viewed in Section II.B. GMM estimation procedure used, with Newey & West HAC covariance matrix estimation Convergence achieved after 15 iterations. Adjusted Sample: 1995:2 – 2002:1, with 28 observations. TJ test failed to reject the null hypothesis of validity of overidentifying restrictions at 10%, 5% and 1% levels - Chi-Square pdf at 8 d.f.. a Implied value for λ obtained by replacing estimatedθ and β in expression (11). For the same type of test, results for US and European data had been: Table 9 US Economy Results Euro Economy Results Parameter Estimate Std. Error Estimate Std. Error θ 0.884 0.020 0.918 0.015 β 0.941 0.018 0.914 0.040 λa 0.021 - 0.014 - a Implied value for λ obtained by replacing estimatedθ and β in expression (11).
  • 20. 20 Analogously, imposing β = 1: Table 10 Parameter Estimate Std. Error t-Statistic Prob. θ 0.699 0.073 9.618 0.0000 λa 0.130 - - - S.E. of regression 0.027523 Sum squared resid 0.020452 Durbin-Watson stat 2.878300 J-statistic 0.147589 Notes: IGP-M used as inflation measure. Marginal cost obtained by expression (10*). Instruments list can be viewed in Section II.B. GMM estimation procedure used, with Newey & West HAC covariance matrix estimation Convergence achieved after 35 iterations. Adjusted Sample: 1995:2 – 2002:1, with 28 observations. TJ test failed to reject the null hypothesis of validity of overidentifying restrictions at 10%, 5% and 1% levels - Chi-Square pdf at 8 d.f.. a Implied value for λ obtained by replacing estimatedθ and β in expression (11). For the US economy5 , our benchmark, results in Gali and Gertler (1999) were: Table 11 US Economy Results Parameter Estimate Std. Error θ 0.915 0.035 λa 0.007 - a Implied value for λ obtained by replacing estimatedθ and β in expression (11). It is worthwhile at this time to establish some comments on the results shown above. In what refers to parameter λ, results robustly indicate a higher estimated value for brazilian economy (comparing to those gotten from US and Europe), with our estimates ranging in general on (0.13,0.33). This is an evidence that the output-gap6 elasticity of inflation is greater for Brazil’s economy, implying that, in this country, inflation responds more (generally upwards, we know) to given changes in output gap, in comparison to other developed countries. This is a somewhat intuitive result, for historical reasons, since Brazil has lived periods of huge inflation, and this may institutionally have affected the way inflation (through 5 Tests with restricted β (equal to one) were not performed in Gali, Gertler and Salido (2001). 6 Using marginal costs as a proxy.
  • 21. 21 price setters) responds to output movements, despite the fact that we cannot rule out the possibility that maybe the difference is to high to be true. Furthermore, after estimating the structural form equation, in both ways of normalization, the vector (θ,β) of brazilian unrestricted always came with values in a very reasonable range. The estimated values for β were confined in the (0.87,0.91) interval, implying some acceptable levels of agents’ impatience rate, quite in line with estimates from Europe and the US. Meanwhile, estimates for θ stayed within (0.59,0.65), a somewhat lower level than results obtained with american and european data, but still valid. Trully, we have an explanation for such difference between brazilian and foreign estimates: as one is able to see, in Table 12, that the lower estimated values for brazilian θ (in both normalizations) imply quite robustly that brazilian price setters, in average, tend to change prices more frequently than its american and european counterparts. As we have stated earlier this results comes acordingly to our expectations. For instance, accordingly to the estimates performed by us and the authors, and using results on equation (14), in a period when european price setters (in average) have changed their prices only once, and the americans roughly less than twice, brazilians would have changed prices more than four times. Such result is firmly backed-up by economic intuition, since we know that inflationary culture is latent in Brazil, a consequence of the long years economic agents were forced to live in a hyperinflationary environment. Table 12 Still commenting the estimation results, when we imposed the β to equal one, our results were not so good when we tested condition (13), though things were notoriously different for expression (14). In the first case, the imposition of beta yielded a negative estimate for θ, which does not make any sense at all, for θ is a probability, which obviously
  • 22. 22 must lie in the interval [0,1]. In the latter case, however, the estimate for θ was very robust to the restriction imposed, and the estimates lied within (0.64, 0.70), not much different from the unrestricted estimate of (13). The sticky result obtained in (13), which did not resist to the imposition of β =1, contrasting with american results, proven to be more robust, is indeed something that lead us to seek explanations. One excuse we have is that is sample size asymmetries between the two studies (our and Gali and Gertler’s), with the american work having much more data available - around 37 years of quarterly observations - compared to the 32 quarterly observations within our dataset. We can speculate that this sets a toll into the robustness of our results, because of consistency reasons. Notwithstanding, in the overall, having obtained some reasonable estimates for parameters in the tests performed here, one should be quite satisfied with the results herein mentioned. They should, indeed, be considered as another good evidence for Calvo’s implied NKPC, supporting Gali and Gertler’s argument. V. Marginal Costs Approach: The Hybrid NKPC V.A – Motivating The New Specification As we pointed out earlier, some of the criticism on Calvo’s derivation of the NKPC is aimed at the purely forward looking agent’s behavior it implies. In fact, NKPC supposes unrealistically that only current and future events in the economy (more specifically, the ones affecting the output gap) will be important in inflation determination. Nevertheless, no single economist, who roughly watches empirical economic events, can feel comfortable with such an idea. It underestimates the phenomenon of persistence in inflation trajectory, which has already been documented by empirical work like Christiano et al.(2001). In addition, most central banks around the world use inflation models incorporating such feature. In particular, the Central Bank of Brazil is no exception to such rule, with all versions of its inflation targeting model hypothesizing a variant of Phillips Curve which allows for the presence of inertia in inflation stochastic process7 . With this regard, inflation inertia in Brazil is considered by economists as key issue for the pathological hyperinflationary process observed in the country’s economic past.
  • 23. 23 In order to test for the presence of a backward looking component in the inflation trajectory, we run some models for the Brazilian economy, still in the Gali and Gertler’s flavor. In their paper, using Calvo’s framework, they attach to the purely forward looking NKPC a backward looking inflation component, in order to capture the persistence effects in inflationary process. V.B – Some Theory, Just for The Record Respecting the same set of assumptions adopted in Calvo’s model, we might now suppose, additionally (in ad hoc way), that some fraction ω of firms use an easy rule of thumb to set their prices, based on past information. This is somewhat different from what we had before: a bunch (randomly selected) companies setting prices by solving their profit maximization problem, subject to time-dependent adjustments constraints, using all information available to foresee future economic conditions, mainly, future marginal costs. We shall now classify these firms as Forward Looking (FL), henceforth. In addition to these firms, our new economy has another class of price setters - firms that set prices depending on what they observed in the past – using history-dependent price rules. They constitute the group of Backward Looking firms (BL). In such environment, aggregate prices are determined by the following expressions: pt = θpt-1 + (1-θ)pt* (15), pt* = (1-ω)pt f + ωpt b (16), where pt* is the restricted aggregate price index, for prices set in the current period, pt f and pt b are, respectively, new prices for (FL) and (BL) firms. They obey the following rules (let k be a time-index from period zero to infinity): pt f = (1-θβ)Σk(θβ)k Et{mct+k} (17), pt b = p t-1* + π t-1 (18). 7 The interested reader is referred to Bogdanski, Tombini and Werlang (2000) and Bogdanski et al.(2001).
  • 24. 24 One can observe that pt f is just the optimal price chosen in the purely forward looking model. It is worth to verify that the (ad hoc) establishment of pt b has an interesting property: for stationary inflation dynamics, the rule converges to the optimal forward looking price setting rule, as time goes by. Closing the derivation of this variant of NKPC – called the hybrid Phillips Curve – one is able to obtain the expression below from combining equations (15) to (18): πt = λmct + γf Et{πt+1} + γb πt-1 (19), where λ = (1 - ω)(1 - θ)(1 - θβ)φ-1 , γf = θβφ-1 , γb =ωφ-1 , φ = θ +ω[1 – θ(1 - β)]. V.C – Estimating the Hybrid Model V.C.1 – Structural Form Estimates By the substitution in (19) of λ, γf and γb , as well as the replacement of mct by st 8 , we get the following moments conditions, in the structural form: Et{(φπt – (1-ω)(1-θ)(1-θβ)st – θβπt+1)Zt} = 0 (20), Et{(πt – φ-1 (1-ω)(1-θ)(1-θβ)st – φ-1 θβπt+1)Zt} = 0 (21). Unfortunately, our empirical tests on this structural form, for brazilian data, has been disappointing. For neither (20) nor (21) we could estimate the moment condition’s parameters, for we invariantly obtained singular covariance matrices, which violate necessary 8 Reminding the reader that St is the measure of marginal costs’ percent deviation from its steady state, already deployed in previous tests of ours.
  • 25. 25 boundness condition and impede us to obtain valid estimates. This also happened for other instrument sets than Zt also tested. One hypothetical explanation is that micronumerosity is showing its ugly head here, setting a huge toll on the estimation procedures. Moreover, it is worth highlighting that when we imposed a restriction that ω = 1, the singular matrix problem could be solved for the set of instruments deployed throughout this work (i.e. Zt), but this would not resolve our problem. In all, this is quite bad for empirical reasons, for it would be useful to have further estimates that could (luckily) strengthen our conclusions already reached over θ, β and λ,as well as it could provide (brand new) estimates for ω, γb and γf , parameters for which we have no results whatsoever this far. In the paper that inspired this current work, Gali and Gertler have only tested the structural form equations, and they never mention anything about reduced form estimation results on the hybrid curve. So, in order to observe empirical evidence on such important issue - the degree of brazilian inflation’s persistence or, if one will, the ‘backwardness’ of the inflationary dynamics in Brazil - we detach for a while from the procedures adopted in Gali and Gertler (1999). From now on, we will be encharged to perform tests on the reduced form of the hybrid NKPC. V.C.1 – Reduced Form Estimates As just stated above, in this sub-section, with will to obtain estimates for important inflation dynamics’ parameters, we mean to test the reduced form of the hybrid curve. In order to do so, and likewise the procedure followed in the previous tests, we will be using the marginal costs approach. From expression (19) we get the following testable equation, substituting mct for our measure of marginal costs percent deviations from its steady-state: πt = λst + γf Et{πt+1} + γb πt-1(22). Through the application of the Iterated Expectations Law in (22), one obtain the next moment condition: Et{(πt – λst – γf πt+1 – γb πt-1)Zt} = 0 (23).
  • 26. 26 Using the same set of instruments as in our previous tests (Zt), the estimation results of (23) are shown in Table 13: Table 13 Parameter Estimate Std. Error t-Statistic Prob. λ 0.480 0.088 5.429 0.0000 γf -0.140 0.087 -1.608 0.1203 γb 0.704 0.083 8.445 0.0000 S.E. of regression 0.029469 Sum squared resid 0.021710 Durbin-Watson stat 2.225785 J-statistic 0.158096 Notes: IGP-M used as inflation measure. Marginal cost obtained by expression (10*). Instruments list can be viewed in Section II.B. GMM estimation procedure used, with Newey & West HAC covariance matrix estimation Convergence achieved after 47 iterations. Adjusted Sample: 1995:2 – 2002:1, with 28 observations. TJ test failed to reject the null hypothesis of validity of overidentifying restrictions at 10%, 5% and 1% levels - Chi-Square pdf at 8 d.f.. In order to gain further interpretability, we compare our estimates with results obtained in Gali and Gertler (1999) for the US economy, and Gali, Gertler and Salido (2001) for the european economy. One should be cautious at this point here, for these authors have estimated only the structural form of the hybrid NKPC, which hampers somewhat the symmetry of the comparison established herein. Nevertheless, it might not completely invalidate it, so we display the “foreign” results (for both types of normalization) in Table 14 and 15: Table 14 US Economy Results Normalization (20) Normalization (21) Parameter Estimate Std. Error Estimate Std. Error λ 0.037 - 0.015 - γf 0.682 0.020 0.591 0.016 γb 0.252 0.023 0.378 0.020
  • 27. 27 Table 15 European Economy Results Normalization (20) Normalization (21) Parameter Estimate Std. Error Estimate Std. Error λ 0.018 - 0.006 - γf 0.877 0.045 0.689 0.044 γb 0.025 0.127 0.272 0.072 The results obtained this far for the hybrid NKPC in the brazilian economy allows us to establish the following parallel to the analogous estimates in the US and european economies. First of all, in the meantime, theλ are still much higher for the brazilian economy than for our benchmark economies, which comes very much in line to previous estimates for the same parameter contained in the NKPC specifications tested before (the levels are proportional too). Second, as expected for the historical reasons already mentioned, the brazilian inflationary dynamics was the one with the highest degree of persistence (or inertia, if one will). This might well be a consequence of a “price indexation culture” present in Brazil: after many years of high inflation, price setters became used to observe past inflation and reset their prices likewise. Maybe this culture or habit has not been left aside yet by a considerable fraction of brazilian price setters, even after the Real Plan implementation (which indeed stabilized prices). In other words, our view is that the highly persistent inflation dynamics in Brazil might be result of sluggish agents’ behavior, who got used to living in a widespread price indexation environment, as was the case for the Brazilian economy in the past. Third, one bizarre result that we found is the lack of significance in the forward looking component in brazilian inflation process. This could hint to some the possibility that brazilian inflation expectations are, even in the Real era, purely adaptative, implying a high level of irrationality from price setters in Brazil. This last result is very strong, and may force us to go into further tests in order to validate it. Therefore, for robustness assessment purposes, we also estimated variants of (23) allowing inflation lags of higher order to enter into the hybrid NKPC specification. The empirical tests for them in Brazil gave us the following results:
  • 28. 28 Table 16 Parameter Estimate Std. Error t- Statistic Prob. λ 0.242 0.073 3.318 0.0029 γf 0.968 0.320 3.028 0.0058 γb (L1 ) 0.685 0.175 3.914 0.0007 γb (L2 ) -0.664 0.192 -3.460 0.0020 Mean dependent var 0.000000 S.D. dependent var 0.000000 S.E. of regression 0.031845 Sum squared resid 0.024339 Durbin-Watson stat 3.176994 J-statistic 0.111940 Notes: IGP-M used as inflation measure. Marginal cost obtained by expression (10*). Instruments list can be viewed in Section II.B. GMM estimation procedure used, with Newey & West HAC covariance matrix estimation Convergence achieved after 93 iterations. Adjusted Sample: 1995:2 – 2002:1, with 28 observations. TJ test failed to reject the null hypothesis of validity of overidentifying restrictions at 10%, 5% and 1% levels - Chi-Square pdf at 8 d.f.. Table 17 Parameter Estimate Std. Error t- Statistic Prob. λ 0.089 0.034 2.643 0.0145 γf 0.562 0.155 3.614 0.0015 γb (L1 ) 0.478 0.136 3.522 0.0018 γb (L2 ) -0.650 0.123 -5.290 0.0000 γb (L3 ) 0.499 0.061 8.152 0.0000 Mean dependent var 0.000000 S.D. dependent var 0.000000 S.E. of regression 0.025332 Sum squared resid 0.014760 Durbin-Watson stat 3.396762 J-statistic 0.068357 Notes: IGP-M used as inflation measure. Marginal cost obtained by expression (10*). Instruments list can be viewed in Section II.B. GMM estimation procedure used, with Newey & West HAC covariance matrix estimation Convergence achieved after 37 iterations. Adjusted Sample: 1995:2 – 2002:1, with 28 observations. TJ test failed to reject the null hypothesis of validity of overidentifying restrictions at 10%, 5% and 1% levels - Chi-Square pdf at 8 d.f.. The estimates displayed in Tables 16 and 17 may show us a weird result for the brazilian economy. As we allow a greater number of inflation lags to enter into the hybrid NKPC, some phenomenon occur: (i) the elasticity of inflation with respect to the output gap (marginal cost as a proxy), denoted by the parameter λ, shrinks as more lags of inflation are used. In the last test, one can notice that the estimated value comes very close to those estimates for the US and Europe’s economy, though brazilian figures are still higher (possibly for the economic reasons already explained previously); (ii) the forward looking component of inflation expectations becomes significant as more inflation lags are added; (iii) the estimated value for γb (L1 ) is monotonically decreasing in the number of inflation lags being
  • 29. 29 inserted into the hybrid NKPC. Perhaps all issues from (i) to (iii) are a symptom of some excluded variable bias in coefficient estimates. This is even more clear in case of (iii), when it seems that γb (L1 ) gives back the due credit merited by γb (L3 ) on pushing the current inflation movements, when the latter is included in the specification. Anyway, in the last estimation of (23) performed (which includes three inflation lags) the reasonable estimate for some parameters like λ and γf , which come not only in line with previous brazilian estimates (in other models) but also compatible to international estimated values, may be interpreted as a strong hint that this may be the a nice specification to approximate (i.e. to fit the data on) brazilian inflation dynamics. Another curious result, and quite robust, we might say, is the negative impact that inflation lagged by two periods has in current inflation, yielding values close to –0.65 in the two last tests. This result lacks intuitiveness. The only explanation found this far for this implied sinusoidal inflation dynamics in Brazil is the possibility that brazilian inflation (in the Real era) displays a mean-revertion property, which impedes it to diverge. However, we shall be conservative now and treat this issue more like a puzzle to be resolved, instead of being satisfied with such explanation (speculation) just given. One last (but not least) point refers to inflation persistence. As our tests could show as empirical evidence, brazilian inflation displays huge degree of inertia in prices acceleration. Such results comes much in line with our expectations based on theory and empirical literature. This is a quite important issue for policy makers, since at the margin, monetary policy tends to be less effective in controlling inflation when agents actions are so much dependent on the past. Or equivalently, such high degree of irrationality may worsen the so called (and theoretically supported) by Mankiw (2000) “inexorable” tradeoff between inflation and output.
  • 30. 30 VI. Conclusions In general, the results obtained in this replication of Gali and Gertler’s experiments, for the Brazilian economy, were supportive for Calvo´s theory when tests were performed using real marginal costs as proxy for the true output gap, as was done by the authors. This outcome comes in line with those obtained for the both US and european economy, despite some natural differences in estimated parameters. Here, in most tests, we had reasonable parameter values (i.e. estimates lying in a very acceptable range, accordingly to the theory). Considering data deficiencies in Brazil, this is something positive. On empirical grounds, one key conclusion we could obtain with our tests is the deep and notorious inflationary culture, which is present in Brazil’s economy. Our tests verified that not only inflationary inertia is a key issue in this country, much more than in the US and Europe, but also that brazilian price setters, compared to their american and european counterpart have (in average) habit to change prices much more frequently. In Brazil, one can say that this is a quite “inflationary” habit, given empirical resistance from price setters to lower their prices. Another evidence of an inflationary culture is the greater sensibility of brazilian inflation to the output gap, when compared to the inflation dynamics in both the US and in Europe. Such conclusion is intuitive, since, in the recent decades, Brazil has suffered from hyperinflationary maladies, contrarily to what happened for the two other regions tested. Notwithstanding, methodologically, one should not disguise the fact that this work here still needs to be improved in terms of robustness of the results. Some of the parameters estimated, in spite of being in reasonable parameter range, are still varying undesirably. In some tests, results changed more than we wanted it to by altering the normalization of moment’s condition or imposing parameters restrictions. Robustness is, in fact, the main point that need development in this work. Our guess is that the smaller degree of robustness in our estimates is caused by the lack of observations we had (32 points, compared to more than 140 in the american work). In addition to have hampered any robustness analysis to be performed in sub-periods, the lack of data might have affected some estimates (the ones showing counter-intuitive results), for parameter estimates’ consistency require greater number of observations. This may explain, also, in our opinion, the variability of estimates results, because GMM is only asymptotically efficient, and micronumerosity might have set a toll on variance estimates as well.
  • 31. 31 References Bogdanski, J., Tombini, A.A., Werlang, S.R.C., 2000, “Implementing Inflation Targeting in Brazil”, Central Bank of Brazil Working Paper #1. Bogdanski, J., Freitas, P.S., Goldfajn, I., Tombini, A.A., 2001, “Inflation Targeting in Brazil: Shocks, Backward-Looking Prices and IMF Conditionality”, Central Bank of Brazil Working Paper #24, August. Christiano, L., Eichenbaum, M., Evans, C., 2000, “Monetary Policy Shocks: What Have We Learned and To What End?”, Handbook of Macroeconomics. Clarida, R., Gali, J. and Gertler, M., 1999b, “The Science of Monetary Policy: a New Keynesian Perspective”, Journal of Economic Literature 37 #2, 1661-1707. Gali, J., 1999, “Technology, Employment, and the Business Cycle: Do Technology Shocks Explain Aggregate Fluctuations?”, American Economic Review, March, 249-271. Gali, J. and Gertler, M., 1999, “Inflation Dynamics: A Structural Econometric Analysis”, Journal of Monetary Economics 44, 195-222. Gali, J. and Gertler, M., Salido, J.D.L., 2001, “European Inflation Dynamics”, NBER Working Paper # 8218. Hamilton, J.D., 1994, “Time Series Analysis”, Princeton University Press. Lucas, R.E., 1976, “Econometric Policy Evaluation: A Critique”, Carnegie- Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy. (1), 19-46.
  • 32. 32 Mankiw, N.G., 2000, “The Inexorable and Mysterious Tradeoff Between Inflation and Unemployment”, NBER Working Paper # 7884. Newey, W.K., West, K.D., 1987, “A Simple Positive Semi-Definite Heteroskedasticity and Autocorrelation Covariance Matrix”, Econometrica (55), 703-708. Roberts, J.M., 1995, “New Keynesian Economics and the Phillips Curve”, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking Vol. 27 (4), 975-984. Sbordone, A.M., 2000, “Prices and Unit Labor Costs: A New Test of Price Stickiness”, Institute of International Economic Studies, Stockholm, Seminar Paper #653, April (revised). Woodford, M., 2001, “Interest and Prices”, mimeo.
  • 33. 33 Figure 1. Marginal Costs and Its Long-Term Trend (HP-Filter) This graph shows marginal costs and its trend (by HP Filter) Figure 2. Smoothing Log-Output By Use of Hodrick Prescott Filter This graph displays log output and natural log output (obtained by HP-Filter) 3.70 3.75 3.80 3.85 3.90 3.95 4.00 4.05 95 96 97 98 99 00 01 02 LOG_MGCOST HP_LOGMGCOST 11.6 11.8 12.0 12.2 12.4 12.6 12.8 95 96 97 98 99 00 01 02 LOG_GDP HP_LOGGDP